Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-45l2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-29T05:07:30.217Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Woodford and Wicksell on Interest and Prices: The Place of the Pure Credit Economy in the Theory of Monetary Policy

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

David Laidler
Affiliation:
Professor Emeritus at the University of Western Ontario, and Scholar in Residence at the C. D. Howe Institute.

Extract

There can be no doubt that the monetary systems of a number of advanced countries nowadays resemble Knut Wicksell's (1898) model of the “pure credit economy” much more closely than did any that actually existed in the world for which he wrote. Currency has long been losing its quantitative importance in mediating transactions among the general public in such countries, and more recently, the development of modern information technology has made it possible for them to operate the clearing and settlement systems that underpin the use of bank deposits as means of exchange with a close-to-zero stock of reserve assets.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2006

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Brunner, Karl and Meltzer, Allan H. (1993) Money in the Economy: Issues in Monetary Analysis (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press for the Raffaele Mattioli Foundation).Google Scholar
Hicks, John (1983) The Collected Essays of Sir John Hicks, Vol.3: Classics and Moderns (Oxford: Oxford University Press).Google Scholar
Humphrey, Thomas M. (2003) Knut Wicksell and Gustav Cassel on the Cumulative Process and the Price-stabilizing Policy Rule, Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 25 (06), pp. 199220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jonung, Lars (1979) Knut Wicksell's Norm of Stabilization and Swedish Monetary Policy in the 1930s, Journal of Monetary Economics, 5 (4), pp. 459–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, David (1999a) Fabricating the Keynesian Revolution (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
Laidler, David (1999b) Variations on a Two Interest Rate Theme, in: Howitt, Peter, di Antoni, Elizabetta, and Leijonhuvfud, Axel (Eds) Money, Markets and Method: Essays in Honour of Robert W. Clower (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar).Google Scholar
Laidler, David (2004) Monetary Policy after Bubbles Burst: the Zero Lower Bound, the Liquidity Trap and the Credit Deadlock, Canadian Public Policy (forthcoming).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Longworth, David (2003) Money in the Bank (of Canada) Technical Report 93 (Ottawa: Bank of Canada).Google Scholar
Ohlin, Bertil (1936) Introduction to Knut Wicksell, Interest and Prices (1898) Kahn, Richard (Trans) (London: Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society, 1936).Google Scholar
Patinkin, Don (1965) Note E: Wicksell's Monetary Theory, in: Money, Interest and Prices, 2nd edition (New York: Harper and Row).Google Scholar
Svennson, Lars (2003) Escaping from a Liquidity Trap and Deflation: the Foolproof Way and Others, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17 (Fall), pp. 145–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wicksell, Knut (1898) Interest and Prices, translated by Kahn, Richard (London: Macmillan for the Royal Economic Society, 1936).Google Scholar
Woodford, Michael (2003) Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar