Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T00:55:35.998Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Political Volatility and Governance in East Central Europe

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2017

Carolyn Forestiere*
Affiliation:
University of Maryland, Baltimore County

Abstract

In this article, Carolyn Forestiere investigates political volatility as a way to explain varying levels of governance across the new democracies of east central Europe. Specifically, legislative and executive volatility are examined. The results suggest that differences in legislative volatility help explain variations in governance, especially during the beginning of a new democracy. Once party systems begin to consolidate, however, differences in executive volatility begin to matter more. A case study of Poland confirms some of Forestiere's conclusions. While the legislative party system has shown some signs of stabilization, executive volatility remains a salient political problem, which over time has led to a steady decline in the quality of governance.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Association for Slavic, East European, and Eurasian Studies. 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

I would like to thank Christopher S. Allen, Dave Marcotte, Shawn Williams, and the anonymous reviewers for their assistance and comments. Any and all errors are my own.

1. Jungerstam-Mulders, Susanne, ed., Post-Communist EU Member States: Parties and Party Systems (Burlington, Vt., 2006)Google Scholar.

2. Altman, David and Perez-Linan, Anibal, “Assessing the Quality of Democracy: Freedom, Competitiveness and Participation in Eighteen Latin American Countries,” Democratimtion9, no. 2 (Summer 2002): 6784 Google Scholar.

3. Vanhanen, Tatu, The Process of Democratization: A Comparative Study of 147 States, 1980-88 (New York, 1990)Google Scholar.

4. Diamond, Larry and Morlino, Leonardo, eds., Assessing tlie Quality of Democracy (Baltimore, 2005)Google Scholar; Anderson, Christopher J. and Guillory, Christine A., “Political Institutions and Satisfaction with Democracy: A Cross-National Analysis of Consensus and Majoritarian Systems,” American Political Science Review 91, no. 1 (March 1997): 6681 Google Scholar.

5. Lijphart, Arend, Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries (New Haven, 1999)Google Scholar.

6. The inclusion of “political stability” as part of the dependent variable, and the use of “political volatility” as the independent variable may cause concern because of potential endogeneity. However, political volatility as defined by the World Bank involves the potential use of violence and unconstitutional means to overthrow a government. Political volatility, as I am using it here, assesses change through democratic means, such as elections and votes of no confidence in the legislature. For this reason, the World Bank's indicator of “political stability” and my indicator of political volatility are considered conceptually distinct; the World Bank's indicators for political stability remain included in the overall governance index. According to the World Bank, “Voice and Accountability measures the extent to which a country's citizens are able to participate in selecting their government, as well as freedom of expression, freedom of association, and a free media. Political Stability and Absence of Violence measures the perceptions of the likelihood that the government will be destabilized or overthrown by unconstitutional or violent means, including domestic violence and terrorism. Government Effectiveness measures the quality of public services, the quality of the civil service and the degree of its independence from political pressures, the qualit)' of policy formulation and implementation, and the credibility of the government's commitment to such policies. Regulatory Quality measures the ability of the government to formulate and implement sound policies and regulations that permit and promote private sector development. Rule of Law measures the extent to which agents have confidence in and abide by the rules of society, in particular the quality of contract enforcement, the police, and the courts, as well as the likelihood of crime and violence. Finally, Control of Corruption measures the extent to which public power is exercised for private gain, including petty and grand forms of corruption, as well as'capture'of the state by elites and private in terests.“ At info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi.faq.htm#2 (lastaccessed 1 September 2010).

7. For a critique on using these measures, however, see Matt Andrews, “Good Government Means Different Things to Different Countries” (paper presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston, 2008).

8. Kitschelt, Herbert etal., Post-Communist Party Systems: Competition, Representation, and Inter-Party Competition (Cambridge, Eng, 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9. Linz, Juan J. and Stepan, Alfred C., Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation: Southern Europe, South America, and Post-Communist Europe (Baltimore, 1996)Google Scholar.

10. Kitschelt, Herbert, “The Formation of Party Systems in East Central Europe,” Politics and Society 20, no. 1 (March 1992): 7 CrossRefGoogle Scholar (emphasis in the original).

11. Innes, Abby, “Party Competition in Postcommunist Europe: The Great Electoral Lottery,” Comparative Politics 35, no. 1 (October 2002): 85 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12. Birch, Sarah, Electoral Systems and Political Transformation in Post-Communist Europe (New York, 2003), 120 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

13. Kitschelt, Herbert and Wilkinson, Steven I., Patrons, Clients, and Policies: Patterns of Democratic Accountability and Political Competition (Cambridge, Eng., 2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14. Pedersen, Mogens N., “The Dynamics of European Party Systems: Changing Patterns of Electoral Volatility,” European fournal of Political Research 7, no. 1 (March 1979): 126 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

15. Birch, Electoral Syste7iis and Political Transformation.

16. Ibid., 123.

17. Here one must distinguish between authoritarian and democratic stability. Dictators may produce stability because they remain in power for long periods of time. But this type of stability is perhaps better labeled rigidity because there are no mechanisms for accountability; leaders stay in power because of coercion. Democratic stability is different because voters reevaluate the performance of political leaders at regular intervals. In a democratically stable state, leaders who remain in power over long periods of time do so because they are viewed as legitimate by the voting public.

18. O'Dwyer, Conor and Kovalčík, Branislav, “And the Last Shall Be First: Part)’ System Institutionalization and Second-Generation Economic Reform in Postcommunist Europe,“ Comparative Institutional Development 41, no. 4 (2007)Google Scholar.

19. Grzymala-Busse, Anna, Rebuilding Leviathan: Party Competition and State Exploitation in Post-Communist Democracies (Cambridge, Eng., 2007), 2 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20. Schmidt, Manfred G., “Political Performance and Types of Democracy: Findings from Comparative Studies,” European Journal of Political Research 41, no. 1 (January 2002): 151 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

21. Taras, Ray, “Executive Leadership: Presidents and Governments,” in White, Stephen et al., eds., Developments in Central and East European Politics 3 (Durham, 2003), 131 Google Scholar.

22. Petr Kopecky, “Structures of Representation: The New Parliaments of Central and Eastern Europe,” in White et al., eds., Developments in Central and East European Politics 3.

23. For an example, see Lijphart, Patterns of Democracy, chap. 7.

24. Because there may be serial correlation within the observations for each country, the standard errors reported in table 2 may be incorrect. One strategy to address this problem is to calculate standard errors “clustered” on countries. When I re-estimate the model reported in table 3, clustering the standard error, the point estimates are unchanged but are less precisely estimated. The coefficient on GNI remains significant, but party replacement is no longer significant at conventional levels (t = —1.34). This result, however, is to be expected: with only four observations for each of the eight countries, there are very few degrees of freedom, making it very unlikely to reject null hypotheses. Since the coefficient for the party replacement variable remained unchanged, the inclusion of additional years’ data would result in more precisely estimated coefficients, likely significant at conventional levels.

25. Greater levels of income are predicted to be associated with higher scores on the governance index because the governments in wealthier countries have significant advantages over governments in poorer countries. Measures for GNI are taken from the Europa World Book for selected years. Furthermore, lower levels of ethnic fractionalization, which assesses the probability that two randomly selected individuals will belong to different groups, are also predicted to be associated with higher scores on the governance index. Governments that have to administer services and respond to largely heterogeneous societies may have greater problems in keeping the peace and providing a high quality of governance to all politically equal citizens. Measures for ethnic fractionalization are taken from Nauro F. Campos and Vitaliy S. Kuzeyev, “On the Dynamics of Ethnic Fractionalization“ (paper prepared for the Institute for the Study of Labor Discussion Paper Series, IZA DP No. 2822, 2007).

26. Slovenia's per capita GNI in 2000 was $10,070 and $9,810 in 2002. By 2006, however, this had increased to $18,890.

27. Castle, Marjorie and Taras, Ray, Democracy in Poland, 2d ed. (Boulder, Colo., 2002)Google Scholar.

28. Campos and Kuzeyev, “On the Dynamics of Ethnic Fractionalization.“

29. Linz and Stepan, Problems of Democratic Transition and Consolidation.

30. Ibid., 275.

31. McMenamin, Iain, “Semi-Presidentialism and Democratisation in Poland,” in Elgie, Robert and Moestrup, Sophia, eds., Semi-Presidentialism in Central and. Eastern Europe (Manchester, Eng., 2008)Google Scholar; Raciborski, J., “Forming Government Elites in a New Democracy: The Case of Poland,” Communist and Post-Communist Studies 40, no. 1 (March 2007): 1740 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32. Jasiewicz, Krzysztof, “Poland,” European Journal of Political Research 22, no. 4 (December 1992): 489504 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33. Jasiewicz, Kizysztof and Jasiewicz-Betkiewicz, Agnieszka, “Poland,” European journal of Political Research 45, nos. 7-8 (December 2006): 1231 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

34. Jasiewicz, Krzysztof, “Poland,” European Journal of Political Research 32, no. 3 (December 1997): 469–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35. Jasiewicz, Krzysztof and jasiewicz-Betkiewicz, Agnieszka, “Poland,” European Journal of Political Research 46, nos. 7-8 (December 2007): 1063–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

36. Mungiu-Pippidi, Alina, “Is East-Central Europe Backsliding? EU Accession Is No 'End of History,'” Journal of Democracy 18, no. 4 (October 2007): 816 Google Scholar.

37. For Freedom House's “Nations in Transit” data, see www.freedomhouse.org/ template.cfm?page= 17 (last accessed 1 September 2010). 38. Ibid.; Raciborski, “Forming Government Elites.“

39. The unfortunate death of President Lech Kaczyriski and several other Polish elite in the Smolensk plane crash on 10 April 2010 may, however, serve as an exogenous event promoting national unity. Furthermore, the new president elected on 4 July 2010, Bronislaw Komorowski, belongs to the same party (Civic Platform) as the current prime minister, which may also facilitate greater executive stability.