Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-22dnz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T02:09:55.624Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Leadership with Trustworthy Associates

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  21 June 2018

TORUN DEWAN*
Affiliation:
London School of Economics and Political Science
FRANCESCO SQUINTANI*
Affiliation:
Warwick University
*
Torun Dewan is a Professor of Government London School of Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, London, UK, WC2A 2AE (t.dewan@lse.ac.uk)
Francesco Squintani is a Professor of Economics Warwick University, Coventry, UK, CV4 7AL (F.Squintani@Warwick.ac.uk)

Abstract

Group members value informed decisions and hold ideological preferences. A leader takes a decision on their behalf. Good leadership depends on characteristics of moderation and judgment. The latter emerges (endogenously) via advice communicated by “trustworthy associates.” Trustworthy advice requires ideological proximity to the leader. A group may choose a relatively extreme leader with a large number of such associates. Paradoxically, this can happen though it is in the group’s collective interest to choose a moderate leader. To assess whether these insights persist when political groups compete, we embed our analysis in a model of elections. Each of two parties chooses a leader who implements her preferred policy if elected. We find that a party may choose an extreme leader who defeats a moderate candidate chosen by the opposing party. Our results highlight the importance of party cohesion and the relations between a leader and her party. These can be more important to electoral success than proximity of a leader’s position to the median voter.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We thank for their comments audiences at several seminars, including Harvard University, Stanford University, University of Chicago, Berkeley University, Princeton University, University of Rochester, and Washington University in St. Louis, and at several conferences, and Melissa Schwartzberg.

References

REFERENCES

Ansolabehere, Stephen D., and Snyder, James M.. 2000. “Valence Politics and Equilibrium in Spatial Election Models.” Public Choice 103 (3–4): 327–36.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen D., Snyder, James M., and Stewart, Charles H. III. 2001. “Candidate Positioning in U.S. House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 45: 136–59.Google Scholar
Aragones, Enriqueta, and Palfrey, Thomas R.. 2002. “Mixed Equilibrium in a Downsian Model with a Favored Candidate.” Journal of Economic Theory 103 (1): 131–61.Google Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan, Glazer, Ami, and Hammond, Thomas H.. 2001. “Theories of Delegation.” Annual Review of Political Science 4: 235–69.Google Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan, and Meirowitz, Adam. 2004. “Spatial Models of Delegation.” American Political Science Review 98 (2): 293310.Google Scholar
Bernhardt, Dan, Câmara, Odilon, and Squintani, Francesco. 2011. “Competence and Ideology.” Review of Economic Studies 78 (2): 487522.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy J., and Reynal-Querol, Marta. 2011. “Do Democracies Select More Educated Leaders?American Political Science Review 105 (3): 552–66.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy J., and Coate, Stephen. 1997. “An Economic Model of Representative Democracy.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112 (1): 85114.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1948. “On the Rationale of Group Decision-making”. Journal of Political Economy 56 (1): 2334.Google Scholar
Blair, Tony. 2010. A Journey. London: Random House.Google Scholar
Blaydes, Lisa, Grimmer, Justin, and McQueen, Alison. 2013. “Mirrors for Prices and Sultans: Advice on the Art of Governance in the Medieval Christian and Islamic Worlds.” Working Paper, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Brunnermeier, Markus K., Bolton, Patrick, and Veldkamp, Laura. 2013. “Leadership, Coordination and Corporate Culture.” Review of Economic Studies 80 (2): 512–37.Google Scholar
Burden, Barry C. 2004. “Candidate Positioning in US Congressional Elections.” British Journal of Political Science 34 (2): 211–27.Google Scholar
Callander, Steven, and Wilkie, Simon. 2007. “Lies, Damned Lies, and Political Campaigns.” Games and Economic Behavior 60 (2): 262–86.Google Scholar
Calvert, Randall L. 1995. “The Rational Choice Theory of Social Institutions: Cooperation, Coordination, and Communication.” In Modern Political Economy: Old Topics, New Directions, eds. Banks, Jeffrey S., and Hanushek, Eric A.. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 216–67.Google Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice. 2006. Who Leads Whom? Presidents, Policy, and the Public. Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Canes-Wrone, Brandice, Herron, Michael C., and Shotts, Kenneth W.. 2001. “Leadership and Pandering: A Theory of Executive Policymaking.” American Journal of Political Science 45 (3): 332–50.Google Scholar
Carlyle, Thomas. 1841. On Heroes, Hero-Worship, and The Heroic in History. London: James Fraser.Google Scholar
Chari, Varadarajan V., Jones, Larry E., and Marimon, Ramon. 1997. “The Economics of Split-Ticket Voting in Representative Democracies.” American Economic Review 87 (5): 957–76.Google Scholar
Clark, Tom. 2012. “Bargaining and Opinion Writing in the US Supreme Court.” In New Directions in Judicial Politics, ed. McGuire, Kevin. London: Routledge, 186204.Google Scholar
Dewan, Torun, Galeotti, Andrea, Ghiglino, Christain, and Squintani, Francesco. 2015. “Information Aggregation and Optimal Structure of the Executive.” American Journal of Political Science 59 (2): 475–94.Google Scholar
Dewan, Torun, and Myatt, David P.. 2007. “Leading the Party: Coordination, Direction and Communication.” American Political Science Review 101 (4): 825–43.Google Scholar
Dewan, Torun, and Myatt, David P.. 2008. “The Qualities of Leadership: Communication, Direction and Obfuscation.” American Political Science Review 102 (3): 351–68.Google Scholar
Dewan, Torun, and Squintani, Francesco. 2016. “In Defence of Factions.” American Journal of Political Science 60 (4): 860–81.Google Scholar
Egorov, Georgy, and Konstantin Sonin. 2011. “Dictators and Their Viziers: Endogenizing the Loyalty-Competence Trade-off.” Journal of the European Economic Association 9 (5): 903–30.Google Scholar
Galasso, Vincenzo, and Nannicini, Tommaso. 2011. “Competing on Good Politicians.” American Political Science Review 105 (1): 7999.Google Scholar
Galeotti, Andrea, Ghiglino, Christian, and Squintani, Francesco. 2013. “Information Transmission Networks.” Journal of Economic Theory 148 (5): 136–59.Google Scholar
Gans, Joshua S., and Smart, Michael. 1996. “Majority Voting with Single Crossing Preferences.” Journal of Public Economics 59: 219–37.Google Scholar
Groseclose, Timothy. 2001. “A Model of Candidate Location When One Candidate Has a Valence Advantage.” American Journal of Political Science 45 (4): 862–86.Google Scholar
Harstad, Bård. 2010. “Strategic Delegation and Voting Rules.” Journal of Public Economics 94 (1-2): 102–13.Google Scholar
Heath, Anthony F., Jowell, Roger M., and Curtice, John K.. 1983. “1983 British Election Study Cross-Section.” University of Essex.Google Scholar
Heath, Anthony F., Jowell, Roger M., and Curtice, John K.. 1987. “1987 British Election Study Cross-Section.” University of Essex.Google Scholar
Heath, Anthony F., Jowell, Roger M., and Curtice, John K.. 1992. “1992 British Election Study Cross-Section.” University of Essex.Google Scholar
Heath, Anthony F., Jowell, Roger M., and Curtice, John K.. 1997. “1997 British Election Study Cross-Section.” University of Essex.Google Scholar
Hermalin, Benjamin E. 1998. “Toward an Economic Theory of Leadership: Leading by Example.” American Economic Review 88: 1188–206.Google Scholar
Huber, John D., and Shipan, Charles R.. 2002. Deliberate Discretion?: The Institutional Foundations of Bureaucratic Autonomy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kearns Goodwin, Doris. 2005. Team of Rivals: The Political Genius of Abraham Lincoln. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 2007. “Supreme Court Appointments as a Move-the-Median Game.” American Journal of Political Science 51 (2): 231–40.Google Scholar
Levi, Margaret, and Ahlquist, John S.. 2011. “Leadership: What it means, what it does, and what we want to know about it.” Annual Review of Political Science 14: 124.Google Scholar
McCurley, Carl, and Mondak, Jeffery J.. 1995. “The Influence of Incumbents’ Competence and Integrity in U.S. House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 39 (4): 864– 85.Google Scholar
McGann, Anthony J. 2002. “The Advantages of Ideological Cohesion A Model of Constituency Representation and Electoral Competition in Multi-Party Democracies.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 14 (1): 3770.Google Scholar
McGann, Anthony J., Koetzle, William, and Grofman, Bernard. 2002. “How an Ideologically Concentrated Minority Can Trump a Dispersed Majority: Nonmedian Voter Results for Plurality, Run-off, and Sequential Elimination Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 46 (1): 134–47.Google Scholar
Michels, Robert. 1911. Zur Soziologie des Parteiwesens in der modernen Demokratie. Untersuchungen über die oligarchischen Tendenzen des Gruppenlebens. Leipzig, Germany: Werner Klinkhardt.Google Scholar
Osborne, Martin J., and Slivinski, Al. 1996. “A Model of Political Competition with Citizen-Candidates.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (1): 6596.Google Scholar
Patty, John W. 2013. “A Theory of Cabinet-Making: The Politics of Inclusion, Exclusion, and Information.” Working Paper, Washington University at St. Louis.Google Scholar
Patty, John W., and Penn, Elizabeth Margaret. 2014. “Sequential Decision Making and Information Aggregation in Small Networks.” Political Science Research and Methods 2 (2): 243–71.Google Scholar
Penn, Elizabeth Margaret. 2016. “Engagement, Disengagement, or Exit: A Theory of Equilibrium Associations.” American Journal of Political Science 60 (2): 322–36.Google Scholar
Rohde, David W., and Shepsle, Kenneth. 2007. “Advising and Consenting in the 60-Vote Senate: Strategic Appointments to the Supreme Court.” Journal of Politics 69 (3): 664–77.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1960. The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Stokes, Donald E. 1963. “Spatial Models of Party Competition.” American Political Science Review 57 (2): 368–77.Google Scholar
Stone, Walter J., and Simas, Elizabeth N.. 2010. “Candidate Valence and Ideological Positions in U.S. House Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 54 (2): 371–88.Google Scholar
Uhl-Bien, Mary. 2006. “Relational Leadership Theory: Exploring the Social Processes of Leadership and Organizing.” Leadership Quarterly 17 (6): 654–76.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Dewan and Squintani supplementary material 1

Online Appendix

Download Dewan and Squintani supplementary material 1(PDF)
PDF 266.2 KB