Skip to main content
×
Home
    • Aa
    • Aa

The Breakdown of Industrial Opposition to Trade: Firms, Product Variety, and Reciprocal Liberalization

Abstract

This article documents systematic deviations from standard models of trade politics, each of which has the effect of undermining sustained efforts at coherent industrial opposition to trade. Industries have internal disagreements about liberalization, support for trade liberalization extends bilaterally across borders in the same industry, and comparative disadvantage industries feature convincing expressions of public support for liberalization. These surprising outcomes are explained by a model of trade politics that emphasizes three factors: firm heterogeneity in export performance, product differentiation, and reciprocal liberalization. The author uses a new data set of industry attitudes about fifteen US trade agreements to show that product differentiation is strongly correlated with these outcomes, even conditional on plausible alternatives. The author concludes that public position-taking and lobbying on trade politics have been fundamentally altered by the rise of product variety; trade's opponents and indifferents have been overwhelmed by pro-globalization firms breaking out to support trade on their own.

Copyright
Linked references
Hide All

This list contains references from the content that can be linked to their source. For a full set of references and notes please see the PDF or HTML where available.

Alberto Alesina , Enrico Spolaore , and Romain Wacziarg . 2000. “Economic Integration and Political Disintegration.” American Economic Review 90, no. 5: 1276–96.

Pol Antràs . 2003. “Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, no. 4: 1375–418.

David H. Autor , David Dorn , and Gordon H. Hanson . 2013. “The China Syndrome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United States.” American Economic Review 103, no. 6: 2121–68.

Leonardo Baccini , and Andreas Dür . 2015. “Investment Discrimination and the Proliferation of Preferential Trade Agreements.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 59, no. 4: 617–44.

Scott L. Baier , and Jeffrey H. Bergstrand . 2007. “Do Free Trade Agreements Actually Increase Members’ International Trade?Journal of International Economics 71, no. 1: 7295.

Scott L. Baier , and Jeffrey H. Bergstrand . 2009. “Estimating the Effects of Free Trade Agreements on International Trade Flows Using Matching Econometrics.” Journal of International Economics 77, no. 1: 6376.

Bela Balassa . 1965. “Trade Liberalisation and ‘Revealed’ Comparative Advantage.” Manchester School 33, no. 2: 99123.

Eugene Beaulieu . 2002a. “Factor or Industry Cleavages in Trade Policy? An Empirical Analysis of the Stolper–Samuelson Theorem.” Economics & Politics 14, no. 2: 99131.

Eugene Beaulieu , and Christopher Magee . 2004. “Four Simple Tests of Campaign Contributions and Trade Policy Preferences.” Economics & Politics 16, no. 2: 163–87.

Andrew B. Bernard , Jonathan Eaton , J. Bradford Jenson , and Samuel Kortum . 2003. “Plants and Productivity in International Trade.” American Economic Review 93, no. 4: 1268–90.

Andrew B. Bernard , J. Bradford Jensen , and Robert Lawrence . 1995. “Exporters, Jobs and Wages in US Manufacturing: 1976–1987.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics 1995: 67112.

Andrew B. Bernard , J. Bradford Jensen , Stephen J. Redding , and Peter K. Schott . 2007. “Firms in International Trade.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21, no. 3: 105–30.

Andrew B. Bernard , J. Bradford Jensen , and Peter K. Schott . 2009. “Importers, Exporters and Multinationals: A Portrait of Firms in the U.S. that Trade Goods.” In Timothy Dunne , J. Bradford Jensen , and Mark J. Roberts , eds., Producer Dynamics: New Evidence from Micro Data. Chicago, Ill.: University of Chicago Press.

Matilde Bombardini , and Francesco Trebbi . 2012. “Competition and Political Organization: Together or Alone in Lobbying for Trade Policy?Journal of International Economics 87, no. 1: 1826.

Christian Broda , and David E. Weinstein . 2006. “Globalization and the Gains from Variety.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 121, no. 2: 541–85.

Marius Brülhart . 2009. “An Account of Global Intra-industry Trade, 1962–2006.” World Economy 32, no. 3: 401–59.

Marc L. Busch , and Eric Reinhardt . 2000. “Geography, International Trade, and Political Mobilization in U.S. Industries.” American Journal of Political Science 44, no. 4: 703–19.

Tim Büthe , and Helen V. Milner . 2008. “The Politics of Foreign Direct Investment into Developing Countries: Increasing FDI through International Trade Agreements?American Journal of Political Science 52, no. 4: 741–62.

Lorenzo Caliendo , and Fernando Parro . 2015. “Estimates of the Trade and Welfare Effects of NAFTA.” Review of Economic Studies 82, no. 1: 144.

Kerry A. Chase 2003. “Economic Interests and Regional Trading Arrangements: The Case of NAFTA.” International Organization 57, no. 1: 137–74.

Dirk De Bièvre , and Andreas Dür . 2005. “Constituency Interests and Delegation in European and American Trade Policy.” Comparative Political Studies 38, no. 10: 1271–96.

Jeffrey M. Drope , and Wendy L. Hansen . 2009. “New Evidence for the Theory of Groups: Trade Association Lobbying in Washington, D.C.” Political Research Quarterly 62, no. 2: 303–16.

Andreas Dür , Leonardo Baccini , and Manfred Elsig . 2014. “The Design of International Trade Agreements: Introducing a New Dataset.” Review of International Organizations 9, no. 3: 353–75.

Pushan Dutt , and Devashish Mitra . 2002. “Endogenous Trade Policy through Majority Voting: An Empirical Investigation.” Journal of International Economics 58, no. 1: 107–33.

Robert C. Feenstra , and Gordon H. Hanson . 2004. “Intermediaries in Entrepôt Trade: Hong Kong Re-Exports of Chinese Goods.” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 13, no. 1: 335.

Jeffry A. Frieden 1991. “Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance.” International Organization 45, no. 4: 425–51.

Kishore Gawande , and Usree Bandyopadhyay . 2000. “Is Protection for Sale? Evidence on the Grossman–Helpman Theory of Endogenous Protection.” Review of Economics and Statistics 82, no. 1: 139–52.

Adam N. Glynn 2012. “The Product and Difference Fallacies for Indirect Effects.” American Journal of Political Science 56, no. 1: 257–69.

Gene M. Grossman , and Elhanan Helpman . 1995. “Trade Wars and Trade Talks.” Journal of Political Economy 103, no. 4: 675708.

Gene M. Grossman , and Elhanan Helpman . 2002. “Integration versus Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117, no. 1: 85120.

Herbert G. Grubel , and Peter J. Lloyd . 1971. “The Empirical Measurement of Intra-Industry Trade.” Economic Record 47, no. 4: 494517.

Jens Hainmueller , and Michael J. Hiscox . 2006. “Learning to Love Globalization: Education and Individual Attitudes toward International Trade.” International Organization 60, no. 2: 469–98.

Keith Head , Thierry Mayer , and John Ries . 2002. “On the Pervasiveness of Home Market Effects.” Economica 69, no. 275: 371–90.

Elhanan Helpman . 1984. “A Simple Theory of International Trade with Multinational Corporations.” Journal of Political Economy 92, no. 3: 451–71.

Elhanan Helpman . 2011. Understanding Global Trade. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Elhanan Helpman , Marc J. Melitz , and Stephen R. Yeaple . 2004. “Export versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms.” American Economic Review 94, no. 1: 300316.

Michael J. Hiscox 2002. “Interindustry Factor Mobility and Technological Change: Evidence on Wage and Profit Dispersion across U.S. Industries, 1820–1990.” Journal of Economic History 62, no. 2: 383416.

Hyeran Jo , and Hyun Namgung . 2012. “Dispute Settlement Mechanisms in Preferential Trade Agreements: Democracy, Boilerplates, and the Multilateral Trade Regime.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 56, no. 6: 1041–68.

Leslie Johns . 2014. “Depth versus Rigidity in the Design of International Trade Agreements.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 26, no. 3: 468–95.

Daniel Yuichi Kono . 2007. “Who Liberalizes? Explaining Preferential Trade Liberalization.” International Interactions 33, no. 4: 401–21.

Daniel Yuichi Kono . 2012. “Alliances, Trade Discrimination, and the Global Trade Regime.” International Interactions 38, no. 5: 647–69.

Paul R. Krugman 1981. “Intraindustry Specialization and the Gains from Trade.” Journal of Political Economy 89, no. 5: 959–73.

Jeffrey Kucik . 2012. “The Domestic Politics of Institutional Design: Producer Preferences over Trade Agreement Rules.” Economics & Politics 24, no. 2: 95118.

Christopher S. P. Magee , Carl Davidson , and Steven J. Matusz . 2005. “Trade, Turnover, and Tithing.” Journal of International Economics 66, no. 1: 157–76.

Mark S. Manger 2005. “Competition and Bilateralism in Trade Policy: The Case of Japan's Free Trade Agreements.” Review of International Political Economy 12, no. 5: 804–28.

Mark S. Manger 2009. Investing in Protection: The Politics of Preferential Trade Agreements between North and South. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Mark S. Manger , Mark A. Pickup , and Tom A. B. Snijders . 2012. “A Hierarchy of Preferences: A Longitudinal Network Analysis Approach to PTA Formation.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 56, no. 5: 853–78.

Edward D. Mansfield , and Eric Reinhardt . 2003. “Multilateral Determinants of Regionalism: The Effects of GATT/WTO on the Formation of Preferential Trading Arrangements.” International Organization 57, no. 4: 829–62.

Thierry Mayer , and Gianmarco I. P. Ottaviano . 2008. “The Happy Few: The Internationalisation of European Firms.” Intereconomics 43, no. 3: 135–48.

Denis Medvedev . 2012. “Beyond Trade: The Impact of Preferential Trade Agreements on FDI Inflows.” World Development 40, no. 1: 4961.

Marc J. Melitz , and Gianmarco I. P. Ottaviano . 2008. “Market Size, Trade, and Productivity.” Review of Economic Studies 75, no. 1: 295316.

Helen V. Milner , and Keiko Kubota . 2005. “Why the Move to Free Trade? Democracy and Trade Policy in the Developing Countries.” International Organization 59, no. 1: 107–43.

Iain Osgood . 2016a. “Differentiated Products, Divided Industries: Firm Preferences over Trade Liberalization.” Economics & Politics 28, no. 2: 161–80.

Nina Pavcnik . 2002. “Trade Liberalization, Exit, and Productivity Improvements: Evidence from Chilean Plants.” Review of Economic Studies 69, no. 1: 245–76.

Justin R. Pierce , and Peter K. Schott . 2016. “The Surprisingly Swift Decline of US Manufacturing Employment.” American Economic Review 106, no. 7: 1632–62.

James E. Rauch 1999. “Networks versus Markets in International Trade.” Journal of International Economics 48, no. 1: 735.

John Ravenhill . 2010. “The ‘New East Asian Regionalism’: A Political Domino Effect.” Review of International Political Economy 17, no. 2: 178208.

Stephanie J. Rickard , and Daniel Y. Kono . 2014. “Think Globally, Buy Locally: International Agreements and Government Procurement.” The Review of International Organizations 9, no. 3: 333–52.

Kenneth F. Scheve , and Matthew J. Slaughter . 2001. “What Determines Individual Trade-Policy Preferences?Journal of International Economics 54, no. 2: 267–92.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

World Politics
  • ISSN: 0043-8871
  • EISSN: 1086-3338
  • URL: /core/journals/world-politics
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×
Type Description Title
WORD
Supplementary Materials

Osgood supplementary material
Abstract and contributors information

 Word (16 KB)
16 KB
PDF
Supplementary Materials

Osgood supplementary material
Osgood supplementary material 1

 PDF (257 KB)
257 KB

Metrics

Altmetric attention score

Full text views

Total number of HTML views: 0
Total number of PDF views: 226 *
Loading metrics...

Abstract views

Total abstract views: 636 *
Loading metrics...

* Views captured on Cambridge Core between 8th December 2016 - 24th September 2017. This data will be updated every 24 hours.