Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-ndmmz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-28T18:16:07.988Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 September 2009

Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Generating Predictability
Institutional Analysis and Design
, pp. 275 - 307
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2005

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adler, Matthew D. (2000). ‘Expressive Theories of Law. A Skeptical Overview.’ University of Pennsylvania Law Review 148: 1363–501CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. and Eric, A. Posner (1999). ‘Rethinking Cost-Benefit Analysis.’ Yale Law Journal 109: 165–247CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. and Eric, A. Posner(2000). ‘Cost–Benefit Analysis. Legal, Economic and Philosophical Perspectives. Introduction.’ Journal of Legal Studies 29: 837–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adomeit, Klaus (2003). ‘Der Rechtspositivismus im Denken von Hans Kelsen und von Gustav Radbruch.’ Juristenzeitung 58: 161–6Google Scholar
Ainslie, George (1992). Picoeconomics. The Strategic Interaction of Successive Motivational States within the Person. Cambridge,Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Ajzen, Icek (1991). ‘The Theory of Planned Behaviour.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 50: 179–211CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ajzen, Icek and Fishbein, Martin (1980). Understanding Attitudes and Predicting Social Behavior. Englewood Cliffs, N. J.,Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A. (1970). ‘The Market for “Lemons”. Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 488–500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albert, Hans (1978). Traktat über rationale Praxis. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Alchian, Armen A. (1950). ‘Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory.’ Journal of Political Economy 58: 211–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allais, Maurice (1953). ‘Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque. Critique des postulats et axiomes de l'école Américaine.’ Econometrica 21: 503–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allison, J. (1989). ‘The Nature of Reinforcement.’ Contemporary Learning Theories. Instrumental Conditioning and the Impact of Biological Constraints on Learning, ed. Klein, S. and Mowrer, R.. Hillsdale, Erlbaum: 13–39Google Scholar
Allport, Gordon W., Vernon, Philip Ewart and Powers, Edwin (1933). Studies in Expressive Movement. New York, MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, James E. and Alberto Alesina (1996). ‘Political Economy. An Overview.’ A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 645–74Google Scholar
Anderson, Elizabeth and Pildes, Richard H. (2000). ‘Expressive Theories of Law. A General Restatement.’ University of Pennsylvania Law Review 148: 1503–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, John R. (2000a). Cognitive Psychology and its Implications. New York, Worth PublishersGoogle Scholar
Anderson, John R.(2000b). Learning and Memory. An Integrated Approach. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Anderson, John R. and Lebiere, Christian (2003). ‘The Newell Test for a Theory of Cognition.’ Behavioral and Brain Sciences 26: 587–640CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Anderson, John R., Bothell, Daniel, Byrne, Michael D. and Lebiere, Christian (2004). ‘An Integrated Theory of the Mind.’ Psychological Review 111: 1036–60CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Anderson, Simon, Goeree, Jacob K. and Holt, Charles A. (1998). ‘A Theoretical Analysis of Altruism and Decision Error in Public Goods Games.’ Journal of Public Economics 70: 297–323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antonides, Gerrit (1996). Psychology in Economics and Business. An Introduction to Economic Psychology. Dordrecht and Boston, Kluwer AcademicGoogle Scholar
Apesteguia, José, Martin Dufwenberg and Richard Selten (2003). ‘Blowing the Whistle.’ Bonn Econ. Discussion Papers 9/2003. ftp://ftp.wiwi.uni-bonn.de/papers/bgse/2003/bgse9_2003.pdfCrossRef
Apter, David E. (1996). ‘Comparative Politics, Old and New.’ A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 372–97Google Scholar
Arce, Daniel G. and Sandler, Todd (2003). ‘An Evolutionary Game Approach to Fundamentalism and Conflict.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 159: 132–54Google Scholar
Arendt, Hannah (1951). The Origins of Totalitarianism. New York, Harcourt BraceGoogle Scholar
Arkes, Hal R. (1991). ‘Costs and Benefits of Judgment Errors – Implications for Debiasing.’ Psychological Bulletin 110 (3): 486–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arkes, Hal R. and Blumer, Catherine (1985). ‘The Psychology of Sunk Cost.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 35: 124–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (1963). Social Choice and Individual Values. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth Joseph(1987). ‘Rationality of Self and Others in an Economic System.’ Rational Choice : the Contrast between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W.. Chicago, Chicago University Press: 201–15Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation. New York, Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Ayton, Peter (2000). ‘Do the Birds and Bees Need Cognitive Reform?Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 666–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Babcock, Linda and George Loewenstein (2000). ‘Explaining Bargaining Impasse. The Role of Self-Serving Bias.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 355–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baird, Douglas G.,Gertner, Robert H. and Picker, Randal C. (1994). Game Theory and the Law. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, Richard E. (1989). ‘Sunk-Cost Hysteresis.’ National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 2911CrossRef
Bandura, Albert (1977). Social Learning Theory. Englewood Cliffs, N. J., Prenctice Hall
Banerjee, Abhijt V. (1992). ‘A Simple Model of Herd Behavior.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 797–817CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bargh, John A.,Chen, Mark and Burrows, Lara (1996). ‘Automaticity of Social Behavior. Direct Effects of Trait Construct and Stereotype Activation on Action.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 71: 230–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, Robert S. and Kerr, Norbert L. (2003). Group Process, Group Decisions, Group Action. Philadelphia, Open University PressGoogle Scholar
Bartlett, Frederic C. (1932). Remembering. A Study in Experimental and Social Psychology. Cambridge, The University PressGoogle Scholar
Bartling, Hartwig (1980). Leitbilder der Wettbewerbspolitik. Munich, VahlenGoogle Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, Roland Benabou and Lear Tirde (2002). ‘Self Control in Peer Groups.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=298448
Baumeister, Roy (1998). ‘The Self.’ The Handbook of Social Psychology, ed. DanielGilbert, T., Fiske, Susan T. and Lindzey, Gardner. Boston, McGraw-Hill: 680–740Google Scholar
Baxter, Terri L. and Goldberg, Lewis R. (1987). ‘Perceived Behavioral Consistency Underlying Trait Attribution to Oneself and Another. An Extension of the Actor–Observer Effect.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 13: 437–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayes, Thomas (1738). ‘An Essay toward Solving a Problem in the Doctrine of Chances.’ Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 53: 370–418CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaman, Arthur L.,Cole, Maureen C., Preston, Marilyn, Klentz, Bannel and Steblay, Nancy (1983). ‘Fifteen Years of Foot-in-the-Door Research.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 9: 181–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becht, Marco, Patrick Bolton and Ailsa Röell (2002). ‘Corporate Governance and Corporate Control.’ ECGI Working Paper Series in Finance 02/2002
Bechtold, Stefan (2002). Vom Urheber-zum Informationsrecht. Implikationen des Digital Rights Management. Munich, BeckGoogle Scholar
Beckenkamp, Martin (2003). ‘Soziales Dilemma “Umwelt”. Spieltheoretische und psychologische Aspekte von Umweltproblemen’ (mimeo)
Becker, Gary Stanley (1962). ‘Irrational Behaviour and Economic Theory.’ Journal of Political Economy 70: 1–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary Stanley(1976). The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary Stanley(1993). Human Capital: a Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. Chicago, University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bem, Daryl J. (1967). ‘Self-Perception. The Dependent Variable of Human Performance.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 2: 105–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bem, Daryl J.(1972). ‘Constructing Cross-Situational Consistencies in Behavior. Some Thoughts on Alker's Critique of Mischel.’ Journal of Personality 40: 17–26CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bem, Daryl J. and Allen, Andrea (1974). ‘On Predicting Some of the People Some of the Time. The Search for Cross-Situational Consistencies in Behavior.’ Psychological Review 81: 506–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benz, Matthias and Alois Stutzer (2002). ‘Do Workers Enjoy Procedural Utility?’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=336581CrossRef
Benz, Matthias, Bruno Frey and Alois Stutzer (2002). ‘Introducing Procedural Utility: Not Only What, but also How Matters.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=338568CrossRef
Berger, Peter L. and Luckmann, Thomas (1967). The Social Construction of Reality. A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City, N. Y.,DoubledayGoogle Scholar
Berle, Adolf Augustus and Coit Means, Gardiner (1932). Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York and Chicago, Commerce Clearing House Loose leaf service division of the Corporation Trust CompanyGoogle Scholar
Betsch, Tilmann, Plessner, Henning, Schwieren, Chistiane and Gütig, Robert (2001). ‘I Like It but I Don't Know Why. A Value-Account Approach to Implicit Attitude Formation.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 27: 242–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, Cristina, John Duffy and Gile Talle (2002). ‘Trust among Strangers.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=304344CrossRef
Biddle, Bruce J. (1986). ‘Recent Developments in Role Theory.’ Annual Review of Sociology 12: 67–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biddle, Bruce J. and Thomas, Edwin J. (1979). Role Theory. Concepts and Research. Huntington, N. Y., R. E. KriegerGoogle Scholar
Bikhchandani, Sushil, Hirshleifer, David and Welch, Ivo (1992). ‘A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change in Informational Cascades.’ Journal of Political Economy 100: 992–1026CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, Ann-Renee and Weber, Elke U. (2001). ‘Domain-Specificity and Gender Differences in Decision Making.’ Risk Decision and Policy 6: 47–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohner, Gerd (2001). ‘Attitudes.’ Introduction to Social Psychology, ed. Hewstone, Miles and Stroebe, Wolfgang. Oxford, Blackwell: 239–82Google Scholar
Bohnet, Iris and Robert D. Cooter (2001). ‘Expressive Law. Framing or Equilibrium Selection?’ http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~.ibohnet.academic.ksg/Bohnet_Cooter.doc
Bone, John, Hey, John D. and Suckling, John (1999). ‘Are Groups More (or Less) Consistent than Individuals?Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 8: 63–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonus, Holger (1981). ‘Emissionsrechte als Mittel der Privatisierung öffentlicher Ressourcen aus der Umwelt.’ Marktwirtschaft und Umwelt, ed. Wegehenkel, Lothar. Tübingen, Mohr: 54–77Google Scholar
Bornschier, Volker (2001). ‘Generalisiertes Vertrauen und die frühe Verbreitung der Internetnutzung im Gesellschaftsvergleich.’ Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 53: 233–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boudon, Raymond (1987). ‘The Individualistic Tradition in Sociology.’ The Micro–Macro Link, ed. Alexander, Jeffrey, Giesen, Bernard, Münch, Richard and Smelser, Neil. Berkeley, University of California Press: 45–70Google Scholar
Boyd, Robert and Richerson, Peter J. (1994). ‘The Evolution of Norms. An Anthropological View.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150: 72–87Google Scholar
Brandenburger, Adam and Nalebuff, Barry (1996). Co-opetition. New York, DoubledayGoogle Scholar
Brandts, Jordi, Tatsuyoshi Saijo and Arthur Schram (2002). ‘How Universal is Behavior? A Four Country Comparison of Spite, Cooperation and Errors in Voluntary Contribution Mechanisms.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=254454
Brehm, Jack Williams (1966). A Theory of Psychological Reactance. New York, Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Brehm, Sharon S. and Williams Brehm, Jack (1981). Psychological Reactance. A Theory of Freedom and Control. New York, Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey and Pettit, Philip (2000). ‘The Hidden Economy of Esteem.’ Economics and Philosophy 16: 77–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brenner, Thomas (1999). Modelling Learning in Economics. Cheltenham and Northampton, Mass., Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Breyer, Stephen G. (1993). Breaking the Vicious Circle. Toward Effective Risk Regulation. Cambridge, Mass.,Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Brickman, Philip and Donald T. Campbell (1971). ‘Hedonic Relativism and Planning the Good Society.’ Adaptation-Level Theory, ed. Appley, Mortimer H.. New York, Academic Press: 287–301Google Scholar
Brocas, Isabelle and Juan D. Carillo (2002). ‘Are We All Better Drivers than Average? Self-Perception and Biased Behaviour.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=353784
Brosig, Jeannette, Weimann, Joachim and Ockenfels, Axel (2003). ‘The Effect of Communication Media on Cooperation.’ German Economic Review 4: 217–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Donald E. (1991). Human Universals. New York, McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Brunswik, Egon, Hammond, Kenneth R. and Stewart, Thomas R. (2001). The Essential Brunswik. Beginnings, Explications, Applications. Oxford and New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. (1965). ‘An Economic Theory of Clubs.’ Economica 32: 1–14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962). The Calculus of Consent. Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, J. R. and Townsend, J. T. (1993). ‘Decision Field Theory. A Dynamic Cognitive Approach to Decision Making in an Uncertain Environment.’ Psychological Review 100: 432–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin F. (1987). ‘Do Biases in Probability Judgement Matter in Markets? Experimental Evidence.’ American Economic Review 77: 981–97Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin F.(1995). ‘Individual Decision Making.’ Handbook of Experimental Economics, ed. Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E.. Princeton, Princeton University Press: 587–703Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin F. and Lovallo, Dan (1999). ‘Overconfidence and Excess Entry: an Experimental Approach.’ American Economic Review 89: 306–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, Judy (2001). ‘Negative Effects of Reward on Intrinsic Motivation: a Limited Phenomenon. Comment on Deci, Koestner, and Ryan (2001).’ Review of Educational Research 71: 29–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, Judy and Pierce, W. David (2001). Rewards and Intrinsic Motivation. Resolving the Controversy. Westport, BerginGoogle Scholar
Camp, Jean (2000). Trust and Risk in Internet Commerce. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Caplan, Bryan (2004). ‘Rational Ignorance.’ Encyclopedia of Public Choice, ed. Rowley, Charles K. and Schneider, Friedrich. Boston, KluwerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, Jeffrey (2002). ‘Punishing Free-Riders. How Group Size Affects Mutual Monitoring and the Provision of Public Goods. Middlebury Economics Discussion Paper 02–06. http://www.middlebury.edu/~econ/RePec/papers/02-06.pdf
Chaiken, Shelly and Trope, Yaacov (1999). Dual-process Theories in Social Psychology. New York, Guilford PressGoogle Scholar
Chamberlin, Edward (1933). The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Chapman, Gretchen B. and Bornstein, Brian H. (1996). ‘The More You Ask for, the More You Get. Anchoring in Personal Injury Verdicts.’ Applied Cognitive Psychology 10: 519–403.0.CO;2-5>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chapman, Gretchen B. and Johnson, Eric J. (1999). ‘Anchoring, Activation, and the Construction of Values.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 79: 115–53CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Charness, Gary and Haruvy, Ernan (2002). ‘Altruism, Equity, and Reciprocity in a Gift-Exchange Experiment. An Encompassing Approach.’ Games and Economic Behavior 40: 203–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John Maurice (1961). Competition as a Dynamic Process. Washington, D.C., Brookings InstitutionGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald (1937). ‘The Nature of the Firm.’ Economica 4: 386–405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald(1960). ‘The Problem of Social Cost.’ Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coglianese, Cary (2002). ‘Is Satisfaction Success? Evaluating Public Participation in Regulatory Policymaking.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=331420CrossRef
Cohen, Michael D. and Sproull, Lee S., eds. (1995). Organizational Learning. London, SageGoogle Scholar
Coleman, James Samuel (1987). ‘Psychological Structure and Social Structure in Economics Models.’ Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W.. Chicago, University of Chicago Press: 181–5Google Scholar
Coleman, James Samuel(1990). Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, Mass., Belknap Press of Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Collins, R. Lorraine and Clara M. Bradizza (2001). ‘Social and Cognitive Learning Processes.’ International Handbook of Alcohol Dependence and Problems, ed. Heather, Nick and Peters, Timothy J.. Chichester, Wiley: 317–37Google Scholar
Condorcet, Marie Jean Antoine Nicolas de Caritat, Marquis, (1785). Essai sur l'application de l'analyse de la probabilité des decisions rendues à la pluralité des voix. Paris, Imprimerie RoyaleGoogle Scholar
Conlisk, John (1996). ‘Why Bounded Rationality?Journal of Economic Literature 34: 669–700Google Scholar
Cook, Karen S., ed. (2001). Trust in Society, Russell Sage Foundation series on trust, vol. II. New York, Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Cooter, Robert (1998). ‘Expressive Law and Economics.’ Journal of Legal Studies 27: 585–608CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas (2004). Law and Economics. Boston, Addison Wesley LongmanGoogle Scholar
Cornes, Richard and Sandler, Todd (1996). The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club Goods. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John (1989). ‘Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture: II. Case Study: a Computational Theory of Social Exchange.’ Ethology and Sociobiology 10: 51–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John(1992). ‘Cognitive Adaptations for Social Exchange.’ The Adapted Mind. Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, ed. Barkow, Jerome, Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John. New York, Oxford University Press: 163–228Google Scholar
Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John(1994). ‘Better than Rational. Evolutionary Psychology and the Invisible Hand.’ American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 84: 327–32Google Scholar
Cowan, Robin, David, Paul A. and Dominique, Foray, (2000). ‘The Explicit Economics of Knowledge Codification and Tacitness.’ Industrial and Corporate Change 9: 211–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, Vincent (1998). ‘A Survey of Experiments on Communication via Cheap Talk.’ Journal of Economic Theory 78 (2): 286–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Czybulka, Detlef (1995). ‘Gewerbenebenrecht. Handwerksrecht and Gaststättenrecht.’ Öffentliches Wirtschaftsrecht Besonderer Teil 1, ed. Schmidt, Reiner. Berlin, Springer: 111–218CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalton, Russell D. (1996). ‘Comparative Politics: Micro-Behavioral Perspectives.’ A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 336–52Google Scholar
Dawes, Robyn M. (1999). ‘A Message from Psychologists to Economists: Mere Predictability Doesn't Matter Like It Should (without a Good Story Appended to It).’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 39: 29–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, Edward L. (1975). Intrinsic Motivation. New York, Plenum PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, Edward L. and Ryan, Richard M. (1985). Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behaviour. New York, Plenum PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, Edward L.,Koestner, Richard and Ryan, Richard M. (1999). ‘A Meta-Analytic Review of Experiments Examining the Effects of Extrinsic Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation.’ Psychological Bulletin 125: 627–68CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Deci, Edward L.,Koestner, Richard, and Ryan, Richard M. (2001a). ‘Extrinsic Rewards and Intrinsic Motivation in Education. Reconsidered Once Again.’ Review of Educational Research 71: 1–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, Edward L.,Ryan, Richard M. and Koestner, Richard (2001b). ‘The Pervasive Negative Effects of Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation: Response to Cameron (2001).’ Review of Educational Research 71: 43–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dekel, Eddie, Lipman, Barton L. and Rustichini, Aldo (1998). ‘Standard State-Space Models Preclude Unawareness.’ Econometrica 66: 159–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delgado, Jose M. R. (2000). ‘Neuronal Imprinting of Human Values.’ International Journal of Psychophysiology 35: 237–46CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Denzau, Arthur and Cecil North, Douglass (1994). ‘Shared Mental Models. Ideologies and Institutions.’ Kyklos 47: 3–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Descartes, René (1664). De Homine. Lvgdvni Batavorvm, Officina HackianaGoogle Scholar
Dessler, David (1989). ‘What's at Stake in the Agent–Structure Debate?International Organization 43: 441–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Devetag, Giovanna (2000). ‘From Utilities to Mental Models. A Critical Survey on Decision Rules and Cognition in Consumer Choice.’ Industrial and Corporate Change 8: 289–351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickenberger, Dorothee, Gisla Gniech and Hans-Joachim Grabitz (1993). ‘Die Theorie der psychologischen Reaktanz.’ Theorien der Sozialpsychologie I: Kognitive Theorien, ed. Frey, Dieter and Irle, Martin. Berne, Huber: 243–74Google Scholar
Dillard, James, Hunter, John and Burgoon, Michael (1984). ‘Sequential Request Persuasive Strategies. Meta-Analysis of Foot-in-the-Door and Door-in-the-Face.’ Human Communication Research 10: 461–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dilthey, Wilhelm (1923). ‘Die Entstehung der Hermeneutik.’ Gesammelte Schriften V, ed. Dilthey, Wilhelm. Leipzig, Teubner: 317–31Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J. (1998). ‘The New Institutionalisms. Avenues of Collaboration.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 154: 696–705Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell (1991). ‘Introduction.’ The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, ed. Powell, Walter W. and DiMaggio, Paul J.. Chicago, University of Chicago Press: 1–38Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash K. and Nalebuff, Barry J. (1991). Thinking Strategically. The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics, and Everyday Life. New York, NortonGoogle Scholar
Domjan, Michael (1998). The Principles of Learning and Behavior. Pacific Grove, Calif.,Brooks/ColeGoogle Scholar
Donald, Merlin (1999). ‘Hominid Enculturation and Cognitive Evolution.’ Cognition and Material Culture. The Archaeology of Symbolic Storage, ed. Renfrew, Colin and Scarre, Chris. Cambridge, McDonald Institute for Archaeological Research: 7–17Google Scholar
Donnell, A. J., Thomas, A. and Buboltz, W. C. (2001). ‘Psychological Reactance. Factor Structure and Internal Consistency of the Questionnaire for the Measurement of Psychological Reactance.’ Journal of Social Psychology 141 (5): 679–87CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Druckman, James (2001). ‘Using Credible Advice to Overcome Framing Effects.’ Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 17: 62–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dudycha, G. J. (1936). ‘An Objective Study in Personality.’ Archives of Psychology 29: 1–53Google Scholar
Dunn, John (1988). ‘Trust and Political Agency.’ Trust. Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations, ed. Gambetta, David. New York, Blackwell: 73–93Google Scholar
Easton, David (1965). A Systems Analysis of Political Life. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Edelman, Murray J. (1964). The Symbolic Uses of Politics. Urbana, University of Illinois PressGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990). Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichberger, Jürgen, David Kelsey and Burkhard Schipper (2003). ‘Ambiguity and Social Interaction.’ http://with1.awi.uni-heidelberg.de/Publik/social-interaction-dk.pdfCrossRef
Eichenberger, Reiner (2002). ‘Wissen und Information in ökonomischer Perspektive.’ Wissen, Nichtwissen, Unsicheres Wissen, ed. Engel, Christoph, Halfmann, Jost and Schulte, Martin. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 75–92Google Scholar
Eisenberg, Andrea (2001). Stabilität and Wandel informeller Institutionen. Selbstorganisation und interdependente Prozesse. Wiesbaden, GablerGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. (1991). Order without Law. How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, Mass.,Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ellsberg, Daniel (1961). ‘Risk, Ambiguity, and the Savage Axioms.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 75: 643–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon (1979). Ulysses and the Sirens. Studies in Rationality and Irrationality. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon(1989). The Cement of Society. A Study of Social Order. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon(1998). ‘Emotions and Economic Theory.’ Journal of Economic Literature 36: 47–74Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph (1999). ‘Vertrauen – ein Versuch.’ Preprints aus der Max-Planck-Projektgruppe Recht der Gemeinschaftsgüter Bonn 1999/12
Engel, Christoph(2000). ‘The Internet and the Nation State.’ Understanding the Impact of Global Networks on Local Social, Political and Cultural Values, ed. Engel, Christoph and Keller, Kenneth H.. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 201–60Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2001a). ‘Die Grammatik des Rechts.’ Instrumente des Umweltschutzes im Wirkungsverbund, ed. Rengeling, Hans-Werner. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 17–49Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2001b). ‘Hybrid Governance across National Jurisdictions as a Challenge to Constitutional Law.’ European Business Organisation Law Review 2: 569–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2001c). ‘Institutionen zwischen Staat und Markt.’ Die Verwaltung 34: 1–24Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2001d). ‘Offene Gemeinwohldefinitionen.’ Rechtstheorie 32: 23–52Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2002a). Abfallrecht und Abfallpolitik. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2002b). ‘Die soziale Funktion des Eigentums.’ Bericht zur Lage des Eigentums, ed. Depenheuer, Otto, Engel, Christoph and Danwitz, Thomas. Berlin, Springer: 1–107Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2003a). ‘Causes and Management of Conflicts.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 159: 1–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2003b). ‘The Constitutional Court – Applying the Proportionality Principle – as a Subsidiary Authority for the Assessment of Political Outcomes.’ Linking Political Science and the Law, ed. Engel, Christoph and Héritier, Adrienne. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 285–314Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2003c). ‘Governing the Egalitarians from Without. The Case of the Internet.’ Preprints aus der Max-Planck-Projektgruppe Recht der Gemeinschaftsgüter 2003/10
Engel, Christoph(2003d). ‘Die Internet-Service-Provider als Geiseln deutscher Ordnungsbehörden. Eine Kritik der Verfügungen der Bezirksregierung Düsseldorf.’ Multimedia und Recht 6, supplement 4: 1–35Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2004a). ‘A Constitutional Framework for Private Governance.’ German Law Journal 5: 197–236Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2004b). ‘Marktabgrenzung als soziale Konstruktion.’ Festschrift Immenga, ed. Fuchs, Andreas, Schwintowski, Hans Peter and Zimmer, Daniel. Munich, Beck: 127–47Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(forthcoming) ‘Autonomie und Freiheit’ Handbuch der Grundrechte II, ed. Merten, Detlef and Papier, Hans-Jürgen. Heidelberg, C. F. Müller
Engel, Christoph and Schweizer, Urs (2002). ‘Organising and Designing Markets.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 158: 1–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelmann, Dirk (2001). ‘Asymmetric Type Recognition with Applications to Dilemma Games.’ Metronomica 52: 357–75Google Scholar
Beate, Englich and Mussweiler, Thomas (2001). ‘Sentencing under Uncertainty. Anchoring Effects in the Court Room.’ Journal of Applied Social Psychology 31: 1535–51Google Scholar
Epley, Nicolas and Gilovich, Thomas (2001). ‘Putting Adjustment Back in the Anchoring and Adjustment Heuristic. Differential Processing of Self-Generated and Experimenter-Provided Anchors.’ Psychological Science 12: 391–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, S. (1977). ‘Traits are Alive and Well.’ Personality at the Crossroads: Current Issues in Interactional Psychology, ed. Magnusson, David and Endler, Norman Solomon. Hillsdale, Erlbaum: 83–98Google Scholar
Epstein, S(1979). ‘The Stability of Behavior. I. On Predicting Most of the People Most of the Time.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 37: 1097–126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eriksson, Anders and Lindgren, Kristian (2002). ‘Cooperation in an Unpredictable Environment.’ Artificial Life 8: 394–99Google Scholar
Evans, Jonathan St. B. T. (1993). ‘Bias and Rationality.’ Rationality. Psychological and Philosophical Perspectives, ed. Manktelow, K. I. and Over, David E.. London, Routledge: 6–29Google Scholar
Evans, Jonathan B. T. St and Over, David E. (1997). ‘Are People Rational? Yes, No, and Sometimes.’ Psychologist: 403–6Google Scholar
Falk, Armin, Fehr, Ernst and Fischbacher, Urs (2003). ‘Reasons for Conflict. Lessons from Bargaining Experiments.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 159: 171–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farnsworth, Ward (2000). ‘Do Parties to Nuisance Cases Bargain after Judgement? A Glimpse into the Cathedral.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 302–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farnsworth, Ward(2001). ‘The Taste for Fairness.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=305761
Farnsworth, Ward(2002). ‘The Economics of Enmity.’ University of Chicago Law Review 69: 211–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farnsworth, Ward(2003). ‘The Legal Management of Self-Serving Bias.’ University of California at Davis Law Review 37: 567–603Google Scholar
Farrell, Joseph and Rabin, Matthew (1996). ‘Cheap Talk.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 10: 103–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fazio, Russell H. (1990). ‘Multiple Processes by which Attitudes Guide Behavior. The MODE Model as an Integrative Framework.’ Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 23, ed. Zanna, Mark P.. San Diego, Academic Press: 75–109Google Scholar
Fazio, Russell H.(2001). ‘On the Automatic Activation of Associated Evaluations. An Overview.’ Cognition and Emotion 15: 115–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst (2000). ‘Cooperation and Punishment in Public Goods Experiments.’ American Economic Review 90: 980–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Falk, Armin (2002). ‘Psychological Foundations of Incentives.’ European Economic Review 46: 687–724CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Simon Gaechter (2001). ‘Do Incentive Contracts Crowd out Voluntary Cooperation?’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=289680
Fehr, Ernst and Simon Gaechter(2002). ‘Do Incentive Contracts Undermine Voluntary Cooperation?’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=313028CrossRef
Fehr, Ernst and Schmidt, Klaus M. (1999). ‘A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 817–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Klaus M. Schmidt(2000). ‘Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity – Evidence and Economic Applications.’ CESifo Working Paper Series No. 403. http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=255223
Fehr, Ernst and Tyran, Jean-Robert (1996). ‘How Do Institutions and Fairness Interact?Central European Journal for Operations Research & Economics 4: 69–84Google Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Zych, Peter K. (1998). ‘Do Addicts Behave Rationally?Scandinavian Journal of Economics 100: 643–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, Gaechter, Simon and Kirchsteiger, Georg (1997). ‘Reciprocity as a Contract Enforcement Device. Experimental Evidence.’ Econometrica 65: 833–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, Allan M. (1980). Welfare Economics and Social Choice Theory. Boston, Martinus NijhoffCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferejohn, John A. and Fiorina, Morris P. (1974). ‘The Paradox of Not Voting. A Decision Theoretic Analysis.’ American Political Science Review 68: 525–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Festinger, Leon (1957). A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. Evanston, Ill., Row PetersonGoogle Scholar
Festinger, Leon and Carlsmith, James M. (1959). ‘Cognitive Consequences of Forced Compliance.’ Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 58: 203–10CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fiedler, Klaus (2000). ‘Beware of Samples! A Cognitive-Ecological Sampling Approach to Judgement Bias.’ Psychological Review 107: 659–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiedler, Klaus, Walther, Eva and Nickel, Stefanie (1999). ‘The Autoverification of Social Hypotheses. Stereotyping and the Power of Sample Size.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 77: 5–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiedler, Klaus, Schmid, Jeannette and Stahl, Teresa (2002). ‘What is the Current Truth about Polygraph Lie Detection?Basic and Applied Social Psychology 24: 313–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, Baruch (2000). ‘Value Elicitation. Is There Anything in There?’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 620–41Google Scholar
Fishbein, Martin and Ajzen, Icek (1975). Belief, Attitude, Intention, and Behavior. An Introduction to Theory and Research. Reading, Mass., Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Fiske, Alan Page (1991). Structures of Social Life. The Four Elementary Forms of Human Relations: Communal Sharing, Authority Ranking, Equality Matching, Market Pricing. New York, Free Press and MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Forest Nelson, George Newman and Jack Wright (1991). ‘The Iowa Presidential Stock Market. A Field Experiment.’ Research in Experimental Economics, ed. Isaac, R. Mark. Greenwich, Conn., JAI Press: 1–43Google Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Lundholm, Russell and Rietz, Thomas (1999). ‘Cheap Talk, Fraud, and Adverse Selection in Financial Markets. Some Experimental Evidence.’ Review of Financial Studies 12: 481–518CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, Craig R. and Amos Tversky (2000). ‘Ambiguity Aversion and Comparative Ignorance.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 528–42Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. (1985). Choosing the Right Pond. Human Behavior and the Quest for Status. New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H.(1988). Passions within Reason. The Strategic Role of the Emotions. New York, NortonGoogle Scholar
Freedman, Jonathan L. and Scott, C. Fraser (1966). ‘Compliance without Pressure. The Foot-in-the-Door Technique.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 4: 195–202CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Frey, Bruno S. ed. (1999a). Economics as a Science of Human Behaviour. Towards a New Social Science Paradigm. Boston and Dordrecht, KluwerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno(1999b). ‘The Price System and Morals.’ Economics as a Science of Human Behaviour. Towards a New Social Science Paradigm, ed. Frey, Bruno. Boston: 159–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno and Eichenberger, Reiner (1994). ‘Economic Incentives Transform Psychological Anomalies.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 23: 215–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno and Jegen, Reto (2001). ‘Motivation Crowding Theory. A Survey of Empirical Evidence.’ Journal of Economic Surveys 15: 589–611CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno and Alois Stutzer (2001). ‘Beyond Bentham – Measuring Procedural Utility.’ CESifo Working Papers 492. http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=268059.
Frey, Bruno and Stutzer, Alois(2002). Happiness and Economics. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Daniel (1998). ‘Monty Hall's Three Doors. Construction and Deconstruction of a Choice Anomaly.’ American Economic Review 88: 933–46Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1953). Essays in Positive Economics. [Chicago], University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Friedmann, Daniel (1989). ‘The Efficient Breach Fallacy.’ Journal of Legal Studies 18: 1–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedrich, James (2000). ‘Fleshing out a Dual-system Solution.’ Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 671–2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frowein, Jochen A. (2000). ‘Konstitutionalisierung des Völkerrechts.’ Berichte der Deutschen Gesellschaft für Völkerrecht 39: 427–47Google Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew and , David K. Levine (1998). The Theory of Learning in Games. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Funder, David C. (2000). ‘Gone with the Wind. Individual Differences in Heuristics and Biases Undermine the Implication of Systematic Irrationality.’ Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 673–4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Funder, David C. and Colvin, C. Randall (1991). ‘Explorations in Behavioral Consistency. Properties of Persons, Situations and Behaviors.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 60: 773–94CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Furubotn, Eirik Grundtvig and Richter, Rudolf (1997). Institutions and Economic Theory. The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Garvin, Susan and Kagel, John H. (1994). ‘Learning in Common Value Auctions – Some Initial Observations.’ Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 25 (3): 351–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geertz, Clifford (1973). ‘Thick Description. Toward an Interpretive Theory of Culture.’ The Interpretation of Cultures, ed. Geertz, Clifford. New York, Basic Books: 3–30Google Scholar
Gehlen, Arnold (1960). ‘Mensch and Institutionen.’ Anthropologische Forschung. Zur Selbstbegegnung und Selbstentdeckung des Menschen, ed. Gehlen, Arnold. Hamburg, Rowohlt: 69–77Google Scholar
Geiger, Theodor Julius and Rehbinder, Manfred (1987). Vorstudien zu einer Soziologie des Rechts. Berlin, Duncker & HumblotCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gentner, Dedre and Stevens, Albert L. (1983). Mental Models. Hillsdale, N. J., ErlbaumGoogle Scholar
Gentner, Dedre, Holyoak, Keith J. and Kokinov, Boicho N., eds. (2001). The Analogical Mind. Perspectives from Cognitive Science.Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press
Gérard-Varet, L. A., Kolm, Serge-Christophe and Ythier, J. Mercier, eds. (2000). The Economics of Reciprocity, Giving, and Altruism. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Macmillan; New York, St Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert (1998). ‘Incentives in Organizations.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 12: 115–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gifford, Sharon (2001). ‘Limited Attention as the Bound on Rationality.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=262181
Gigerenzer, Gerd, ed. (2000a). Adaptive Thinking. Rationality in the Real World. Oxford, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd(2000b). ‘How to Make Cognitive Illusions Disappear.’ Adaptive Thinking. Rationality in the Real World, ed. Gigerenzer, Gerd. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 241–66Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd, Todd, Peter M. and ABC Research Group (1999). Simple Heuristics that Make us Smart. New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Glenn, H. Patrick (1997). ‘The Capture, Reconstruction and Marginalization of “Custom”.’ American Journal of Comparative Law 45: 613–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glimcher, Paul W. (2003). Decisions, Uncertainty, and the Brain. The Science of Neuroeconomics. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Gode, Dhananjay K. and Sunder, Shyam (1993). ‘Allocative Efficiency of Markets with Zero-Intelligence Traders. Market as a Partial Substitute for Individual Irrationality.’ Journal of Political Economy 101: 119–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goffman, Erving (1956). The Presentation of Self in Everyday Life. Edinburgh, University of Edinburgh Social Sciences Research CentreGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, William M. and Robin M. Hogarth (1997). ‘Judgment and Decision Research. Some Historical Context.’ Research on Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 3–65Google Scholar
Goldstein, William M. and Elke U. Weber (1997). ‘Content and Discontent. Indications and Implications of Domain Specificity in Preferential Decision Making.’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 566–617Google Scholar
Granovetter, Marc (1985). ‘Economic Action and Social Structure. The Problem of Embeddedness.’ American Journal of Sociology 91: 481–510CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grether, David M. (1980). ‘Bayes' Rule as a Descriptive Model. The Representativeness Heuristic.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 95: 537–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grether, David M.(1992). ‘Testing Bayes' Rule and the Representativeness Heuristic: Some Experimental Evidence.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 17: 31–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grunberg, Emile and Modigliani, Franco (1954). ‘The Predictability of Social Events.’ Journal of Political Economy 52: 465–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruter, Margaret and Masters, Roger D., eds. (1986). Ostracism. A Social and Biological Phenomenon. New York, ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Guesnerie, Roger (2001). ‘The Government and Market Expectations.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 157: 116–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, Werner and Hartmut Kliemt (2003). ‘Perfect or Bounded Rationality? Some Facts, Speculations and Proposals’ (mimeo)
Güth, Werner, Schmittberger, Rolf and Schwarze, Bernd (1982). ‘An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3: 367–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter and Taylor, Rosemary C. R. (1996). ‘Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms.’ Political Studies 44: 936–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. (1932). ‘Institution.’ Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, ed. Seligman, Edwin R. A. and Johnson, Alvin. New York, Macmillan: 84–9Google Scholar
Hammond, Daniel J. (1990). ‘Realism in Friedman's Essays in Positive Economics.’ Perspectives on the History of Economic Thought. Vol. IV. Keynes, Macroeconomics and Method. Selected Papers from the History of Economics Society Conference, ed. Moggridge, Donald E.. Aldershot, Edward Elgar: 194–208Google Scholar
Hanoch, Yaniv (2002). ‘Neither an Angel nor an Ant: Emotion as an Aid to Bounded Rationality.’ Journal of Economic Psychology 23: 1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansjürgens, Bernd and Lübbe-Wolff, Gertrude, eds. (2000). Symbolische Umweltpolitik. Frankfurt, SuhrkampGoogle Scholar
Harbaugh, William T. and Krause, Kate (2000). ‘Children's Altruism in Public Good and Dictator Experiments.’ Economic Inquiry 38: 95–109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Garrett (1968). ‘The Tragedy of the Commons.’ Science 162: 1243–8Google ScholarPubMed
Hardin, Russell (2001). ‘Conceptions and Explanations of Trust.’ Trust in Society, ed. Cook, Karen S.. New York, Russell Sage Foundation: 3–39Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell(2002). Trust and Trustworthiness. New York, Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Harless, David W. and Camerer, Colin F. (1994). ‘The Predictive Utility of Generalized Expected Utility Theories.’ Econometrica 62: 1251–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John (1967–68). ‘Games with Incomplete Information Played by “Bayesian” Players.’ Management Science 14: 159–82, 320–4, 486–502CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartshorne, Hugh, Arthur May, Mark, Maller, Julius Bernard and Shuttleworth, Frank K. (1928). Studies in the Nature of Character. New York, MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Hartwick, John M. and Olewiler, Nancy D. (1998). The Economics of Natural Resource Use. Reading, Mass., Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Hastie, Reid and Bernadette Park (1997). ‘The Relationship between Memory and Judgement Depends on whether the Judgement Task is Memory-Based or On-Line.’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 431–53Google Scholar
Hayashi, Nahoko, Ostrom, Elinor, Walker, James M. and Yanagishi, Toshio (1999). ‘Reciprocity, Trust, and the Sense of Control. A Cross-Societal Study.’ Rationality and Society 11: 27–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heath, Chip (1995). ‘Escalation and De-Escalation of Commitment in Response to Sunk Costs. The Role of Budgeting in Mental Accounting.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 62: 38–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hebb, Donald O. (1949). The Organization of Behavior. A Neuropsychological Theory. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Heifetz, Aviad, Martin Meier and Burkhard Schipper (2003). ‘Interactive Unawareness and Speculative Trade.’ http://www.tau.ac.il/~heifetz/interactive_unawareness.pdf
Heiner, Ronald A. (1983). ‘The Origin of Predictable Behavior.’ American Economic Review 73: 560–95Google Scholar
Heiner, Ronald A.(1985a). ‘Origin of Predictable Behavior: Further Modeling and Applications.’ American Economic Review 75: 391–6Google Scholar
Heiner, Ronald A.(1985b). ‘Predictable Behavior: Reply.’ American Economic Review 75: 579–85Google Scholar
Heiner, Ronald A.(1989). ‘The Origin of Predictable Dynamic Behavior.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 12: 233–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, Joseph and Robert Boyd (2001). ‘“Economic Man” in Cross-Cultural Perspective. Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies.’ http://www.sscnet.ucla.edu/anthro/faculty/boyd/MacGamesBBSFinal.pdf
Hermalin, Benjamin E. and Alice M. Isen (1999). ‘The Effect of Affect on Economic and Strategic Decision Making.’ University of California, Berkeley, Department of Economics Working Paper: E99/270
Hirschman, Albert O. (1970). Exit, Voice, and Loyalty. Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1987). ‘On the Emotions as Guarantors of Threats and Promises.’ The Latest on the Best: Essays on Evolution and Optimality, ed. Dupre, John. Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press: 307–26Google Scholar
Hirt, Edward R. and Markman, Keith D. (1995). ‘Multiple Explanation – a Consider-an-Alternative Strategy for Debiasing Judgments.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 69 (6): 1069–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas (1651). Leviathan, or, The matter, forme, & power of a common-wealth ecclesiasticall and civill. London, Printed for Andrew Crooke, i.e. Crooke at the Green Dragon in St Pauls Church-yard
Hodgson, Geoffrey Martin (1988). Economics and Institutions. A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics. Philadelphia, University of Pennsylvania PressGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey Martin(1998). ‘The Approach of Institutional Economics.’ Journal of Economic Literature 36: 166–92Google Scholar
Hoffmann, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1985). ‘Entitlements, Rights, and Fairness. An Experimental Examination of Subject's Concepts of Distributive Justice.’ Journal of Legal Studies 14: 259–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffrage, Ulrich, Gigerenzer, Gerd, Krauss, Stefan and Mastignan, Larva (2002). ‘Representation Facilitates Reasoning. What Natural Frequencies Are and What They Are Not.’ Cognition 84: 343–52CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hogarth, Robin M. and Howard Kunreuther (1997). ‘Decision Making under Ignorance. Arguing with Yourself.’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 482–508Google Scholar
Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W., eds. (1986). Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology. Chicago, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hogarth, Robin M., Brian J. Gibbs, Craig R. M. McKerzie and Margaret A. Marquis (1997). ‘Learning from Feedback. Exactingness and Incentives.’ Research on Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 244–84Google Scholar
Holzinger, Katharina (2003). ‘The Problems of Collective Action. A New Approach.’ http://www.mpp-rdg.mpg.de/pdf_dat/2003_2.pdf
Homann, Karl and Suchanek, Andreas (2000). Ökonomik. Eine Einführung. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Honderich, Ted, ed. (1985). Morality and Rehibutive Emotions: a Tribute to John L. Maclire. London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Hopkins, Nick and Murdoch, Neil (1999). ‘The Role of the “Other” in National Identity. Exploring the Context-Dependence of the National Ingroup Stereotype.’ Journal of Community & Applied Social Psychology 9: 321–383.0.CO;2-M>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, Christopher K. (2000). ‘Attribute Evaluability. Its Implications for Joint-Separate Evaluation Reversals and Beyond.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 543–63Google Scholar
Hsee, Christopher K., Zhang, Jiao, Yu, Fang and Xi, Yiheng (2003). ‘Lay Rationalism, and Inconsistency between Decision and Predicted Experience.’ Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 16: 257–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hume, David (1739). A Treatise of Human Nature. Oxford, Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Immergut, Ellen M. (1998). ‘The Theoretical Core of the New Institutionalism.’ Politics and Society 26: 5–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackman, Simon and Paul M. Sniderman (2002). ‘Institutional Organization of Choice Spaces. A Political Conception of Political Psychology.’ Political Psychology, ed. Monroe, K. R.. Mahweh, Erlbaum: 209–24Google Scholar
Jakobs, Günther (1999). Norm, Person, Gesellschaft. Vorüberlegungen zu einer Rechtsphilosophie. Berlin, Duncker & HumblotGoogle Scholar
James, William (1890). The Principles of Psychology. New York, H. HoltGoogle Scholar
Janssen, Maarten W. C. and Mendys, Ewa (2004). ‘The Price of a Price. On the Crowding out of Social Norms.’ Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organization 55: 377–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Japp, Klaus P. (2002). ‘Struktureffekte öffentlicher Risikokommunikation auf Regulierungsregime. Zur Funktion von Nichtwissen im BSE-Konflikt,’ in Wissen, Nichtwissen, Unsicheres Wissen, ed. Engel, Christoph, Halfmann, Jost and Schulte, Martin. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 35–74Google Scholar
Jensen, Michael C. and Meckling, William H. (1976). ‘Theory of the Firm. Managerial Behaviour, Agency Cost and Ownership Structure.’ Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jickeli, Joachim (1990). Marktzutrittsschranken im Recht der Wettbewerbsbeschränkungen. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Jickeli, Joachim(1996). Der langfristige Vertrag. Eine rechtswissenschaftliche Untersuchung auf institutionen-ökonomischer Grundlage. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Johnson-Laird, Philip N. (1983). Mental Models. Towards a Cognitive Science of Language, Inference and Consciousness. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Johnson-Laird, Philip N.(1989). ‘Mental Models.’ Foundations of Cognitive Science, ed. Posner, Michael. Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press: 469–99Google Scholar
Jolls, Christine (2000). ‘Behavioural Economic Analysis of Redistributive Legal Rules.’ Behavioural Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 288–301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jolls, Christine, Sunstein, Cass R. and Thaler, Richard H. (1998). ‘A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics.’ Stanford Law Review 50: 1471–550CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jolls, Christine, Sunstein, Cass R., and Thaler, Richard H.(2000). ‘A Behavioural Approach to Law and Economics.’ Behavioural Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 13–58Google Scholar
Jones, Edward Ellsworth and Richard E. Nisbett (1972). ‘The Actor and the Observer. Divergent Perceptions of the Causes of Behavior.’ Attribution. Perceiving the Causes of Behavior, ed. Jones, Edward Ellsworth. Morristown, General Learning Press: 79–94Google Scholar
Jones, Phil, ed. (1999). Taboo. Philadelphia, Jessika KingsleyGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel (1986). ‘Fairness and the Assumptions of Economics.’ Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W.. Chicago, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel(1992). ‘Reference Points, Anchors, Norms, and Mixed Feelings.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 51: 296–312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel(2000a). ‘Evaluation by Moments. Past and Future.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 693–708Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel(2000b). ‘Experienced Utility and Objective Happiness. A Moment-Based Approach.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambrdige University Press: 673–92Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel(2000c). Preface. Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: ix–xviiGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Dan Lovallo (2000). ‘Timid Choices and Bold Forecasts. A Cognitive Perspective on Risk Taking.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 393–413Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Jackie Snell (1997). ‘Predicting a Changing Taste. Do People Know What They Will Like?’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 393–410Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1972). ‘Subjective Probability. A Judgement of Representativeness.’ Cognitive Psychology 3: 430–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(1973). ‘Availability. A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and Probability.’ Cognitive Psychology 4: 207–32Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(1979). ‘Prospect Theory. An Analysis of Decision under Risk.’ Econometrica 47: 263–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(1995). ‘Conflict Resolution. A Cognitive Perspective.’ Barriers to Conflict Resolution, ed. Arrow, Kenneth Joseph, Mnookin, Robert H., Ross, Lee, Tversky, Amos and Wilson, Robert B.. New York, Norton: 44–61Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(2000a). Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge, Russell Sage Foundation and Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(2000b). ‘Choices, Values, and Frames.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 1–16Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(2000c). ‘Prospect Theory. An Analysis of Decision under Risk.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 17–43Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Slovic, Paul and Tversky, Amos (1982). Judgment under Uncertainty. Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch and Richard H. Thaler (2000a). ‘Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 211–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch and Richard H. Thaler (2000b). ‘Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking. Entitlements in the Market.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 317–34Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Ilana Ritov and David Schkade (2000c). ‘Economic Preferences or Attitude Expressions? An Analysis of Dollar Responses to Public Issues.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 642–71Google Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro (2002). ‘Introduction to Repeated Games with Private Monitoring.’ Journal of Economic Theory 102: 1–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, Todd R. and Bradley J. Ruffle (2001). ‘The Self-Serving Bias and Beliefs about Rationality.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=251308CrossRef
Kaufman, Bruce E. (1999). ‘Emotional Arousal as a Source of Bounded Rationality.’ Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 38: 135–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelman, Mark, Yuval Rottenstreich and Amos Tversky (2000). ‘Context-Dependence in Legal Decision Making.’ Behavioural Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 61–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keren, Gideon (1990). ‘Cognitive Aids and Debiasing Methods. Can Cognitive Pills Cure Cognitive Ills?’ Cognitive Biases, ed. Caverni, Jean-Paul and Fabre, Jean-Marc. Amsterdam, North Holland: 523–52Google Scholar
Kersting, Wolfgang (1994). Die politische Philosophie des Gesellschaftsvertrags. Darmstadt, Wissenschaftliche BuchgesellschaftGoogle Scholar
Kersting, Wolfgang(1997). ‘Methodologische Probleme einer Theorie der sozialen Gerechtigkeit.’ Recht, Gerechtigkeit und demokratische Tugend. Abhandlungen zur praktischen Philosophie der Gegenwart, ed. Kersting, Wolfgang. Frankfurt, Suhrkamp: 213–42Google Scholar
Kiesler, Sara B. (1973). ‘Preference for Predictability or Unpredictability as a Mediator of Reactions to Norm Violations.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 27: 354–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard (1992). ‘Towards a Theory of Low-Cost Decisions.’ European Journal of Political Economy 8: 305–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard(1996). ‘Bemerkungen zur Minimalmoral.’ Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften 116: 223–51Google Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard and Pommerehne, Werner (1993). ‘Low Cost Decisions as a Challenge to Public Choice.’ Public Choice 77: 107–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirchhof, Ferdinand (1987). Private Rechtsetzung. Berlin, Duncker & HumblotGoogle Scholar
Klein, Gary (2001). ‘The Fiction of Optimization.’ Bounded Rationality. The Adaptive Toolbox. Dahlem Workshop Report, ed. Gerd Gigerenzer and Reinhard Selten. Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press: 103–21Google Scholar
Knight, Frank Hyneman (1921). Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Boston and New York, Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Knight, Jack (1992). Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, Jack and Itai Sened (1995). ‘Introduction.’ Explaining Social Institutions, ed. Knight, Jack and Sened, Itai. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Knill, Christoph and Andrea Lenschow (1999). ‘Governance im Mehrebenensystem. Die institutionellen Grenzen effektiver Implementation in der europäischen Umweltpolitik.’ Preprints aus der Max-Planck-Projektgruppe Recht der Gemeinschaftsgüter Bonn 1999/1. http://www.mpp-rdg.mpg.de/extern/pdf_dat/9808.pdf
Kofman, Fred and Lawarree, Jacques (1996). ‘On the Optimality of Allowing Collusion.’ Journal of Public Economics 61: 383–407CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koriat, Asher, Lichtenstein, Sarah and Fischhoff, Baruch (1980). ‘Reasons for Confidence.’ Journal of Experimental Psychology 6: 107–18Google Scholar
Korobkin, Russell B. and Ulen, Thomas S. (2000). ‘Law and Behavioral Science. Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics.’ California Law Review 88: 1051–144CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kötz, Hein (1996). Europäisches Vertragsrecht I. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Krause, Bodo (1991). ‘Components of Cognitive Learning.’ Zeitschrift für Psychologie 199: 35–44Google Scholar
Krause, Bodo(1992). ‘Kognitives Lernen. Ansätze und experimentelle Befunde.’ Zeitschrift für Psychologie 200: 199–223Google Scholar
Kreps, David M. (1990). Game Theory and Economic Modelling. Oxford and New York, Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krüger, Hans-Peter (1999). ‘Verzicht auf Sanktionsnormen im Straaenverkehrsrecht-ein Beitrag zur Effektivität von Verhaltensnormen?’ Wirkungsforschung zum Recht I. Wirkungen und Erfolgsbedingungen von Gesetzen, ed. Hof, Hagen and Lübbe-Wolff, Gertrude. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 223–34Google Scholar
Kühberger, Anton (2000). ‘What about Motivation?Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 685CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S. (1962). The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. [Chicago], University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Kulms, Rainer (2000). Schuldrechtliche Organisationsverträge in der Unternehmenskooperation. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Kunda, Ziva and Nisbett, Richard E. (1988). ‘Predicting Individual Evaluations from Group Evaluations and Vice Versa. Different Patterns for Self and Other?Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 14: 326–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunig, Philip (1986). Das Rechtsstaatsprinzip. Überlegungen zu seiner Bedeutung für das Verfassungsrecht der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Lachmann, Ludwig M. (1963). ‘Wirtschaftsordnung und wirtschaftliche Institutionen.’ Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 14: 63–77Google Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques (1999). ‘Political Economy, Information and Incentives.’ European Economic Review 43: 649–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lahno, Bernd (2002). Der Begriff des Vertrauens. Paderborn, MentisGoogle Scholar
Laibson, David (1997). ‘Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 443–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laird, John E., Newell, Allen and Rosenbloom, Paul (1991). ‘Soar: an Architecture for General Intelligence.’ Artificial Intelligence 47: 289–325Google Scholar
Langer, Ellen J. (1975). ‘The Illusion of Control.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32: 311–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langevoort, Donald C. (2000). ‘Organized Illusions. A Behavioral Theory of Why Corporations Mislead Stock Market Investors (and Cause Other Social Harms).’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 144–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langlois, Richard N. (1986). ‘Rationality, Institutions, and Explanation.’ Economics as a Process. Essays in the New Institutional Economics, ed. Langlois, Richard N.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 225–55Google Scholar
LaPiere, Richard T. (1934). ‘Attitudes vs. Actions.’ Social Forces 13: 230–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, Anton E. (2002). ‘The Origin of Conditional Logic. Does a Cheater Detection Module Exist?Journal of Genetic Psychology 163: 425–44CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ledyard, John O. (1995). ‘Public Goods. A Survey of Experimental Research.’ The Handbook of Experimental Economics, ed. Kagel, J. H. and Roth, A. E.. Princeton, Princeton University Press: 111–94Google Scholar
Lehmann, Jill Fain, John E. Lairdand Paul Rosenbloom (1998). ‘A Gentle Introduction to Soar: an Architecture for Human Cognition.’ Methods, Models, and Conceptual Issues, Vol. IV. An Invitation to Cognitive Science, ed. Scarborough, Don and Stemberg, Saul: 211–53Google Scholar
León, Immaculada and Hernández, Juan A. (1998). ‘Testing the Role of Attribution and Appraisal in Predicting Own and Other's Emotions.’ Cognition and Emotion 12: 27–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, Jennifer S. and Tetlock, Philip E. (1999). ‘Accounting for the Effects of Accountability.’ Psychological Bulletin 125: 255–75CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lessig, Lawrence (1999). Code and other Laws of Cyberspace. New York, Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Lessig, Lawrence and Resnick, Paul (1999). ‘Zoning Speech on the Internet. A Legal and Technical Model.’ Michigan Law Review 98: 395–431CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinson, Stephen C. (1995). ‘Interactional Biases in Human Thinking.’ Social Intelligence and Interaction, ed. Goody, Esther. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 221–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liebrand, Wim B. and , Charles G.McClintock, (1988). ‘The Ring Measure of Social Values. A Computerized Procedure for Assessing Individual Differences in Information Processing and Social Value Orientation.’ European Journal of Personality 2: 217–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lind, E. Allan and Tyler, Tom R. (1988). The Social Psychology of Procedural Justice. New York, Plenum PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linton, Ralph (1945). The Cultural Background of Personality. New York, London, D. Appleton-CenturyGoogle Scholar
List, Christian and Goodin, Robert E. (2001). ‘Epistemic Democracy. Generalizing the Condorcet Jury Theorem.’ Journal of Political Philosophy 9: 277–306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, John A. (2000). ‘The Effect of Market Experience on the WTA/WTP Disparity. Evidence from a Field Experiment with Sports Memorabilia.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id230007
Loewenstein, George and Daniel Adler (2000). ‘A Bias in the Prediction of Tastes.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 726–34Google Scholar
Loewenstein, George F. and Drazen Prelec (1992). ‘Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice. Evidence and an Interpretation.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 573–98CrossRef
Loewenstein, George and Prelec, Drazen(2000). ‘Preferences for Sequences of Outcomes.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 565–77Google Scholar
Loewenstein, George and Richard H. Thaler (1997). ‘Intertemporal Choice.’ Research on Judgement and Decisionmaking, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 365–78Google Scholar
Loewenstein, George, Weber, Elke U., Hsee, Christopher and Welch, Ned (2001). ‘Risk as Feelings.’ Psychological Bulletin 127: 267–86CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lübbe, Weyma (2002). ‘Epistemische Pflichten in der “Wissensgesellschaft”.’ Wissen, Nichtwissen, Unsicheres Wissen, ed. Engel, Christoph, Halfmann, Jost and Schulte, Martin. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 145–60Google Scholar
Lüdemann, Jörn (2004). Edukatorisches Staatshandeln. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Luhmann, Niklas (1986). Ökologische Kommunikation. Kann die moderne Gesellschaft sich auf ökologische Gefährdungen einstellen?Opladen, Westdeutscher VerlagGoogle Scholar
McAdams, Richard H. (2000). ‘A Focal Point Theory of Expressive Law.’ Virginia Law Review 86: 1649–729CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCaffery, Edward, Daniel Kahneman and Matthew L. Spitzer (2000). ‘Framing the Jury. Cognitive Perspective on Pain and Suffering Awards.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 259–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McEvily, Bill, Roberto Weber, Cristiná Bicchieri and Violet Ho (2002). ‘Can Groups be Trusted? An Experimental Study of Collective Trust.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=323223CrossRef
McGarity, Thomas O. (1998). ‘A Cost-Benefit State.’ Administrative Law Review 50: 7–79Google Scholar
Machina, Mark J. (1987). ‘Choice under Uncertainty. Problems Solved and Unsolved.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 1: 121–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKenzie Alexander, Jason (2003). ‘Evolutionary Game Theory.’ The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, ed. Zalta, Edward E.. Stanford, Stanford UniversityGoogle Scholar
MacNeil, Ian R. (1971). Contracts: Exchange Transactions and Relationships. Mineola, Foundation PressGoogle Scholar
MacNeil, Ian R.(1982). ‘Efficient Breach of Contract: Circles in the Sky.’ Virginia Law Review 68: 947–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mair, Peter (1996). ‘Comparative Politics. An Overview.’ A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 309–35Google Scholar
Mantzavinos, Chrysostomos (2001). Individuals, Institutions, and Markets. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P. (1989). Rediscovering Institutions. The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York, Free PressGoogle Scholar
Markovits, Richard S. (1996). ‘Monopoly and the Allocative Inefficiency of First-Best-Allocatively-Efficient Tort Law in our Worse-Than-Second-Best World. The Whys and some Therefores.’ Case Western Reserve Law Review 46: 313–448Google Scholar
Martignon, Laura and Kathryn Blackmond Laskey (1999). ‘Bayesian Benchmarks for Fast and Frugal Heuristics.’ Simple Heuristics that Make Us Smart, ed. Gigerenzer, Gerd and Todd, Peter M.. New York, Oxford University Press: 169–90Google Scholar
Maslow, Abraham H. (1954). Motivation and Personality. New York, HarperGoogle Scholar
Maunz, Theodor and Dürig, Günter, eds. (1958). Grundgesetz: Kommentar. Munich, BeckGoogle Scholar
May, Judith V. and Wildavsky, Aaron B. (1978). The Policy Cycle. Beverly Hills, SageGoogle Scholar
Maynard, Smith, John, (1982). Evolution and the Theory of Games. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Mayntz, Renate (1980). Implementation politischer Programme. Empirische Forschungsberichte. Königstein/Ts., AthenäumGoogle Scholar
Mayntz, Renate(1983). ‘Implementation von regulativer Politik.’ Implementation politischer Programme II, ed. Mayntz, Renate. Opladen, Westdeutscher Verlag: 50–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meade, James (1970). ‘The Theory of Indicative Planning.’ The Collected Papers of James Meade, Vol. II. Value, Distribution and Growth, ed. Meade, James. Winchester, Unwin Hyman: 109–57Google Scholar
Meadow, William and Sunstein, Cass R. (2001). ‘Statistics, not Experts.’ Duke Law Journal 51: 629–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meehl, Paul E. (1954). Clinical Versus Statistical Prediction. A Theoretical Analysis and a Review of the Evidence. Minneapolis, University of Minnesota PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Messick, David M. and Liebrand, Wim B. (1995). ‘Individual Heuristics and the Dynamics of Cooperation in Large Groups.’ Psychological Review 102: 131–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Messick, David M., Moore, Don A. and Bazerman, Max H. (1997). ‘Ultimatum Bargaining with a Group. Underestimating the Importance of the Decision Rule.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 69: 87–101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, David E. and Kieras, David E. (1997). ‘A Computational Theory of Executive Cognitive Processes and Multiple-Task Performance: I. Basic Mechanisms.’ Psychological Review 104: 3–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, John W. and Scott, W. Richard (1983). Organizational Environments. Ritual and Rationality. Beverly Hills, SageGoogle Scholar
Miller, Dale T. and Ross, Michael (1975). ‘Self-Serving Biases in the Attribution of Causality: Fact or Fiction?Psychological Bulletin 82: 213–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mischel, Walter and Peake, Philip K. (1982). ‘Beyond déjà vu in the Search for Cross-Situational Consistency.’ Psychological Review 89: 730–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mischel, Walter and Shoda, Yuichi (1995). ‘A Cognitive-Affective System Theory of Personality. Reconceptualizing Situations, Dispositions, Dynamics, and Invariance in Personality Structure.’ Psychological Review 102: 246–68CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mookherjee, Dilip (1990). ‘Rank Order Competition and Incentives. An Organizational Perspective.’ Economic Theory and Policy. Essays in Honour of Dipak Banerjee, ed. Dutta, Bhaskar. New Delhi, Oxford University Press: 194–229Google Scholar
Morgenstern, Oskar (1928). Wirtschaftsprognose. Eine Untersuchung ihrer Vorraussetzungen und Möglichkeiten. Vienna, SpringerGoogle Scholar
Morgenstern, Oskar(1935). ‘Vollkommene Voraussicht und wirtschaftliches Gleichgewicht.’ Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 6: 337–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mui, Vai-Lam (1995). ‘The Economics of Envy.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 26: 311–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mullainathan, Sendhil (2002). ‘A Memory-Based Model of Bounded Rationality.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 735–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murdock, Kevin C. (2002). ‘Intrinsic Motivation and Optimal Incentive Contracts.’ Rand Journal of Economics 33: 650–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mussweiler, Thomas, Strack, Fritz and Tim, Pfeiffer (2000). ‘Overcoming the Inevitable Anchoring Effect. Considering the Opposite Compensates for Selective Accessibility.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 26: 1142–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
National Research Council (2002). Global Networks and Local Values. Washington, D.C, National Academy of Sciences
Nee, Victor (1998). ‘Sources of the New Institutionalism.’ The New Institutionalism in Sociology, ed. Brinton, Mary C. and Nee, Victor. New York, Russell Sage Foundation: 1–16Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. (1995). ‘Recent Evolutionary Theorizing about Economic Change.’ Journal of Economic Literature 33: 48–90Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Neumann, Franz Leopold (1942). Behemoth. The Structure and Practice of National Socialism. New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Newcomb, Theodore Mead (1929). The Consistency of Certain Extrovert-Introvert Behavior Patterns in 51 Problem Boys. New York, Teachers College Columbia UniversityGoogle Scholar
Newell, Allen (1990). Unified Theories of Cognition. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Newell, Allen and Simon, Herbert Alexander (1972). Human Problem Solving. Englewood Cliffs, N. J., Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Newstead, Stephen E. (2000). ‘Are There Two Different Types of Thinking?Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 690–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nisbett, Richard E. and Ross, Lee (1980). Human Inference. Strategies and Shortcomings of Social Judgment. Englewood Cliffs, N. J., Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Noll, Roger and James E. Krier (2000). ‘Some Implications of Cognitive Psychology for Risk Regulation.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 325–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass Cecil (1981). Structure and Change in Economic History. New York, NortonGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass Cecil(1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nyborg, Karine and Mari Rege (2001). ‘Does Public Policy Crowd out Private Contributions to Public Goods?’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=292802CrossRef
Ockenfels, Axel (2003). ‘Reputationsmechanismen auf Internet-Marktplattformen. Theorie und Empirie.’ Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft 73: 295–315Google Scholar
Ofek, Elie, Muhamet Yildiz and Ernan Haruvy (2002). ‘Sequential Decision Making: How Prior Choices Affect Subsequent Valuations.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=353421CrossRef
Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor(1998). ‘A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action.’ American Political Science Review 92: 1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott (1951). The Social System. Glencoe, Ill., Free PressGoogle Scholar
Pashler, Harold E. (1998). The Psychology of Attention. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Pavlov, Ivan Petrovich and Anrep, Gleb Vasilievich (1927). Conditioned Reflexes. An Investigation of the Physiological Activity of the Cerebral Cortex. London, Oxford University Press and Humphrey MilfordGoogle Scholar
Payne, John W., Bettman, James R. et al. (1988). ‘Adaptive Strategy Selection in Decision Making.’ Journal of Experimental Psychology 14: 534–52Google Scholar
Payne, John W., Bettman, James R.Johnson, Eric J.(1992). ‘Behavioral Decision Research. A Constructive Processing Perspective.’ Annual Review of Psychology 43: 87–131CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(1997). ‘The Adaptive Decision Maker. Effort and Accuracy in Choice.’ Research on Judgement and Decision Making. Currents, Connections, and Controversies, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 181–204Google Scholar
Pennington, Nancy and Hastie, Reid (1993). ‘Reasoning in Explanation-Based Decision-Making.’ Cognition 49: 123–63CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pennington, Nancy and Hastie, Reid(1997). ‘Explanation-Based Decision Making. Effects of Memory Structure on Judgement.’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 454–81Google Scholar
Perritt, Henry H. (2000). ‘Dispute Resolution in Cyberspace. Demand for New Forms of ADR.’ Ohio State Journal on Dispute Resolution 15: 675–703Google Scholar
Guy, Peters B. (1999). Institutional Theory in Political Science. The New Institutionalism. London, PinterGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1932). The Economics of Welfare. London, MacmillanCrossRef
Pitschas, Rainer (1996). ‘Recht der Freien Berufe.’ Öffentliches Wirtschaftsrecht Besonderer Teil 2, ed. Schmidt, Reiner. Berlin, Springer: 1–126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plessner, Helmuth (1928). Die Stufen des Organischen und der Mensch. Einleitung in die Philosophische Anthropologie. Berlin and Leipzig, W. de GruyterGoogle Scholar
Plott, Charles R. (1986). ‘Rational Choice in Experimental Markets.’ Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W.. Chicago, University of Chicago Press: 117–44Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. (2000). Law and Social Norms. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. (2000). ‘Cost–Benefit Analysis. Definition, Justification, and Comment on Conference-Papers.’ Journal of Legal Studies 29: 1153–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A.(2003). Economic Analysis of Law. New York, AspenGoogle Scholar
Poundstone, William (1992). Prisoner's Dilemma. New York, DoubledayGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, Canice (1999). ‘The Provision of Incentives in Firms.’ Journal of Economic Literature 37: 7–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Presson, Paul K. and Benassi, Victor A. (1996). ‘Illusion of Control. A Meta-Analytic Review.’ Journal of Social Behavior and Personality 11: 493–510Google Scholar
Price, Michael E., Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John (2002). ‘Punitive Sentiment as an Anti-Free Rider Psychological Device.’ Evolution and Human Behavior 23: 203–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Priest, George L. (1981). ‘A Theory of the Consumer Product Warranty.’ Yale Law Journal 90: 1297–352CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quattrone, George A. and Amos Tversky (2000). ‘Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analysis of Political Choice.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 451–72Google Scholar
Quillen, Gwyn D. (1988). ‘Contract Damages and Cross-Subsidization.’ Southern California Law Review 61: 1125–41Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew (1998). ‘Psychology and Economics.’ Journal of Economic Literature 36: 11–46Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew(2002). ‘A Perspective on Psychology and Economics.’ European Economic Review 46: 657–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rachlin, Howard (2001). ‘Behavioural Analysis, Cognitive Analysis, and Economics.’ Behavioral and Experimental Economics Nobel Symposium, 4–6 December 2001, at http://www.iies.su.se/nobel/papers/stockholm text3.pdf
Rachlinski, Jeffrey J. (2000). ‘A Positive Psychological Theory of Judging in Hindsight.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 95–115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rachlinski, Jeffrey J.(2003). ‘The Uncertain Psychological Case for Paternalism.’ Northwestern University Law Review 97: 1165–225Google Scholar
Rapoport, Anatol and Chammah, Albert M. (1965). Prisoner's Dilemma. A Study in Conflict and Cooperation. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rasmusen, Eric (1989). Games and Information. An Introduction to Game Theory. Oxford and New York, Basil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Rawls, John (1999). A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, Mass., Belknap Press of Harvard Univeristy PressGoogle Scholar
Redelmeier, Donald A. and Tversky, Amos (1992). ‘On the Framing of Multiple Prospects.’ Psychological Science 3: 191–3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ripperger, Tanja (1998). Ökonomik des Vertrauens. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Risse, Thomas (2000). ‘“Let's Argue!”. Communicative Action in World Politics.’ International Organization 54: 1–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritov, Ilana and Jonathan Baron (2000). ‘Reluctance to Vaccinate. Omission Bias and Ambiguity.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 168–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, Brent W. and Donahue, Eileen M. (1994). ‘One Personality, Multiple Selves. Integrating Personality and Social Roles.’ Journal of Personality 62: 199–218CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rohe, Mathias (1998). Netzverträge. Rechtsprobleme komplexer Vertragsbindungen. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Ronis, D. L., J. F. Yates and J. P. Kirscht (1989). ‘Attitudes, Decisions, and Habits as Determinants of Repeated Behavior.’ Attitude Structure and Function, ed. Pratkanis, A. R., Breckler, S. J. and Greenwald, A. G.. Hillsdale, Erlbaum: 213–39Google Scholar
Rosa, Jose Antonio, Porac, Joseph F., Runser-Spanjol, Jelena and Saxan, Michael S. (1999). ‘Sociocognitive Dynamics in a Product Market.’ Journal of Marketing 63: 64–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Lee and Nisbett, Richard E. (1991). The Person and the Situation. Perspectives of Social Psychology. New York, McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Ross, Lee, Greene, David and House, Pamela (1977a). ‘The False Consensus Effect: an Egocentric Bias in Social Perception and Attribution Processes.’ Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 13: 279–301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Lee, Lepper, Mark R., Strack, Fritz and Steinmetz, Julia (1977b). ‘Social Explanation and Social Expectation. Effects of Real and Hypothetical Explanations on Subjective Likelihood.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 35: 817–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rostain, Tanina (2000). ‘Educating Homo Economicus. Cautionary Notes on the New Behavioral Law and Economics Movement.’ Law and Society Review 34: 973–1006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques (1763). Du contrat social; ou, Principes du droit politique. n.p
Rutherford, Malcolm (1994). Institutions in Economics. The Old and the New Institutionalism. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd (2001). Economic Concepts for the Social Sciences. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanna, Lawrence J. and Schwarz, Norbert (2003). ‘Debiasing the Hindsight Bias. The Role of Accessibility Experiences and (Mis)attributions.’ Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 39 (3): 287–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sansone, Carol and Harackiewicz, Judith M. (2000). Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation. The Search for Optimal Motivation and Performance. San Diego, Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Satz, Debra and Ferejohn, John A. (1994). ‘Rational Choice and Social Theory.’ The Journal of Philosophy 91: 71–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. (1954). The Foundations of Statistics. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, Fritz Wilhelm (1997). Games Real Actors Play. Actor-Centered Institutionalism in Policy Research. Boulder, Colo., Westview PressGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, Fritz Wilhelm(1998). ‘Die Problemlösungsfähigkeit der Mehrebenenpolitik in Europa.’ Politische Viertelsjahresschrift 39: 121–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, Fritz Wilhelm(1999). Governing in Europe. Effective and Democratic?Oxford and New York, Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheler, Max (1928). Die Stellung des Menschen im Kosmos. Darmstadt, ReichlGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. (1960). The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, Mass.,Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C.(1984). ‘Self-Command in Practice, in Policy, and in a Theory of Rational Choice.’ American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 74: 1–11Google Scholar
Schimank, Uwe (1992). ‘Erwartungssicherheit und Zielverfolgung. Sozialität zwischen Prisoners' Dilemma und Battle of the Sexes.’ Soziale Welt 43: 182–200Google Scholar
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1998). On Custom in the Economy. Oxford, Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmeidler, David (1989). ‘Subjective Probability and Expected Utility without Additivity.’ Econometrica 57: 571–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schöch, Heinz (1999). ‘Verzicht auf Sanktionsnormen im Straβenverkehrsrecht – ein Beitrag zur Effektivität von Verhaltensnormen?’ Wirkungsforschung zum Recht I. Wirkungen und Erfolgsbedingungen von Gesetzen, ed. Hof, Hagen and Lübbe-Wolff, Gertrude. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 235–44Google Scholar
Schulte, Martin (2002). ‘Zum Umgang mit Wissen, Nichtwissen and Unsicherem Wissen im Recht – dargestellt am Beispiel des BSE- and MKS-Konflikts.’ Wissen, Nichtwissen, Unsicheres Wissen, ed. Engel, Christoph, Halfmann, Jost and Schulte, Martin. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 351–70Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph Alois (1912). Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Leipzig, Duncker & HumblotGoogle Scholar
Schweizer, Urs (1999). Vertragstheorie. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Sedikides, Constantine, Schopler, John and Insko, Chester A. (1998). Intergroup Cognition and Intergroup Behavior. Mahwah, N. J., Lawrence ErlbaumGoogle Scholar
Selten, Reinhard (1978). ‘The Chain Store Paradox.’ Theory and Decision 9: 127–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, Reinhard(1998). ‘Features of Experimentally Observed Bounded Rationality.’ European Economic Review 42: 413–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shackle, George L. (1992). ‘Risk, Uncertainty and Imagination.’ The Theory of Choice. A Critical Guide, ed. Shaun, H. Heap, Hollis, Martin, Lyons, Bruce, Sudgen, Robert and Wale, Albert. Oxford, Blackwell: 51–61Google Scholar
Shafir, Eldar, Itamar Simonson and Amos Tversky (2000). ‘Reason-Based Choice.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 597–619Google Scholar
Shavitt, Sharon and Fazio, Russell H. (1991). ‘Effects of Attribute Salience on the Consistency between Attitudes and Behaviour Predictions.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 17: 506–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheposh, J. P. and Gallo, P. S. (1973). ‘Asymmetry of Payoff Structure and Cooperative Behaviour in the Prisoner's Dilemma Game.’ Journal of Conflict Resolution 17: 321–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sherrington, Charles Scott (1906). The Integrative Action of the Nervous System. New York, C. Scribner's SonsGoogle Scholar
Shoda, Yuichi (1999). ‘A Unified Framework for the Study of Behavioral Consistency. Briding Person x Situation Interaction and the Consistency Paradox.’ European Journal of Personality 13: 361–873.0.CO;2-X>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shoemaker, Paul J. (1982). ‘The Expected Utility Model. Its Variants, Purposes, Evidence and Limitations.’ Journal of Economic Literature 20: 529–63Google Scholar
Siebert, Horst (1996). ‘Institutionelle Arrangements für die Zuweisung von Opportunitätskosten.’ Festschrift für Ernst-Joachim Mestmäcker, ed. Immenga, Ulrich, Möschel, Wernhard and Reuter, Dieter. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 309–20Google Scholar
Sil, Rudra (2000). ‘The Division of Labor in Social Science Research. Unified Methodology or “Organic Solidarity”?’ Polity 32: 499–531CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander (1957). Models of Man: Social and Rational. Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Society Setting. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1962). ‘The Architecture of Complexity.’ Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 106: 467–82Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1976). Administrative Behavior. A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization. New York, Free PressGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1987). ‘Rational Decision Making in Business Organisations.’ Advances in Behavioural Economics 1, ed. Green, Leonard and Kagel, John H.. Norwood, Ablex: 18–47Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1990). ‘Invariants of Human Behavior.’ Annual Review of Psychology 41: 1–19CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1991). ‘Cognitive Architectures and Rational Analysis. Comment.’ Architectures for Intelligence, ed. VanLehn, Kurt. Hillsdale, Erlbaum: 25–39Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1993). ‘Altruism and Economics.’ American Economic Review 83: 156– 61Google Scholar
Simon, Jürgen and Braun, Susanne (2002). ‘Legal Aspects of Genetic Data Banking in Germany.’ Eubios Journal of Asian and International Bioethics 12: 171–6Google Scholar
Simonson, Itamar (2000). ‘The Effect of Purchasing Quantity and Timing on Variety-Seeking Behavior.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 735–57Google Scholar
Singer, O. (1993). ‘Policy Communities und Diskurs-Koalitionen. Experten und Expertise in der Wirtschaftspolitik.’ Policy Analyse. Kritik und Neuorientierung, ed. Héritier, Adrienne. Opladen, Westdeutscher Verlag: 149–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slembeck, Tilman and Jean-Robert Tyran (2002). ‘Do Institutions Promote Rationality? An Experimental Study of the Three-Door Anomaly.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=345721CrossRef
Slovic, Paul (1995). ‘The Construction of Preference.’ American Psychologist 50: 364–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, Paul and Fischhoff, Baruch (1977). ‘On the Psychology of Experimental Surprises.’ Journal of Experimental Psychology 3: 544–51Google Scholar
Smend, Rudolf (1968). ‘Verfassung und Verfassungsrecht.’ Staatsrechtliche Abhandlungen und andere Aufsätze, ed. Smend, Rudolf. Berlin, Duncker & Humblot: 119–276Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1790). The Theory of Moral Sentiments, or, An Essay Towards an Analysis of the Principles by which Men Naturally Judge Concerning the Conduct and Character, First of Their Neighbours, and Afterwards of Themselves. To which is Added, a Dissertation on the Origin of Languages. London, StrahanGoogle Scholar
Smith, Eliot R. and Coster, Jamie (2000). ‘Dual-Process Models in Social and Cognitive Psychology: Conceptual Integration and Links to Underlying Memory Systems.’ Personality and Social Psychology Review 4: 108–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Trenton G. (2003). ‘Obesity and Nature's Thumbprint. How Institutions Make Behaviour Predictable. How Modern Waistlines can Inform Economic Theory.’ University of California at Santa Barbara, Working Paper in Economics 18-02, 23 August 2003
Smith, Vernon L. (1989). ‘Theory, Experiment and Economics.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives: 3 (1): 151–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L.(1991). ‘Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology.’ Journal of Political Economy 99: 877–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L.(1994). ‘Economics in the Laboratory.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 8: 112–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L. and Walker, James M. (1993). ‘Monetary Rewards and Decision Cost in Experimental Economics.’ Economic Inquiry 31: 245–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L., Suchanek, Gerry L. and Arlington, W. Williams (1988). ‘Bubbles, Crashes, and Endogenous Expectations in Experimental Spot Asset Markets.’ Econometrica 56: 1119–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Mark and Swann, William B. (1976). ‘When Actions Reflect Attitudes. The Politics of Impression Management.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 34: 1034–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobota, Katharina (1997). Das Prinzip Rechtsstaat. Verfassungs- und verwaltungsrechtliche Aspekte. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Spiecker gen. Döhmann, Indra (2001). ‘Staatliche Entscheidungen unter Unsicherheit. Juristische und ökonomische Vorgaben.’ Gentechnik im nicht–menschlichen Bereich – was kann und was sollte das Recht regeln?, ed. Lege, Joachim. Berlin, Arno Spitz: 51–88Google Scholar
Stanovich, Keith E. and West, Richard F. (2000). ‘Individual Differences in Reasoning. Implications for the Rationality Debate?Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 645–65CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stark, Oded (1995). Altruism and Beyond. An Economic Analysis of Transfers and Exchanges within Families and Groups. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinmo, Sven, Thelen, Kathleen Ann and Frank, Longstreth (1992). Structuring Politics. Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephens, David W. and Krebs, J. R. (1986). Foraging Theory. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2000). ‘Formal and Informal Institutions.’ Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective, ed. Dasgupta, Partha and Serageldin, Ismail. Washington, D.C., World Bank: 59–68Google Scholar
Strack, Fritz and Roland Deutsch (2002). ‘Reflective and Impulsive Determinants of Social Behaviour’ (mimeo)
Strack, Fritz and Deutsch, Roland(forthcoming). ‘Urteilsheuristiken.’ Theorien der Sozialpsychologie – Motivations- und Informationsverarbeitungstheorien, ed. Frey, Dieter and Irle, Martin
Strack, Fritz and Mussweiler, Thomas (1997). ‘Explaining the Enigmatic Anchoring Effect. Mechanisms of Selective Accessibility.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 73: 437–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ströbele, Wolfgang (1987). Rohstoffökonomik Theorie natürlicher Ressourcen mit Anwendungsbeispielen Öl, Kupfer, Uran und Fischerei. Munich, VahlenGoogle Scholar
Stults, Daniel M. and Messe, Lawrence A. (1985). ‘Behavioral Consistency: the Impact of Public Versus Private Statements of Intentions.’ Journal of Social Psychology 125: 277–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. (1996). ‘Legislative Foreword. Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State.’ Stanford Law Review 48: 247–309CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(1998). ‘How Law Constructs Preferences.’ Georgetown Law Journal 86: 2637–52Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.,ed. (2000a). Behavioral Law and Economics. Cambridge Series on Judgment and Decision Making. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(2000b). ‘Cost–Benefit Default Principles.’ Chicago, John M. Olin Law & Economics Working Paper 104. http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=247884
Sunstein, Cass R.(2000c). ‘Introduction.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 1–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(2001). ‘Cost–Benefit Default Principles.’ Michigan Law Review 99: 1651–723CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(2002). ‘The Law of Group Polarization.’ Journal of Political Philosophy 10: 175–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. and Edna Ullmann-Margalit (2000). ‘Second-Order Decisions.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 187–208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, Ola (1981). ‘Are We All Less Risky and More Skilful than Our Fellow Drivers?Acta Psychologica 47: 143–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sweet, Alec Stone (1999). ‘Judicialization and the Construction of Governance.’ Comparative Political Studies 32: 147–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Symposium, (2000). ‘Cost–Benefit Analysis. Legal, Economic, and Philosophical Perspectives.’ Journal of Legal Studies 29: 837–1177Google Scholar
Tack, Werner H. (2003). ‘Kooperative Rationalität in sozialen Situationen.’ Grenzen rationaler Orientierung, ed. Astroh, Michael. Hildesheim, Olms: 103–35Google Scholar
Takacs, Karoly (2001). ‘Structural Embeddedness and Intergroup Conflict.’ Journal of Conflict Resolution 45: 743–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tedeschi, James T. (1981). Impression Management Theory and Social Psychological Research. New York, Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Tetlock, Philip E. (1985). ‘Accountability. The Neglected Social Context of Judgement and Choice.’ Research in Organizational Behaviour 7: 297–332Google Scholar
Tetlock, Philip E.(1999). ‘Accountability Theory. Mixing Properties of Human Agents with Properties of Social Systems.’ Shared Cognition in Organizations. The Management of Knowledge, ed. Thompson, Leigh L., Levine, John M. and Messick, David M.. Mahwah, N. J., Lawrence Erlbaum: 117–37Google Scholar
Tetlock, Philip E., Skitka, Linda and Boettger, Richard (1989). ‘Social and Cognitive Strategies for Coping with Accountability. Conformity, Complexity, and Bolstering.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57: 632–40CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Teubner, Gunther and Vaios Karavas (2003). ‘http://www.CompanyNameSucks.com: Drittwirkung der Grundrechte gegenüber “Privaten” im autonomen Recht des Internet.’ Innovationsoffene Regulierung des Internet, ed. Ladeur., Karl-Heinz, Baden-Baden, Nomos: 249–72Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. (1999). ‘Mental Accounting Matters.’ Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 12: 183–2063.0.CO;2-F>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, Richard H.(2000). ‘Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 269–87Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. and Shefrin, H. M. (1981). ‘An Economic Theory of Self-Control.’ Journal of Political Economy 89: 392–406CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Theissen, Eric (2002). ‘Floor versus Screen Trading. Evidence from the German Stock Market.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 158: 32–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, Leigh L.,Levine, John M. and Messick, David M. (1999). Shared Cognition in Organizations. The Management of Knowledge. Mahwah, N. J., Lawrence ErlbaumGoogle Scholar
Thompson, M.,Ellis, Richard and Wildavsky, Aaron B. (1990). Cultural Theory. Boulder, Colo., Westview PressGoogle Scholar
Thorburn, W. M. (1915). ‘Occam's Razor.’ Mind 24: 287–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tietenberg, Thomas H. (1982). ‘Transferable Discharge Permits and the Control of Air Pollution – a Survey and Synthesis.’ Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht 3: 477–508Google Scholar
Tietenberg, Thomas H.(1998). Environmental Economics and Policy. Reading, Mass., Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean (1986). ‘Hierarchies and Bureaucracies: On the Role of Collusion in Organizations.’ Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 2: 181–214Google Scholar
Tirole, Jean(1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean(2002). ‘Rational Irrationality. Some Economics of Self-Management.’ European Economic Review 46: 633–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turner, Mark (2001). Cognitive Dimensions of Social Science. New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Dale W. Griffin (2000). ‘Endowments and Contrasts in Judgements of Well-Being.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 709–25Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1973). ‘Availability. A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and Probability.’ Cognitive Psychology 5: 207–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel(1974). ‘Judgement under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases.’ Science 185: 1124–31CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel(1991). ‘Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice. A Reference-Dependent Model.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 1039–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel(2000). ‘Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions.’ Choices, Values and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 209–23Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Itamar Simonson (2000). ‘Context-Dependent Preferences.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 518–27Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos, Shmuel Sattath and Paul Slovic (2000). ‘Contingent Weighting in Judgement and Choice.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 503–17Google Scholar
Tyler, Tom R. (1990). Why People Obey the Law. New Haven, Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Tyler, Tom R.(1997). ‘The Psychology of Legitimacy.’ Personality and Social Psychology Review 1: 323–44CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Underwood, Bill and Moore, Bert S. (1981). ‘Sources of Behavioral Consistency.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 40: 780–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanberg, Victor (2002). ‘Rational Choice vs. Program-Based Behavior. Alternative Theoretical Approaches and their Relevance for the Study of Institutions.’ Rationality and Society 14: 7–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanberg, Victor and Buchanan, James M. (1989). ‘Interests and Theories in Constitutional Choice.’ Journal of Theoretical Politics 1: 49–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veer, Donald (1986). Paternalistic Intervention. The Moral Bounds of Benevolence. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein (1919). The Place of Science in Modern Civilisation and Other Essays. New York, B. W.HuebschGoogle Scholar
Verweij, Marco (2000). Transboundary Environmental Problems and Cultural Theory. The Protection of the Rhine and the Great Lakes. Houndmills, Basingstoke, and New York, PalgraveGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich-August (1967). Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics. London, RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar (1944). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Savigny, Friedrich Karl (1814). Vom Beruf unsrer Zeit für Gesetzgebung und Rechtswissenschaft. Heidelberg, Mohr and ZimmerGoogle Scholar
Wade-Benzoni, Kimberly A., Tenbrunsel, Ann E. and Bazerman, Max H. (1996). ‘Egocentric Interpretations of Fairness in Asymmetric, Environmental Social Dilemmas. Explaining Harvesting Behavior and the Role of Communication.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 67: 111–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagenaar, Willem A., Gideon Keren and Sarah Lichtenstein (1997). ‘Islanders and Hostages. Deep and Surface Structures of Decision Problems.’ Research on Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 552–65Google Scholar
Walker, James M., Gardner, Roy, Herr, Andrew and Ostron, Elinor (2000). ‘Collective Choice in the Commons. Experimental Results on Proposed Allocation Rules and Votes.’ The Economic Journal 110: 212–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Elke U. and Patrizia G. Lindemann (2002). ‘Decision Modes or Choosing How to Choose. Making Decisions with Our Head, Our Heart, or by the Book’ (mimeo)
Weber, Elke U., William M. Goldstein and S. Barlas (1995). ‘And Let Us not Forget Memory. The Role of Memory Processes and Techniques in the Study of Judgement and Choice.’ The Psychology of Learning and Motivation, 32. Decision Making from a Cognitive Perspective, ed. Busemeyer, J. R., Hastie, Reid and Medin, D. L.. San Diego, Academic Press: 33–81Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1976). Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Grundriss der verstehenden Soziologie. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Webster, Hutton and H. Milford (1942). Taboo. A Sociological Study. Stanford, Stanford University Press; London, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Weck-Hannemann, Hannelore (1999). ‘Rationale Auβensteuerung menschlichen Verhaltens – Möglichkeiten und Grenzen.’ Rationale Umweltpolitik - Rationales Umweltrecht. Konzepte, Kriterien und Grenzen rationaler Steuerung im Umweltschutz, ed. Gawel, Erik and Lübbe-Wolff, Gertrude. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 67–92Google Scholar
Wegner, Gerhard (1996). Wirtschaftspolitik zwischen Selbst- und Fremdsteuerung – ein neuer Ansatz. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Weigend, A (1994). ‘On Overfitting and the Effective Number of Hidden Units.’ Proceedings of the 1993 Connectionist Models Summer School, ed. Mozer, Michael C.. Hillsdale, N. J., Lawrence Erlbaum: 335–42Google Scholar
Welch, Ivo (1992). ‘Sequential Sales, Learning, and Cascades.’ Journal of Finance 47: 695–732CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Harrison C. (1992). Identity and Control. A Structural Theory of Social Action. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
White, Harrison C.(1995). ‘Social Networks Can Resolve Actor Paradoxes in Economics and in Psychology.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 151: 58–74Google Scholar
Wicker, Allan W. (1969). ‘Attitudes versus Actions. The Relationship of Verbal and Overt Behavioral Responses to Attitude Objects.’ Journal of Social Issues 25: 41–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiersma, Uco J. (1992). ‘The Effects of Extrinsic Rewards in Intrinsic Motivation. A Meta-Analysis.’ Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology 65: 101–14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilder, David A. (1978). ‘Effect of Predictability on Units of Perception and Attribution.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 4: 281–4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York, Free Press; London, Collier MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Timothy D., Houston, Christopher E., Etling, Kathryn M. and Brekke, Nancy (1996). ‘A New Look at Anchoring Effects. Basic Anchoring and its Antecedents.’ Journal of Experimental Psychology 125: 387–402CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Timothy D., Lindsey, Samuel and Schooler, Tonya Y. (2000). ‘A Model of Dual Attitudes.’ Psychological Review 107: 101–26CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Windhoff-Héritier, Adrienne (1980). Politikimplementation. Ziel und Wirklichkeit politischer Entscheidungen. Königstein/Ts., HainGoogle Scholar
Winter, Gerd (1975). Das Vollzugsdefizit im Wasserrecht. Ein Beitrag zur Soziologie des Öffentlichen Rechts. Berlin, SchmidtGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ulrich (2000a). ‘Changing Cognitive Frames – Changing Organizational Forms: an Entrepreneurial Theory of Organizational Development.’ Industrial and Corporate Change 9: 733–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ulrich(2000b). ‘Genetic Adaptation, Cultural Learning, and the Utilitarian Program in Economics.’ Paper prepared for the AEA Panel ‘Consilience: the Unity of Knowledge in the 21st Century’, Boston, 7 January 2000
Wright, Jack C. and Mischel, Walter (1987). ‘A Conditional Approach to Dispositional Constructs. The Local Predictability of Social Behavior.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 53: 1159–77CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Yee, Albert S. (1996). ‘The Causal Effects of Ideas on Policies.’ International Organization 50: 66–108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. Eyton (1994). Equity. In Theory and Practice. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Zhou Xueguang (1997). ‘Organizational Decision Making as Rule Following.’ Organizational Decision Making, ed. Shapira, Zur. New York, Cambridge University Press: 257–81Google Scholar
Zweigert, Konrad and Kötz, Hein (1998). Introduction to Comparative Law. Oxford, Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. (2000). ‘Expressive Theories of Law. A Skeptical Overview.’ University of Pennsylvania Law Review 148: 1363–501CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. and Eric, A. Posner (1999). ‘Rethinking Cost-Benefit Analysis.’ Yale Law Journal 109: 165–247CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. and Eric, A. Posner(2000). ‘Cost–Benefit Analysis. Legal, Economic and Philosophical Perspectives. Introduction.’ Journal of Legal Studies 29: 837–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adomeit, Klaus (2003). ‘Der Rechtspositivismus im Denken von Hans Kelsen und von Gustav Radbruch.’ Juristenzeitung 58: 161–6Google Scholar
Ainslie, George (1992). Picoeconomics. The Strategic Interaction of Successive Motivational States within the Person. Cambridge,Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Ajzen, Icek (1991). ‘The Theory of Planned Behaviour.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 50: 179–211CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ajzen, Icek and Fishbein, Martin (1980). Understanding Attitudes and Predicting Social Behavior. Englewood Cliffs, N. J.,Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A. (1970). ‘The Market for “Lemons”. Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 84: 488–500CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Albert, Hans (1978). Traktat über rationale Praxis. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Alchian, Armen A. (1950). ‘Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory.’ Journal of Political Economy 58: 211–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allais, Maurice (1953). ‘Le comportement de l'homme rationnel devant le risque. Critique des postulats et axiomes de l'école Américaine.’ Econometrica 21: 503–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allison, J. (1989). ‘The Nature of Reinforcement.’ Contemporary Learning Theories. Instrumental Conditioning and the Impact of Biological Constraints on Learning, ed. Klein, S. and Mowrer, R.. Hillsdale, Erlbaum: 13–39Google Scholar
Allport, Gordon W., Vernon, Philip Ewart and Powers, Edwin (1933). Studies in Expressive Movement. New York, MacmillanCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, James E. and Alberto Alesina (1996). ‘Political Economy. An Overview.’ A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 645–74Google Scholar
Anderson, Elizabeth and Pildes, Richard H. (2000). ‘Expressive Theories of Law. A General Restatement.’ University of Pennsylvania Law Review 148: 1503–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, John R. (2000a). Cognitive Psychology and its Implications. New York, Worth PublishersGoogle Scholar
Anderson, John R.(2000b). Learning and Memory. An Integrated Approach. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Anderson, John R. and Lebiere, Christian (2003). ‘The Newell Test for a Theory of Cognition.’ Behavioral and Brain Sciences 26: 587–640CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Anderson, John R., Bothell, Daniel, Byrne, Michael D. and Lebiere, Christian (2004). ‘An Integrated Theory of the Mind.’ Psychological Review 111: 1036–60CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Anderson, Simon, Goeree, Jacob K. and Holt, Charles A. (1998). ‘A Theoretical Analysis of Altruism and Decision Error in Public Goods Games.’ Journal of Public Economics 70: 297–323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Antonides, Gerrit (1996). Psychology in Economics and Business. An Introduction to Economic Psychology. Dordrecht and Boston, Kluwer AcademicGoogle Scholar
Apesteguia, José, Martin Dufwenberg and Richard Selten (2003). ‘Blowing the Whistle.’ Bonn Econ. Discussion Papers 9/2003. ftp://ftp.wiwi.uni-bonn.de/papers/bgse/2003/bgse9_2003.pdfCrossRef
Apter, David E. (1996). ‘Comparative Politics, Old and New.’ A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 372–97Google Scholar
Arce, Daniel G. and Sandler, Todd (2003). ‘An Evolutionary Game Approach to Fundamentalism and Conflict.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 159: 132–54Google Scholar
Arendt, Hannah (1951). The Origins of Totalitarianism. New York, Harcourt BraceGoogle Scholar
Arkes, Hal R. (1991). ‘Costs and Benefits of Judgment Errors – Implications for Debiasing.’ Psychological Bulletin 110 (3): 486–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arkes, Hal R. and Blumer, Catherine (1985). ‘The Psychology of Sunk Cost.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 35: 124–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth Joseph (1963). Social Choice and Individual Values. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth Joseph(1987). ‘Rationality of Self and Others in an Economic System.’ Rational Choice : the Contrast between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W.. Chicago, Chicago University Press: 201–15Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation. New York, Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Ayton, Peter (2000). ‘Do the Birds and Bees Need Cognitive Reform?Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 666–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Babcock, Linda and George Loewenstein (2000). ‘Explaining Bargaining Impasse. The Role of Self-Serving Bias.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 355–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baird, Douglas G.,Gertner, Robert H. and Picker, Randal C. (1994). Game Theory and the Law. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, Richard E. (1989). ‘Sunk-Cost Hysteresis.’ National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 2911CrossRef
Bandura, Albert (1977). Social Learning Theory. Englewood Cliffs, N. J., Prenctice Hall
Banerjee, Abhijt V. (1992). ‘A Simple Model of Herd Behavior.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 797–817CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bargh, John A.,Chen, Mark and Burrows, Lara (1996). ‘Automaticity of Social Behavior. Direct Effects of Trait Construct and Stereotype Activation on Action.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 71: 230–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baron, Robert S. and Kerr, Norbert L. (2003). Group Process, Group Decisions, Group Action. Philadelphia, Open University PressGoogle Scholar
Bartlett, Frederic C. (1932). Remembering. A Study in Experimental and Social Psychology. Cambridge, The University PressGoogle Scholar
Bartling, Hartwig (1980). Leitbilder der Wettbewerbspolitik. Munich, VahlenGoogle Scholar
Battaglini, Marco, Roland Benabou and Lear Tirde (2002). ‘Self Control in Peer Groups.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=298448
Baumeister, Roy (1998). ‘The Self.’ The Handbook of Social Psychology, ed. DanielGilbert, T., Fiske, Susan T. and Lindzey, Gardner. Boston, McGraw-Hill: 680–740Google Scholar
Baxter, Terri L. and Goldberg, Lewis R. (1987). ‘Perceived Behavioral Consistency Underlying Trait Attribution to Oneself and Another. An Extension of the Actor–Observer Effect.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 13: 437–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayes, Thomas (1738). ‘An Essay toward Solving a Problem in the Doctrine of Chances.’ Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society 53: 370–418CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaman, Arthur L.,Cole, Maureen C., Preston, Marilyn, Klentz, Bannel and Steblay, Nancy (1983). ‘Fifteen Years of Foot-in-the-Door Research.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 9: 181–96CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becht, Marco, Patrick Bolton and Ailsa Röell (2002). ‘Corporate Governance and Corporate Control.’ ECGI Working Paper Series in Finance 02/2002
Bechtold, Stefan (2002). Vom Urheber-zum Informationsrecht. Implikationen des Digital Rights Management. Munich, BeckGoogle Scholar
Beckenkamp, Martin (2003). ‘Soziales Dilemma “Umwelt”. Spieltheoretische und psychologische Aspekte von Umweltproblemen’ (mimeo)
Becker, Gary Stanley (1962). ‘Irrational Behaviour and Economic Theory.’ Journal of Political Economy 70: 1–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary Stanley(1976). The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary Stanley(1993). Human Capital: a Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. Chicago, University of Chicago PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bem, Daryl J. (1967). ‘Self-Perception. The Dependent Variable of Human Performance.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Performance 2: 105–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bem, Daryl J.(1972). ‘Constructing Cross-Situational Consistencies in Behavior. Some Thoughts on Alker's Critique of Mischel.’ Journal of Personality 40: 17–26CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bem, Daryl J. and Allen, Andrea (1974). ‘On Predicting Some of the People Some of the Time. The Search for Cross-Situational Consistencies in Behavior.’ Psychological Review 81: 506–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benz, Matthias and Alois Stutzer (2002). ‘Do Workers Enjoy Procedural Utility?’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=336581CrossRef
Benz, Matthias, Bruno Frey and Alois Stutzer (2002). ‘Introducing Procedural Utility: Not Only What, but also How Matters.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=338568CrossRef
Berger, Peter L. and Luckmann, Thomas (1967). The Social Construction of Reality. A Treatise in the Sociology of Knowledge. Garden City, N. Y.,DoubledayGoogle Scholar
Berle, Adolf Augustus and Coit Means, Gardiner (1932). Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York and Chicago, Commerce Clearing House Loose leaf service division of the Corporation Trust CompanyGoogle Scholar
Betsch, Tilmann, Plessner, Henning, Schwieren, Chistiane and Gütig, Robert (2001). ‘I Like It but I Don't Know Why. A Value-Account Approach to Implicit Attitude Formation.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 27: 242–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bicchieri, Cristina, John Duffy and Gile Talle (2002). ‘Trust among Strangers.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=304344CrossRef
Biddle, Bruce J. (1986). ‘Recent Developments in Role Theory.’ Annual Review of Sociology 12: 67–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Biddle, Bruce J. and Thomas, Edwin J. (1979). Role Theory. Concepts and Research. Huntington, N. Y., R. E. KriegerGoogle Scholar
Bikhchandani, Sushil, Hirshleifer, David and Welch, Ivo (1992). ‘A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change in Informational Cascades.’ Journal of Political Economy 100: 992–1026CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, Ann-Renee and Weber, Elke U. (2001). ‘Domain-Specificity and Gender Differences in Decision Making.’ Risk Decision and Policy 6: 47–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohner, Gerd (2001). ‘Attitudes.’ Introduction to Social Psychology, ed. Hewstone, Miles and Stroebe, Wolfgang. Oxford, Blackwell: 239–82Google Scholar
Bohnet, Iris and Robert D. Cooter (2001). ‘Expressive Law. Framing or Equilibrium Selection?’ http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~.ibohnet.academic.ksg/Bohnet_Cooter.doc
Bone, John, Hey, John D. and Suckling, John (1999). ‘Are Groups More (or Less) Consistent than Individuals?Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 8: 63–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonus, Holger (1981). ‘Emissionsrechte als Mittel der Privatisierung öffentlicher Ressourcen aus der Umwelt.’ Marktwirtschaft und Umwelt, ed. Wegehenkel, Lothar. Tübingen, Mohr: 54–77Google Scholar
Bornschier, Volker (2001). ‘Generalisiertes Vertrauen und die frühe Verbreitung der Internetnutzung im Gesellschaftsvergleich.’ Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 53: 233–58CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boudon, Raymond (1987). ‘The Individualistic Tradition in Sociology.’ The Micro–Macro Link, ed. Alexander, Jeffrey, Giesen, Bernard, Münch, Richard and Smelser, Neil. Berkeley, University of California Press: 45–70Google Scholar
Boyd, Robert and Richerson, Peter J. (1994). ‘The Evolution of Norms. An Anthropological View.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150: 72–87Google Scholar
Brandenburger, Adam and Nalebuff, Barry (1996). Co-opetition. New York, DoubledayGoogle Scholar
Brandts, Jordi, Tatsuyoshi Saijo and Arthur Schram (2002). ‘How Universal is Behavior? A Four Country Comparison of Spite, Cooperation and Errors in Voluntary Contribution Mechanisms.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=254454
Brehm, Jack Williams (1966). A Theory of Psychological Reactance. New York, Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Brehm, Sharon S. and Williams Brehm, Jack (1981). Psychological Reactance. A Theory of Freedom and Control. New York, Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Brennan, Geoffrey and Pettit, Philip (2000). ‘The Hidden Economy of Esteem.’ Economics and Philosophy 16: 77–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brenner, Thomas (1999). Modelling Learning in Economics. Cheltenham and Northampton, Mass., Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Breyer, Stephen G. (1993). Breaking the Vicious Circle. Toward Effective Risk Regulation. Cambridge, Mass.,Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Brickman, Philip and Donald T. Campbell (1971). ‘Hedonic Relativism and Planning the Good Society.’ Adaptation-Level Theory, ed. Appley, Mortimer H.. New York, Academic Press: 287–301Google Scholar
Brocas, Isabelle and Juan D. Carillo (2002). ‘Are We All Better Drivers than Average? Self-Perception and Biased Behaviour.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=353784
Brosig, Jeannette, Weimann, Joachim and Ockenfels, Axel (2003). ‘The Effect of Communication Media on Cooperation.’ German Economic Review 4: 217–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brown, Donald E. (1991). Human Universals. New York, McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Brunswik, Egon, Hammond, Kenneth R. and Stewart, Thomas R. (2001). The Essential Brunswik. Beginnings, Explications, Applications. Oxford and New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. (1965). ‘An Economic Theory of Clubs.’ Economica 32: 1–14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962). The Calculus of Consent. Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Busemeyer, J. R. and Townsend, J. T. (1993). ‘Decision Field Theory. A Dynamic Cognitive Approach to Decision Making in an Uncertain Environment.’ Psychological Review 100: 432–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camerer, Colin F. (1987). ‘Do Biases in Probability Judgement Matter in Markets? Experimental Evidence.’ American Economic Review 77: 981–97Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin F.(1995). ‘Individual Decision Making.’ Handbook of Experimental Economics, ed. Kagel, John H. and Roth, Alvin E.. Princeton, Princeton University Press: 587–703Google Scholar
Camerer, Colin F. and Lovallo, Dan (1999). ‘Overconfidence and Excess Entry: an Experimental Approach.’ American Economic Review 89: 306–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, Judy (2001). ‘Negative Effects of Reward on Intrinsic Motivation: a Limited Phenomenon. Comment on Deci, Koestner, and Ryan (2001).’ Review of Educational Research 71: 29–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, Judy and Pierce, W. David (2001). Rewards and Intrinsic Motivation. Resolving the Controversy. Westport, BerginGoogle Scholar
Camp, Jean (2000). Trust and Risk in Internet Commerce. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Caplan, Bryan (2004). ‘Rational Ignorance.’ Encyclopedia of Public Choice, ed. Rowley, Charles K. and Schneider, Friedrich. Boston, KluwerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, Jeffrey (2002). ‘Punishing Free-Riders. How Group Size Affects Mutual Monitoring and the Provision of Public Goods. Middlebury Economics Discussion Paper 02–06. http://www.middlebury.edu/~econ/RePec/papers/02-06.pdf
Chaiken, Shelly and Trope, Yaacov (1999). Dual-process Theories in Social Psychology. New York, Guilford PressGoogle Scholar
Chamberlin, Edward (1933). The Theory of Monopolistic Competition. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Chapman, Gretchen B. and Bornstein, Brian H. (1996). ‘The More You Ask for, the More You Get. Anchoring in Personal Injury Verdicts.’ Applied Cognitive Psychology 10: 519–403.0.CO;2-5>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chapman, Gretchen B. and Johnson, Eric J. (1999). ‘Anchoring, Activation, and the Construction of Values.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 79: 115–53CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Charness, Gary and Haruvy, Ernan (2002). ‘Altruism, Equity, and Reciprocity in a Gift-Exchange Experiment. An Encompassing Approach.’ Games and Economic Behavior 40: 203–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, John Maurice (1961). Competition as a Dynamic Process. Washington, D.C., Brookings InstitutionGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald (1937). ‘The Nature of the Firm.’ Economica 4: 386–405CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald(1960). ‘The Problem of Social Cost.’ Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coglianese, Cary (2002). ‘Is Satisfaction Success? Evaluating Public Participation in Regulatory Policymaking.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=331420CrossRef
Cohen, Michael D. and Sproull, Lee S., eds. (1995). Organizational Learning. London, SageGoogle Scholar
Coleman, James Samuel (1987). ‘Psychological Structure and Social Structure in Economics Models.’ Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W.. Chicago, University of Chicago Press: 181–5Google Scholar
Coleman, James Samuel(1990). Foundations of Social Theory. Cambridge, Mass., Belknap Press of Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Collins, R. Lorraine and Clara M. Bradizza (2001). ‘Social and Cognitive Learning Processes.’ International Handbook of Alcohol Dependence and Problems, ed. Heather, Nick and Peters, Timothy J.. Chichester, Wiley: 317–37Google Scholar
Condorcet, Marie Jean Antoine Nicolas de Caritat, Marquis, (1785). Essai sur l'application de l'analyse de la probabilité des decisions rendues à la pluralité des voix. Paris, Imprimerie RoyaleGoogle Scholar
Conlisk, John (1996). ‘Why Bounded Rationality?Journal of Economic Literature 34: 669–700Google Scholar
Cook, Karen S., ed. (2001). Trust in Society, Russell Sage Foundation series on trust, vol. II. New York, Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Cooter, Robert (1998). ‘Expressive Law and Economics.’ Journal of Legal Studies 27: 585–608CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooter, Robert and Ulen, Thomas (2004). Law and Economics. Boston, Addison Wesley LongmanGoogle Scholar
Cornes, Richard and Sandler, Todd (1996). The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods and Club Goods. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John (1989). ‘Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture: II. Case Study: a Computational Theory of Social Exchange.’ Ethology and Sociobiology 10: 51–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John(1992). ‘Cognitive Adaptations for Social Exchange.’ The Adapted Mind. Evolutionary Psychology and the Generation of Culture, ed. Barkow, Jerome, Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John. New York, Oxford University Press: 163–228Google Scholar
Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John(1994). ‘Better than Rational. Evolutionary Psychology and the Invisible Hand.’ American Economic Association Papers and Proceedings 84: 327–32Google Scholar
Cowan, Robin, David, Paul A. and Dominique, Foray, (2000). ‘The Explicit Economics of Knowledge Codification and Tacitness.’ Industrial and Corporate Change 9: 211–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crawford, Vincent (1998). ‘A Survey of Experiments on Communication via Cheap Talk.’ Journal of Economic Theory 78 (2): 286–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Czybulka, Detlef (1995). ‘Gewerbenebenrecht. Handwerksrecht and Gaststättenrecht.’ Öffentliches Wirtschaftsrecht Besonderer Teil 1, ed. Schmidt, Reiner. Berlin, Springer: 111–218CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dalton, Russell D. (1996). ‘Comparative Politics: Micro-Behavioral Perspectives.’ A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 336–52Google Scholar
Dawes, Robyn M. (1999). ‘A Message from Psychologists to Economists: Mere Predictability Doesn't Matter Like It Should (without a Good Story Appended to It).’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 39: 29–40CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, Edward L. (1975). Intrinsic Motivation. New York, Plenum PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, Edward L. and Ryan, Richard M. (1985). Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behaviour. New York, Plenum PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, Edward L.,Koestner, Richard and Ryan, Richard M. (1999). ‘A Meta-Analytic Review of Experiments Examining the Effects of Extrinsic Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation.’ Psychological Bulletin 125: 627–68CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Deci, Edward L.,Koestner, Richard, and Ryan, Richard M. (2001a). ‘Extrinsic Rewards and Intrinsic Motivation in Education. Reconsidered Once Again.’ Review of Educational Research 71: 1–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deci, Edward L.,Ryan, Richard M. and Koestner, Richard (2001b). ‘The Pervasive Negative Effects of Rewards on Intrinsic Motivation: Response to Cameron (2001).’ Review of Educational Research 71: 43–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dekel, Eddie, Lipman, Barton L. and Rustichini, Aldo (1998). ‘Standard State-Space Models Preclude Unawareness.’ Econometrica 66: 159–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delgado, Jose M. R. (2000). ‘Neuronal Imprinting of Human Values.’ International Journal of Psychophysiology 35: 237–46CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Denzau, Arthur and Cecil North, Douglass (1994). ‘Shared Mental Models. Ideologies and Institutions.’ Kyklos 47: 3–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Descartes, René (1664). De Homine. Lvgdvni Batavorvm, Officina HackianaGoogle Scholar
Dessler, David (1989). ‘What's at Stake in the Agent–Structure Debate?International Organization 43: 441–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Devetag, Giovanna (2000). ‘From Utilities to Mental Models. A Critical Survey on Decision Rules and Cognition in Consumer Choice.’ Industrial and Corporate Change 8: 289–351CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickenberger, Dorothee, Gisla Gniech and Hans-Joachim Grabitz (1993). ‘Die Theorie der psychologischen Reaktanz.’ Theorien der Sozialpsychologie I: Kognitive Theorien, ed. Frey, Dieter and Irle, Martin. Berne, Huber: 243–74Google Scholar
Dillard, James, Hunter, John and Burgoon, Michael (1984). ‘Sequential Request Persuasive Strategies. Meta-Analysis of Foot-in-the-Door and Door-in-the-Face.’ Human Communication Research 10: 461–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dilthey, Wilhelm (1923). ‘Die Entstehung der Hermeneutik.’ Gesammelte Schriften V, ed. Dilthey, Wilhelm. Leipzig, Teubner: 317–31Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J. (1998). ‘The New Institutionalisms. Avenues of Collaboration.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 154: 696–705Google Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J. and Walter W. Powell (1991). ‘Introduction.’ The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis, ed. Powell, Walter W. and DiMaggio, Paul J.. Chicago, University of Chicago Press: 1–38Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash K. and Nalebuff, Barry J. (1991). Thinking Strategically. The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics, and Everyday Life. New York, NortonGoogle Scholar
Domjan, Michael (1998). The Principles of Learning and Behavior. Pacific Grove, Calif.,Brooks/ColeGoogle Scholar
Donald, Merlin (1999). ‘Hominid Enculturation and Cognitive Evolution.’ Cognition and Material Culture. The Archaeology of Symbolic Storage, ed. Renfrew, Colin and Scarre, Chris. Cambridge, McDonald Institute for Archaeological Research: 7–17Google Scholar
Donnell, A. J., Thomas, A. and Buboltz, W. C. (2001). ‘Psychological Reactance. Factor Structure and Internal Consistency of the Questionnaire for the Measurement of Psychological Reactance.’ Journal of Social Psychology 141 (5): 679–87CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Druckman, James (2001). ‘Using Credible Advice to Overcome Framing Effects.’ Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 17: 62–82CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dudycha, G. J. (1936). ‘An Objective Study in Personality.’ Archives of Psychology 29: 1–53Google Scholar
Dunn, John (1988). ‘Trust and Political Agency.’ Trust. Making and Breaking Cooperative Relations, ed. Gambetta, David. New York, Blackwell: 73–93Google Scholar
Easton, David (1965). A Systems Analysis of Political Life. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Edelman, Murray J. (1964). The Symbolic Uses of Politics. Urbana, University of Illinois PressGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, Thrainn (1990). Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eichberger, Jürgen, David Kelsey and Burkhard Schipper (2003). ‘Ambiguity and Social Interaction.’ http://with1.awi.uni-heidelberg.de/Publik/social-interaction-dk.pdfCrossRef
Eichenberger, Reiner (2002). ‘Wissen und Information in ökonomischer Perspektive.’ Wissen, Nichtwissen, Unsicheres Wissen, ed. Engel, Christoph, Halfmann, Jost and Schulte, Martin. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 75–92Google Scholar
Eisenberg, Andrea (2001). Stabilität and Wandel informeller Institutionen. Selbstorganisation und interdependente Prozesse. Wiesbaden, GablerGoogle Scholar
Ellickson, Robert C. (1991). Order without Law. How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, Mass.,Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Ellsberg, Daniel (1961). ‘Risk, Ambiguity, and the Savage Axioms.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 75: 643–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon (1979). Ulysses and the Sirens. Studies in Rationality and Irrationality. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon(1989). The Cement of Society. A Study of Social Order. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, Jon(1998). ‘Emotions and Economic Theory.’ Journal of Economic Literature 36: 47–74Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph (1999). ‘Vertrauen – ein Versuch.’ Preprints aus der Max-Planck-Projektgruppe Recht der Gemeinschaftsgüter Bonn 1999/12
Engel, Christoph(2000). ‘The Internet and the Nation State.’ Understanding the Impact of Global Networks on Local Social, Political and Cultural Values, ed. Engel, Christoph and Keller, Kenneth H.. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 201–60Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2001a). ‘Die Grammatik des Rechts.’ Instrumente des Umweltschutzes im Wirkungsverbund, ed. Rengeling, Hans-Werner. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 17–49Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2001b). ‘Hybrid Governance across National Jurisdictions as a Challenge to Constitutional Law.’ European Business Organisation Law Review 2: 569–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2001c). ‘Institutionen zwischen Staat und Markt.’ Die Verwaltung 34: 1–24Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2001d). ‘Offene Gemeinwohldefinitionen.’ Rechtstheorie 32: 23–52Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2002a). Abfallrecht und Abfallpolitik. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2002b). ‘Die soziale Funktion des Eigentums.’ Bericht zur Lage des Eigentums, ed. Depenheuer, Otto, Engel, Christoph and Danwitz, Thomas. Berlin, Springer: 1–107Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2003a). ‘Causes and Management of Conflicts.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 159: 1–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2003b). ‘The Constitutional Court – Applying the Proportionality Principle – as a Subsidiary Authority for the Assessment of Political Outcomes.’ Linking Political Science and the Law, ed. Engel, Christoph and Héritier, Adrienne. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 285–314Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2003c). ‘Governing the Egalitarians from Without. The Case of the Internet.’ Preprints aus der Max-Planck-Projektgruppe Recht der Gemeinschaftsgüter 2003/10
Engel, Christoph(2003d). ‘Die Internet-Service-Provider als Geiseln deutscher Ordnungsbehörden. Eine Kritik der Verfügungen der Bezirksregierung Düsseldorf.’ Multimedia und Recht 6, supplement 4: 1–35Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2004a). ‘A Constitutional Framework for Private Governance.’ German Law Journal 5: 197–236Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(2004b). ‘Marktabgrenzung als soziale Konstruktion.’ Festschrift Immenga, ed. Fuchs, Andreas, Schwintowski, Hans Peter and Zimmer, Daniel. Munich, Beck: 127–47Google Scholar
Engel, Christoph(forthcoming) ‘Autonomie und Freiheit’ Handbuch der Grundrechte II, ed. Merten, Detlef and Papier, Hans-Jürgen. Heidelberg, C. F. Müller
Engel, Christoph and Schweizer, Urs (2002). ‘Organising and Designing Markets.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 158: 1–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Engelmann, Dirk (2001). ‘Asymmetric Type Recognition with Applications to Dilemma Games.’ Metronomica 52: 357–75Google Scholar
Beate, Englich and Mussweiler, Thomas (2001). ‘Sentencing under Uncertainty. Anchoring Effects in the Court Room.’ Journal of Applied Social Psychology 31: 1535–51Google Scholar
Epley, Nicolas and Gilovich, Thomas (2001). ‘Putting Adjustment Back in the Anchoring and Adjustment Heuristic. Differential Processing of Self-Generated and Experimenter-Provided Anchors.’ Psychological Science 12: 391–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, S. (1977). ‘Traits are Alive and Well.’ Personality at the Crossroads: Current Issues in Interactional Psychology, ed. Magnusson, David and Endler, Norman Solomon. Hillsdale, Erlbaum: 83–98Google Scholar
Epstein, S(1979). ‘The Stability of Behavior. I. On Predicting Most of the People Most of the Time.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 37: 1097–126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eriksson, Anders and Lindgren, Kristian (2002). ‘Cooperation in an Unpredictable Environment.’ Artificial Life 8: 394–99Google Scholar
Evans, Jonathan St. B. T. (1993). ‘Bias and Rationality.’ Rationality. Psychological and Philosophical Perspectives, ed. Manktelow, K. I. and Over, David E.. London, Routledge: 6–29Google Scholar
Evans, Jonathan B. T. St and Over, David E. (1997). ‘Are People Rational? Yes, No, and Sometimes.’ Psychologist: 403–6Google Scholar
Falk, Armin, Fehr, Ernst and Fischbacher, Urs (2003). ‘Reasons for Conflict. Lessons from Bargaining Experiments.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 159: 171–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farnsworth, Ward (2000). ‘Do Parties to Nuisance Cases Bargain after Judgement? A Glimpse into the Cathedral.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 302–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farnsworth, Ward(2001). ‘The Taste for Fairness.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=305761
Farnsworth, Ward(2002). ‘The Economics of Enmity.’ University of Chicago Law Review 69: 211–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farnsworth, Ward(2003). ‘The Legal Management of Self-Serving Bias.’ University of California at Davis Law Review 37: 567–603Google Scholar
Farrell, Joseph and Rabin, Matthew (1996). ‘Cheap Talk.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 10: 103–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fazio, Russell H. (1990). ‘Multiple Processes by which Attitudes Guide Behavior. The MODE Model as an Integrative Framework.’ Advances in Experimental Social Psychology 23, ed. Zanna, Mark P.. San Diego, Academic Press: 75–109Google Scholar
Fazio, Russell H.(2001). ‘On the Automatic Activation of Associated Evaluations. An Overview.’ Cognition and Emotion 15: 115–41CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst (2000). ‘Cooperation and Punishment in Public Goods Experiments.’ American Economic Review 90: 980–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Falk, Armin (2002). ‘Psychological Foundations of Incentives.’ European Economic Review 46: 687–724CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Simon Gaechter (2001). ‘Do Incentive Contracts Crowd out Voluntary Cooperation?’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=289680
Fehr, Ernst and Simon Gaechter(2002). ‘Do Incentive Contracts Undermine Voluntary Cooperation?’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=313028CrossRef
Fehr, Ernst and Schmidt, Klaus M. (1999). ‘A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 817–68CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Klaus M. Schmidt(2000). ‘Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity – Evidence and Economic Applications.’ CESifo Working Paper Series No. 403. http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=255223
Fehr, Ernst and Tyran, Jean-Robert (1996). ‘How Do Institutions and Fairness Interact?Central European Journal for Operations Research & Economics 4: 69–84Google Scholar
Fehr, Ernst and Zych, Peter K. (1998). ‘Do Addicts Behave Rationally?Scandinavian Journal of Economics 100: 643–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, Ernst, Gaechter, Simon and Kirchsteiger, Georg (1997). ‘Reciprocity as a Contract Enforcement Device. Experimental Evidence.’ Econometrica 65: 833–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feldman, Allan M. (1980). Welfare Economics and Social Choice Theory. Boston, Martinus NijhoffCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferejohn, John A. and Fiorina, Morris P. (1974). ‘The Paradox of Not Voting. A Decision Theoretic Analysis.’ American Political Science Review 68: 525–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Festinger, Leon (1957). A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. Evanston, Ill., Row PetersonGoogle Scholar
Festinger, Leon and Carlsmith, James M. (1959). ‘Cognitive Consequences of Forced Compliance.’ Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology 58: 203–10CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fiedler, Klaus (2000). ‘Beware of Samples! A Cognitive-Ecological Sampling Approach to Judgement Bias.’ Psychological Review 107: 659–76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiedler, Klaus, Walther, Eva and Nickel, Stefanie (1999). ‘The Autoverification of Social Hypotheses. Stereotyping and the Power of Sample Size.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 77: 5–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiedler, Klaus, Schmid, Jeannette and Stahl, Teresa (2002). ‘What is the Current Truth about Polygraph Lie Detection?Basic and Applied Social Psychology 24: 313–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischhoff, Baruch (2000). ‘Value Elicitation. Is There Anything in There?’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 620–41Google Scholar
Fishbein, Martin and Ajzen, Icek (1975). Belief, Attitude, Intention, and Behavior. An Introduction to Theory and Research. Reading, Mass., Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Fiske, Alan Page (1991). Structures of Social Life. The Four Elementary Forms of Human Relations: Communal Sharing, Authority Ranking, Equality Matching, Market Pricing. New York, Free Press and MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Forest Nelson, George Newman and Jack Wright (1991). ‘The Iowa Presidential Stock Market. A Field Experiment.’ Research in Experimental Economics, ed. Isaac, R. Mark. Greenwich, Conn., JAI Press: 1–43Google Scholar
Forsythe, Robert, Lundholm, Russell and Rietz, Thomas (1999). ‘Cheap Talk, Fraud, and Adverse Selection in Financial Markets. Some Experimental Evidence.’ Review of Financial Studies 12: 481–518CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, Craig R. and Amos Tversky (2000). ‘Ambiguity Aversion and Comparative Ignorance.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 528–42Google Scholar
Frank, Robert H. (1985). Choosing the Right Pond. Human Behavior and the Quest for Status. New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Frank, Robert H.(1988). Passions within Reason. The Strategic Role of the Emotions. New York, NortonGoogle Scholar
Freedman, Jonathan L. and Scott, C. Fraser (1966). ‘Compliance without Pressure. The Foot-in-the-Door Technique.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 4: 195–202CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Frey, Bruno S. ed. (1999a). Economics as a Science of Human Behaviour. Towards a New Social Science Paradigm. Boston and Dordrecht, KluwerCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno(1999b). ‘The Price System and Morals.’ Economics as a Science of Human Behaviour. Towards a New Social Science Paradigm, ed. Frey, Bruno. Boston: 159–75CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno and Eichenberger, Reiner (1994). ‘Economic Incentives Transform Psychological Anomalies.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 23: 215–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno and Jegen, Reto (2001). ‘Motivation Crowding Theory. A Survey of Empirical Evidence.’ Journal of Economic Surveys 15: 589–611CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, Bruno and Alois Stutzer (2001). ‘Beyond Bentham – Measuring Procedural Utility.’ CESifo Working Papers 492. http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=268059.
Frey, Bruno and Stutzer, Alois(2002). Happiness and Economics. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Daniel (1998). ‘Monty Hall's Three Doors. Construction and Deconstruction of a Choice Anomaly.’ American Economic Review 88: 933–46Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton (1953). Essays in Positive Economics. [Chicago], University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Friedmann, Daniel (1989). ‘The Efficient Breach Fallacy.’ Journal of Legal Studies 18: 1–24CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedrich, James (2000). ‘Fleshing out a Dual-system Solution.’ Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 671–2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frowein, Jochen A. (2000). ‘Konstitutionalisierung des Völkerrechts.’ Berichte der Deutschen Gesellschaft für Völkerrecht 39: 427–47Google Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew and , David K. Levine (1998). The Theory of Learning in Games. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Funder, David C. (2000). ‘Gone with the Wind. Individual Differences in Heuristics and Biases Undermine the Implication of Systematic Irrationality.’ Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 673–4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Funder, David C. and Colvin, C. Randall (1991). ‘Explorations in Behavioral Consistency. Properties of Persons, Situations and Behaviors.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 60: 773–94CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Furubotn, Eirik Grundtvig and Richter, Rudolf (1997). Institutions and Economic Theory. The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Garvin, Susan and Kagel, John H. (1994). ‘Learning in Common Value Auctions – Some Initial Observations.’ Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 25 (3): 351–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Geertz, Clifford (1973). ‘Thick Description. Toward an Interpretive Theory of Culture.’ The Interpretation of Cultures, ed. Geertz, Clifford. New York, Basic Books: 3–30Google Scholar
Gehlen, Arnold (1960). ‘Mensch and Institutionen.’ Anthropologische Forschung. Zur Selbstbegegnung und Selbstentdeckung des Menschen, ed. Gehlen, Arnold. Hamburg, Rowohlt: 69–77Google Scholar
Geiger, Theodor Julius and Rehbinder, Manfred (1987). Vorstudien zu einer Soziologie des Rechts. Berlin, Duncker & HumblotCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gentner, Dedre and Stevens, Albert L. (1983). Mental Models. Hillsdale, N. J., ErlbaumGoogle Scholar
Gentner, Dedre, Holyoak, Keith J. and Kokinov, Boicho N., eds. (2001). The Analogical Mind. Perspectives from Cognitive Science.Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press
Gérard-Varet, L. A., Kolm, Serge-Christophe and Ythier, J. Mercier, eds. (2000). The Economics of Reciprocity, Giving, and Altruism. Houndmills, Basingstoke, Macmillan; New York, St Martin's PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gibbons, Robert (1998). ‘Incentives in Organizations.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 12: 115–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gifford, Sharon (2001). ‘Limited Attention as the Bound on Rationality.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=262181
Gigerenzer, Gerd, ed. (2000a). Adaptive Thinking. Rationality in the Real World. Oxford, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd(2000b). ‘How to Make Cognitive Illusions Disappear.’ Adaptive Thinking. Rationality in the Real World, ed. Gigerenzer, Gerd. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 241–66Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd, Todd, Peter M. and ABC Research Group (1999). Simple Heuristics that Make us Smart. New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Glenn, H. Patrick (1997). ‘The Capture, Reconstruction and Marginalization of “Custom”.’ American Journal of Comparative Law 45: 613–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glimcher, Paul W. (2003). Decisions, Uncertainty, and the Brain. The Science of Neuroeconomics. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Gode, Dhananjay K. and Sunder, Shyam (1993). ‘Allocative Efficiency of Markets with Zero-Intelligence Traders. Market as a Partial Substitute for Individual Irrationality.’ Journal of Political Economy 101: 119–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goffman, Erving (1956). The Presentation of Self in Everyday Life. Edinburgh, University of Edinburgh Social Sciences Research CentreGoogle Scholar
Goldstein, William M. and Robin M. Hogarth (1997). ‘Judgment and Decision Research. Some Historical Context.’ Research on Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 3–65Google Scholar
Goldstein, William M. and Elke U. Weber (1997). ‘Content and Discontent. Indications and Implications of Domain Specificity in Preferential Decision Making.’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 566–617Google Scholar
Granovetter, Marc (1985). ‘Economic Action and Social Structure. The Problem of Embeddedness.’ American Journal of Sociology 91: 481–510CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grether, David M. (1980). ‘Bayes' Rule as a Descriptive Model. The Representativeness Heuristic.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 95: 537–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grether, David M.(1992). ‘Testing Bayes' Rule and the Representativeness Heuristic: Some Experimental Evidence.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 17: 31–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grunberg, Emile and Modigliani, Franco (1954). ‘The Predictability of Social Events.’ Journal of Political Economy 52: 465–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gruter, Margaret and Masters, Roger D., eds. (1986). Ostracism. A Social and Biological Phenomenon. New York, ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Guesnerie, Roger (2001). ‘The Government and Market Expectations.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 157: 116–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Güth, Werner and Hartmut Kliemt (2003). ‘Perfect or Bounded Rationality? Some Facts, Speculations and Proposals’ (mimeo)
Güth, Werner, Schmittberger, Rolf and Schwarze, Bernd (1982). ‘An Experimental Analysis of Ultimatum Bargaining.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 3: 367–88CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter and Taylor, Rosemary C. R. (1996). ‘Political Science and the Three New Institutionalisms.’ Political Studies 44: 936–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, Walton H. (1932). ‘Institution.’ Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, ed. Seligman, Edwin R. A. and Johnson, Alvin. New York, Macmillan: 84–9Google Scholar
Hammond, Daniel J. (1990). ‘Realism in Friedman's Essays in Positive Economics.’ Perspectives on the History of Economic Thought. Vol. IV. Keynes, Macroeconomics and Method. Selected Papers from the History of Economics Society Conference, ed. Moggridge, Donald E.. Aldershot, Edward Elgar: 194–208Google Scholar
Hanoch, Yaniv (2002). ‘Neither an Angel nor an Ant: Emotion as an Aid to Bounded Rationality.’ Journal of Economic Psychology 23: 1–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansjürgens, Bernd and Lübbe-Wolff, Gertrude, eds. (2000). Symbolische Umweltpolitik. Frankfurt, SuhrkampGoogle Scholar
Harbaugh, William T. and Krause, Kate (2000). ‘Children's Altruism in Public Good and Dictator Experiments.’ Economic Inquiry 38: 95–109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Garrett (1968). ‘The Tragedy of the Commons.’ Science 162: 1243–8Google ScholarPubMed
Hardin, Russell (2001). ‘Conceptions and Explanations of Trust.’ Trust in Society, ed. Cook, Karen S.. New York, Russell Sage Foundation: 3–39Google Scholar
Hardin, Russell(2002). Trust and Trustworthiness. New York, Russell Sage FoundationGoogle Scholar
Harless, David W. and Camerer, Colin F. (1994). ‘The Predictive Utility of Generalized Expected Utility Theories.’ Econometrica 62: 1251–89CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John (1967–68). ‘Games with Incomplete Information Played by “Bayesian” Players.’ Management Science 14: 159–82, 320–4, 486–502CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hartshorne, Hugh, Arthur May, Mark, Maller, Julius Bernard and Shuttleworth, Frank K. (1928). Studies in the Nature of Character. New York, MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Hartwick, John M. and Olewiler, Nancy D. (1998). The Economics of Natural Resource Use. Reading, Mass., Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Hastie, Reid and Bernadette Park (1997). ‘The Relationship between Memory and Judgement Depends on whether the Judgement Task is Memory-Based or On-Line.’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 431–53Google Scholar
Hayashi, Nahoko, Ostrom, Elinor, Walker, James M. and Yanagishi, Toshio (1999). ‘Reciprocity, Trust, and the Sense of Control. A Cross-Societal Study.’ Rationality and Society 11: 27–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heath, Chip (1995). ‘Escalation and De-Escalation of Commitment in Response to Sunk Costs. The Role of Budgeting in Mental Accounting.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 62: 38–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hebb, Donald O. (1949). The Organization of Behavior. A Neuropsychological Theory. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Heifetz, Aviad, Martin Meier and Burkhard Schipper (2003). ‘Interactive Unawareness and Speculative Trade.’ http://www.tau.ac.il/~heifetz/interactive_unawareness.pdf
Heiner, Ronald A. (1983). ‘The Origin of Predictable Behavior.’ American Economic Review 73: 560–95Google Scholar
Heiner, Ronald A.(1985a). ‘Origin of Predictable Behavior: Further Modeling and Applications.’ American Economic Review 75: 391–6Google Scholar
Heiner, Ronald A.(1985b). ‘Predictable Behavior: Reply.’ American Economic Review 75: 579–85Google Scholar
Heiner, Ronald A.(1989). ‘The Origin of Predictable Dynamic Behavior.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 12: 233–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, Joseph and Robert Boyd (2001). ‘“Economic Man” in Cross-Cultural Perspective. Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies.’ http://www.sscnet.ucla.edu/anthro/faculty/boyd/MacGamesBBSFinal.pdf
Hermalin, Benjamin E. and Alice M. Isen (1999). ‘The Effect of Affect on Economic and Strategic Decision Making.’ University of California, Berkeley, Department of Economics Working Paper: E99/270
Hirschman, Albert O. (1970). Exit, Voice, and Loyalty. Responses to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack (1987). ‘On the Emotions as Guarantors of Threats and Promises.’ The Latest on the Best: Essays on Evolution and Optimality, ed. Dupre, John. Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press: 307–26Google Scholar
Hirt, Edward R. and Markman, Keith D. (1995). ‘Multiple Explanation – a Consider-an-Alternative Strategy for Debiasing Judgments.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 69 (6): 1069–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas (1651). Leviathan, or, The matter, forme, & power of a common-wealth ecclesiasticall and civill. London, Printed for Andrew Crooke, i.e. Crooke at the Green Dragon in St Pauls Church-yard
Hodgson, Geoffrey Martin (1988). Economics and Institutions. A Manifesto for a Modern Institutional Economics. Philadelphia, University of Pennsylvania PressGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey Martin(1998). ‘The Approach of Institutional Economics.’ Journal of Economic Literature 36: 166–92Google Scholar
Hoffmann, Elizabeth and Spitzer, Matthew L. (1985). ‘Entitlements, Rights, and Fairness. An Experimental Examination of Subject's Concepts of Distributive Justice.’ Journal of Legal Studies 14: 259–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffrage, Ulrich, Gigerenzer, Gerd, Krauss, Stefan and Mastignan, Larva (2002). ‘Representation Facilitates Reasoning. What Natural Frequencies Are and What They Are Not.’ Cognition 84: 343–52CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hogarth, Robin M. and Howard Kunreuther (1997). ‘Decision Making under Ignorance. Arguing with Yourself.’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 482–508Google Scholar
Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W., eds. (1986). Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology. Chicago, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hogarth, Robin M., Brian J. Gibbs, Craig R. M. McKerzie and Margaret A. Marquis (1997). ‘Learning from Feedback. Exactingness and Incentives.’ Research on Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 244–84Google Scholar
Holzinger, Katharina (2003). ‘The Problems of Collective Action. A New Approach.’ http://www.mpp-rdg.mpg.de/pdf_dat/2003_2.pdf
Homann, Karl and Suchanek, Andreas (2000). Ökonomik. Eine Einführung. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Honderich, Ted, ed. (1985). Morality and Rehibutive Emotions: a Tribute to John L. Maclire. London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Hopkins, Nick and Murdoch, Neil (1999). ‘The Role of the “Other” in National Identity. Exploring the Context-Dependence of the National Ingroup Stereotype.’ Journal of Community & Applied Social Psychology 9: 321–383.0.CO;2-M>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hsee, Christopher K. (2000). ‘Attribute Evaluability. Its Implications for Joint-Separate Evaluation Reversals and Beyond.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 543–63Google Scholar
Hsee, Christopher K., Zhang, Jiao, Yu, Fang and Xi, Yiheng (2003). ‘Lay Rationalism, and Inconsistency between Decision and Predicted Experience.’ Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 16: 257–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hume, David (1739). A Treatise of Human Nature. Oxford, Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Immergut, Ellen M. (1998). ‘The Theoretical Core of the New Institutionalism.’ Politics and Society 26: 5–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jackman, Simon and Paul M. Sniderman (2002). ‘Institutional Organization of Choice Spaces. A Political Conception of Political Psychology.’ Political Psychology, ed. Monroe, K. R.. Mahweh, Erlbaum: 209–24Google Scholar
Jakobs, Günther (1999). Norm, Person, Gesellschaft. Vorüberlegungen zu einer Rechtsphilosophie. Berlin, Duncker & HumblotGoogle Scholar
James, William (1890). The Principles of Psychology. New York, H. HoltGoogle Scholar
Janssen, Maarten W. C. and Mendys, Ewa (2004). ‘The Price of a Price. On the Crowding out of Social Norms.’ Journal of Economic Behaviour & Organization 55: 377–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Japp, Klaus P. (2002). ‘Struktureffekte öffentlicher Risikokommunikation auf Regulierungsregime. Zur Funktion von Nichtwissen im BSE-Konflikt,’ in Wissen, Nichtwissen, Unsicheres Wissen, ed. Engel, Christoph, Halfmann, Jost and Schulte, Martin. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 35–74Google Scholar
Jensen, Michael C. and Meckling, William H. (1976). ‘Theory of the Firm. Managerial Behaviour, Agency Cost and Ownership Structure.’ Journal of Financial Economics 3: 305–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jickeli, Joachim (1990). Marktzutrittsschranken im Recht der Wettbewerbsbeschränkungen. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Jickeli, Joachim(1996). Der langfristige Vertrag. Eine rechtswissenschaftliche Untersuchung auf institutionen-ökonomischer Grundlage. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Johnson-Laird, Philip N. (1983). Mental Models. Towards a Cognitive Science of Language, Inference and Consciousness. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Johnson-Laird, Philip N.(1989). ‘Mental Models.’ Foundations of Cognitive Science, ed. Posner, Michael. Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press: 469–99Google Scholar
Jolls, Christine (2000). ‘Behavioural Economic Analysis of Redistributive Legal Rules.’ Behavioural Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 288–301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jolls, Christine, Sunstein, Cass R. and Thaler, Richard H. (1998). ‘A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics.’ Stanford Law Review 50: 1471–550CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jolls, Christine, Sunstein, Cass R., and Thaler, Richard H.(2000). ‘A Behavioural Approach to Law and Economics.’ Behavioural Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 13–58Google Scholar
Jones, Edward Ellsworth and Richard E. Nisbett (1972). ‘The Actor and the Observer. Divergent Perceptions of the Causes of Behavior.’ Attribution. Perceiving the Causes of Behavior, ed. Jones, Edward Ellsworth. Morristown, General Learning Press: 79–94Google Scholar
Jones, Phil, ed. (1999). Taboo. Philadelphia, Jessika KingsleyGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel (1986). ‘Fairness and the Assumptions of Economics.’ Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W.. Chicago, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel(1992). ‘Reference Points, Anchors, Norms, and Mixed Feelings.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 51: 296–312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel(2000a). ‘Evaluation by Moments. Past and Future.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 693–708Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel(2000b). ‘Experienced Utility and Objective Happiness. A Moment-Based Approach.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambrdige University Press: 673–92Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel(2000c). Preface. Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: ix–xviiGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Dan Lovallo (2000). ‘Timid Choices and Bold Forecasts. A Cognitive Perspective on Risk Taking.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 393–413Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Jackie Snell (1997). ‘Predicting a Changing Taste. Do People Know What They Will Like?’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 393–410Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos (1972). ‘Subjective Probability. A Judgement of Representativeness.’ Cognitive Psychology 3: 430–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(1973). ‘Availability. A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and Probability.’ Cognitive Psychology 4: 207–32Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(1979). ‘Prospect Theory. An Analysis of Decision under Risk.’ Econometrica 47: 263–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(1995). ‘Conflict Resolution. A Cognitive Perspective.’ Barriers to Conflict Resolution, ed. Arrow, Kenneth Joseph, Mnookin, Robert H., Ross, Lee, Tversky, Amos and Wilson, Robert B.. New York, Norton: 44–61Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(2000a). Choices, Values, and Frames. Cambridge, Russell Sage Foundation and Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(2000b). ‘Choices, Values, and Frames.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 1–16Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos(2000c). ‘Prospect Theory. An Analysis of Decision under Risk.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 17–43Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Slovic, Paul and Tversky, Amos (1982). Judgment under Uncertainty. Heuristics and Biases. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch and Richard H. Thaler (2000a). ‘Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 211–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch and Richard H. Thaler (2000b). ‘Fairness as a Constraint on Profit Seeking. Entitlements in the Market.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 317–34Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Ilana Ritov and David Schkade (2000c). ‘Economic Preferences or Attitude Expressions? An Analysis of Dollar Responses to Public Issues.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 642–71Google Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro (2002). ‘Introduction to Repeated Games with Private Monitoring.’ Journal of Economic Theory 102: 1–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, Todd R. and Bradley J. Ruffle (2001). ‘The Self-Serving Bias and Beliefs about Rationality.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=251308CrossRef
Kaufman, Bruce E. (1999). ‘Emotional Arousal as a Source of Bounded Rationality.’ Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 38: 135–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kelman, Mark, Yuval Rottenstreich and Amos Tversky (2000). ‘Context-Dependence in Legal Decision Making.’ Behavioural Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 61–94CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keren, Gideon (1990). ‘Cognitive Aids and Debiasing Methods. Can Cognitive Pills Cure Cognitive Ills?’ Cognitive Biases, ed. Caverni, Jean-Paul and Fabre, Jean-Marc. Amsterdam, North Holland: 523–52Google Scholar
Kersting, Wolfgang (1994). Die politische Philosophie des Gesellschaftsvertrags. Darmstadt, Wissenschaftliche BuchgesellschaftGoogle Scholar
Kersting, Wolfgang(1997). ‘Methodologische Probleme einer Theorie der sozialen Gerechtigkeit.’ Recht, Gerechtigkeit und demokratische Tugend. Abhandlungen zur praktischen Philosophie der Gegenwart, ed. Kersting, Wolfgang. Frankfurt, Suhrkamp: 213–42Google Scholar
Kiesler, Sara B. (1973). ‘Preference for Predictability or Unpredictability as a Mediator of Reactions to Norm Violations.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 27: 354–9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard (1992). ‘Towards a Theory of Low-Cost Decisions.’ European Journal of Political Economy 8: 305–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard(1996). ‘Bemerkungen zur Minimalmoral.’ Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften 116: 223–51Google Scholar
Kirchgässner, Gebhard and Pommerehne, Werner (1993). ‘Low Cost Decisions as a Challenge to Public Choice.’ Public Choice 77: 107–15CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirchhof, Ferdinand (1987). Private Rechtsetzung. Berlin, Duncker & HumblotGoogle Scholar
Klein, Gary (2001). ‘The Fiction of Optimization.’ Bounded Rationality. The Adaptive Toolbox. Dahlem Workshop Report, ed. Gerd Gigerenzer and Reinhard Selten. Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press: 103–21Google Scholar
Knight, Frank Hyneman (1921). Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. Boston and New York, Houghton MifflinGoogle Scholar
Knight, Jack (1992). Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, Jack and Itai Sened (1995). ‘Introduction.’ Explaining Social Institutions, ed. Knight, Jack and Sened, Itai. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan PressGoogle Scholar
Knill, Christoph and Andrea Lenschow (1999). ‘Governance im Mehrebenensystem. Die institutionellen Grenzen effektiver Implementation in der europäischen Umweltpolitik.’ Preprints aus der Max-Planck-Projektgruppe Recht der Gemeinschaftsgüter Bonn 1999/1. http://www.mpp-rdg.mpg.de/extern/pdf_dat/9808.pdf
Kofman, Fred and Lawarree, Jacques (1996). ‘On the Optimality of Allowing Collusion.’ Journal of Public Economics 61: 383–407CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koriat, Asher, Lichtenstein, Sarah and Fischhoff, Baruch (1980). ‘Reasons for Confidence.’ Journal of Experimental Psychology 6: 107–18Google Scholar
Korobkin, Russell B. and Ulen, Thomas S. (2000). ‘Law and Behavioral Science. Removing the Rationality Assumption from Law and Economics.’ California Law Review 88: 1051–144CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kötz, Hein (1996). Europäisches Vertragsrecht I. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Krause, Bodo (1991). ‘Components of Cognitive Learning.’ Zeitschrift für Psychologie 199: 35–44Google Scholar
Krause, Bodo(1992). ‘Kognitives Lernen. Ansätze und experimentelle Befunde.’ Zeitschrift für Psychologie 200: 199–223Google Scholar
Kreps, David M. (1990). Game Theory and Economic Modelling. Oxford and New York, Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krüger, Hans-Peter (1999). ‘Verzicht auf Sanktionsnormen im Straaenverkehrsrecht-ein Beitrag zur Effektivität von Verhaltensnormen?’ Wirkungsforschung zum Recht I. Wirkungen und Erfolgsbedingungen von Gesetzen, ed. Hof, Hagen and Lübbe-Wolff, Gertrude. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 223–34Google Scholar
Kühberger, Anton (2000). ‘What about Motivation?Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 685CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S. (1962). The Structure of Scientific Revolutions. [Chicago], University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Kulms, Rainer (2000). Schuldrechtliche Organisationsverträge in der Unternehmenskooperation. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Kunda, Ziva and Nisbett, Richard E. (1988). ‘Predicting Individual Evaluations from Group Evaluations and Vice Versa. Different Patterns for Self and Other?Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 14: 326–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunig, Philip (1986). Das Rechtsstaatsprinzip. Überlegungen zu seiner Bedeutung für das Verfassungsrecht der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Lachmann, Ludwig M. (1963). ‘Wirtschaftsordnung und wirtschaftliche Institutionen.’ Jahrbuch für die Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft 14: 63–77Google Scholar
Laffont, Jean-Jacques (1999). ‘Political Economy, Information and Incentives.’ European Economic Review 43: 649–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lahno, Bernd (2002). Der Begriff des Vertrauens. Paderborn, MentisGoogle Scholar
Laibson, David (1997). ‘Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 443–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laird, John E., Newell, Allen and Rosenbloom, Paul (1991). ‘Soar: an Architecture for General Intelligence.’ Artificial Intelligence 47: 289–325Google Scholar
Langer, Ellen J. (1975). ‘The Illusion of Control.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 32: 311–28CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langevoort, Donald C. (2000). ‘Organized Illusions. A Behavioral Theory of Why Corporations Mislead Stock Market Investors (and Cause Other Social Harms).’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 144–67CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langlois, Richard N. (1986). ‘Rationality, Institutions, and Explanation.’ Economics as a Process. Essays in the New Institutional Economics, ed. Langlois, Richard N.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 225–55Google Scholar
LaPiere, Richard T. (1934). ‘Attitudes vs. Actions.’ Social Forces 13: 230–7CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, Anton E. (2002). ‘The Origin of Conditional Logic. Does a Cheater Detection Module Exist?Journal of Genetic Psychology 163: 425–44CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ledyard, John O. (1995). ‘Public Goods. A Survey of Experimental Research.’ The Handbook of Experimental Economics, ed. Kagel, J. H. and Roth, A. E.. Princeton, Princeton University Press: 111–94Google Scholar
Lehmann, Jill Fain, John E. Lairdand Paul Rosenbloom (1998). ‘A Gentle Introduction to Soar: an Architecture for Human Cognition.’ Methods, Models, and Conceptual Issues, Vol. IV. An Invitation to Cognitive Science, ed. Scarborough, Don and Stemberg, Saul: 211–53Google Scholar
León, Immaculada and Hernández, Juan A. (1998). ‘Testing the Role of Attribution and Appraisal in Predicting Own and Other's Emotions.’ Cognition and Emotion 12: 27–43CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, Jennifer S. and Tetlock, Philip E. (1999). ‘Accounting for the Effects of Accountability.’ Psychological Bulletin 125: 255–75CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lessig, Lawrence (1999). Code and other Laws of Cyberspace. New York, Basic BooksGoogle Scholar
Lessig, Lawrence and Resnick, Paul (1999). ‘Zoning Speech on the Internet. A Legal and Technical Model.’ Michigan Law Review 98: 395–431CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levinson, Stephen C. (1995). ‘Interactional Biases in Human Thinking.’ Social Intelligence and Interaction, ed. Goody, Esther. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 221–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Liebrand, Wim B. and , Charles G.McClintock, (1988). ‘The Ring Measure of Social Values. A Computerized Procedure for Assessing Individual Differences in Information Processing and Social Value Orientation.’ European Journal of Personality 2: 217–30CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lind, E. Allan and Tyler, Tom R. (1988). The Social Psychology of Procedural Justice. New York, Plenum PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Linton, Ralph (1945). The Cultural Background of Personality. New York, London, D. Appleton-CenturyGoogle Scholar
List, Christian and Goodin, Robert E. (2001). ‘Epistemic Democracy. Generalizing the Condorcet Jury Theorem.’ Journal of Political Philosophy 9: 277–306CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, John A. (2000). ‘The Effect of Market Experience on the WTA/WTP Disparity. Evidence from a Field Experiment with Sports Memorabilia.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id230007
Loewenstein, George and Daniel Adler (2000). ‘A Bias in the Prediction of Tastes.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 726–34Google Scholar
Loewenstein, George F. and Drazen Prelec (1992). ‘Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice. Evidence and an Interpretation.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 107: 573–98CrossRef
Loewenstein, George and Prelec, Drazen(2000). ‘Preferences for Sequences of Outcomes.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 565–77Google Scholar
Loewenstein, George and Richard H. Thaler (1997). ‘Intertemporal Choice.’ Research on Judgement and Decisionmaking, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 365–78Google Scholar
Loewenstein, George, Weber, Elke U., Hsee, Christopher and Welch, Ned (2001). ‘Risk as Feelings.’ Psychological Bulletin 127: 267–86CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lübbe, Weyma (2002). ‘Epistemische Pflichten in der “Wissensgesellschaft”.’ Wissen, Nichtwissen, Unsicheres Wissen, ed. Engel, Christoph, Halfmann, Jost and Schulte, Martin. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 145–60Google Scholar
Lüdemann, Jörn (2004). Edukatorisches Staatshandeln. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Luhmann, Niklas (1986). Ökologische Kommunikation. Kann die moderne Gesellschaft sich auf ökologische Gefährdungen einstellen?Opladen, Westdeutscher VerlagGoogle Scholar
McAdams, Richard H. (2000). ‘A Focal Point Theory of Expressive Law.’ Virginia Law Review 86: 1649–729CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCaffery, Edward, Daniel Kahneman and Matthew L. Spitzer (2000). ‘Framing the Jury. Cognitive Perspective on Pain and Suffering Awards.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 259–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McEvily, Bill, Roberto Weber, Cristiná Bicchieri and Violet Ho (2002). ‘Can Groups be Trusted? An Experimental Study of Collective Trust.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=323223CrossRef
McGarity, Thomas O. (1998). ‘A Cost-Benefit State.’ Administrative Law Review 50: 7–79Google Scholar
Machina, Mark J. (1987). ‘Choice under Uncertainty. Problems Solved and Unsolved.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 1: 121–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKenzie Alexander, Jason (2003). ‘Evolutionary Game Theory.’ The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, ed. Zalta, Edward E.. Stanford, Stanford UniversityGoogle Scholar
MacNeil, Ian R. (1971). Contracts: Exchange Transactions and Relationships. Mineola, Foundation PressGoogle Scholar
MacNeil, Ian R.(1982). ‘Efficient Breach of Contract: Circles in the Sky.’ Virginia Law Review 68: 947–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mair, Peter (1996). ‘Comparative Politics. An Overview.’ A New Handbook of Political Science, ed. Goodin, Robert E. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. Oxford, Oxford University Press: 309–35Google Scholar
Mantzavinos, Chrysostomos (2001). Individuals, Institutions, and Markets. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
March, James G. and Olsen, Johan P. (1989). Rediscovering Institutions. The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York, Free PressGoogle Scholar
Markovits, Richard S. (1996). ‘Monopoly and the Allocative Inefficiency of First-Best-Allocatively-Efficient Tort Law in our Worse-Than-Second-Best World. The Whys and some Therefores.’ Case Western Reserve Law Review 46: 313–448Google Scholar
Martignon, Laura and Kathryn Blackmond Laskey (1999). ‘Bayesian Benchmarks for Fast and Frugal Heuristics.’ Simple Heuristics that Make Us Smart, ed. Gigerenzer, Gerd and Todd, Peter M.. New York, Oxford University Press: 169–90Google Scholar
Maslow, Abraham H. (1954). Motivation and Personality. New York, HarperGoogle Scholar
Maunz, Theodor and Dürig, Günter, eds. (1958). Grundgesetz: Kommentar. Munich, BeckGoogle Scholar
May, Judith V. and Wildavsky, Aaron B. (1978). The Policy Cycle. Beverly Hills, SageGoogle Scholar
Maynard, Smith, John, (1982). Evolution and the Theory of Games. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Mayntz, Renate (1980). Implementation politischer Programme. Empirische Forschungsberichte. Königstein/Ts., AthenäumGoogle Scholar
Mayntz, Renate(1983). ‘Implementation von regulativer Politik.’ Implementation politischer Programme II, ed. Mayntz, Renate. Opladen, Westdeutscher Verlag: 50–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meade, James (1970). ‘The Theory of Indicative Planning.’ The Collected Papers of James Meade, Vol. II. Value, Distribution and Growth, ed. Meade, James. Winchester, Unwin Hyman: 109–57Google Scholar
Meadow, William and Sunstein, Cass R. (2001). ‘Statistics, not Experts.’ Duke Law Journal 51: 629–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meehl, Paul E. (1954). Clinical Versus Statistical Prediction. A Theoretical Analysis and a Review of the Evidence. Minneapolis, University of Minnesota PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Messick, David M. and Liebrand, Wim B. (1995). ‘Individual Heuristics and the Dynamics of Cooperation in Large Groups.’ Psychological Review 102: 131–45CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Messick, David M., Moore, Don A. and Bazerman, Max H. (1997). ‘Ultimatum Bargaining with a Group. Underestimating the Importance of the Decision Rule.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 69: 87–101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, David E. and Kieras, David E. (1997). ‘A Computational Theory of Executive Cognitive Processes and Multiple-Task Performance: I. Basic Mechanisms.’ Psychological Review 104: 3–65CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, John W. and Scott, W. Richard (1983). Organizational Environments. Ritual and Rationality. Beverly Hills, SageGoogle Scholar
Miller, Dale T. and Ross, Michael (1975). ‘Self-Serving Biases in the Attribution of Causality: Fact or Fiction?Psychological Bulletin 82: 213–25CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mischel, Walter and Peake, Philip K. (1982). ‘Beyond déjà vu in the Search for Cross-Situational Consistency.’ Psychological Review 89: 730–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mischel, Walter and Shoda, Yuichi (1995). ‘A Cognitive-Affective System Theory of Personality. Reconceptualizing Situations, Dispositions, Dynamics, and Invariance in Personality Structure.’ Psychological Review 102: 246–68CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mookherjee, Dilip (1990). ‘Rank Order Competition and Incentives. An Organizational Perspective.’ Economic Theory and Policy. Essays in Honour of Dipak Banerjee, ed. Dutta, Bhaskar. New Delhi, Oxford University Press: 194–229Google Scholar
Morgenstern, Oskar (1928). Wirtschaftsprognose. Eine Untersuchung ihrer Vorraussetzungen und Möglichkeiten. Vienna, SpringerGoogle Scholar
Morgenstern, Oskar(1935). ‘Vollkommene Voraussicht und wirtschaftliches Gleichgewicht.’ Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie 6: 337–57CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mui, Vai-Lam (1995). ‘The Economics of Envy.’ Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 26: 311–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mullainathan, Sendhil (2002). ‘A Memory-Based Model of Bounded Rationality.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 735–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murdock, Kevin C. (2002). ‘Intrinsic Motivation and Optimal Incentive Contracts.’ Rand Journal of Economics 33: 650–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mussweiler, Thomas, Strack, Fritz and Tim, Pfeiffer (2000). ‘Overcoming the Inevitable Anchoring Effect. Considering the Opposite Compensates for Selective Accessibility.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 26: 1142–50CrossRefGoogle Scholar
National Research Council (2002). Global Networks and Local Values. Washington, D.C, National Academy of Sciences
Nee, Victor (1998). ‘Sources of the New Institutionalism.’ The New Institutionalism in Sociology, ed. Brinton, Mary C. and Nee, Victor. New York, Russell Sage Foundation: 1–16Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. (1995). ‘Recent Evolutionary Theorizing about Economic Change.’ Journal of Economic Literature 33: 48–90Google Scholar
Nelson, Richard R. and Winter, Sidney G. (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Neumann, Franz Leopold (1942). Behemoth. The Structure and Practice of National Socialism. New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Newcomb, Theodore Mead (1929). The Consistency of Certain Extrovert-Introvert Behavior Patterns in 51 Problem Boys. New York, Teachers College Columbia UniversityGoogle Scholar
Newell, Allen (1990). Unified Theories of Cognition. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Newell, Allen and Simon, Herbert Alexander (1972). Human Problem Solving. Englewood Cliffs, N. J., Prentice-HallGoogle Scholar
Newstead, Stephen E. (2000). ‘Are There Two Different Types of Thinking?Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 690–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nisbett, Richard E. and Ross, Lee (1980). Human Inference. Strategies and Shortcomings of Social Judgment. Englewood Cliffs, N. J., Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Noll, Roger and James E. Krier (2000). ‘Some Implications of Cognitive Psychology for Risk Regulation.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 325–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass Cecil (1981). Structure and Change in Economic History. New York, NortonGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass Cecil(1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nyborg, Karine and Mari Rege (2001). ‘Does Public Policy Crowd out Private Contributions to Public Goods?’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=292802CrossRef
Ockenfels, Axel (2003). ‘Reputationsmechanismen auf Internet-Marktplattformen. Theorie und Empirie.’ Zeitschrift für Betriebswirtschaft 73: 295–315Google Scholar
Ofek, Elie, Muhamet Yildiz and Ernan Haruvy (2002). ‘Sequential Decision Making: How Prior Choices Affect Subsequent Valuations.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=353421CrossRef
Ostrom, Elinor (1990). Governing the Commons. The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor(1998). ‘A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action.’ American Political Science Review 92: 1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Parsons, Talcott (1951). The Social System. Glencoe, Ill., Free PressGoogle Scholar
Pashler, Harold E. (1998). The Psychology of Attention. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Pavlov, Ivan Petrovich and Anrep, Gleb Vasilievich (1927). Conditioned Reflexes. An Investigation of the Physiological Activity of the Cerebral Cortex. London, Oxford University Press and Humphrey MilfordGoogle Scholar
Payne, John W., Bettman, James R. et al. (1988). ‘Adaptive Strategy Selection in Decision Making.’ Journal of Experimental Psychology 14: 534–52Google Scholar
Payne, John W., Bettman, James R.Johnson, Eric J.(1992). ‘Behavioral Decision Research. A Constructive Processing Perspective.’ Annual Review of Psychology 43: 87–131CrossRefGoogle Scholar
(1997). ‘The Adaptive Decision Maker. Effort and Accuracy in Choice.’ Research on Judgement and Decision Making. Currents, Connections, and Controversies, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 181–204Google Scholar
Pennington, Nancy and Hastie, Reid (1993). ‘Reasoning in Explanation-Based Decision-Making.’ Cognition 49: 123–63CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pennington, Nancy and Hastie, Reid(1997). ‘Explanation-Based Decision Making. Effects of Memory Structure on Judgement.’ Research in Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 454–81Google Scholar
Perritt, Henry H. (2000). ‘Dispute Resolution in Cyberspace. Demand for New Forms of ADR.’ Ohio State Journal on Dispute Resolution 15: 675–703Google Scholar
Guy, Peters B. (1999). Institutional Theory in Political Science. The New Institutionalism. London, PinterGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A. C. (1932). The Economics of Welfare. London, MacmillanCrossRef
Pitschas, Rainer (1996). ‘Recht der Freien Berufe.’ Öffentliches Wirtschaftsrecht Besonderer Teil 2, ed. Schmidt, Reiner. Berlin, Springer: 1–126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plessner, Helmuth (1928). Die Stufen des Organischen und der Mensch. Einleitung in die Philosophische Anthropologie. Berlin and Leipzig, W. de GruyterGoogle Scholar
Plott, Charles R. (1986). ‘Rational Choice in Experimental Markets.’ Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology, ed. Hogarth, Robin M. and Reder, Melvin W.. Chicago, University of Chicago Press: 117–44Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. (2000). Law and Social Norms. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A. (2000). ‘Cost–Benefit Analysis. Definition, Justification, and Comment on Conference-Papers.’ Journal of Legal Studies 29: 1153–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A.(2003). Economic Analysis of Law. New York, AspenGoogle Scholar
Poundstone, William (1992). Prisoner's Dilemma. New York, DoubledayGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, Canice (1999). ‘The Provision of Incentives in Firms.’ Journal of Economic Literature 37: 7–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Presson, Paul K. and Benassi, Victor A. (1996). ‘Illusion of Control. A Meta-Analytic Review.’ Journal of Social Behavior and Personality 11: 493–510Google Scholar
Price, Michael E., Cosmides, Leda and Tooby, John (2002). ‘Punitive Sentiment as an Anti-Free Rider Psychological Device.’ Evolution and Human Behavior 23: 203–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Priest, George L. (1981). ‘A Theory of the Consumer Product Warranty.’ Yale Law Journal 90: 1297–352CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quattrone, George A. and Amos Tversky (2000). ‘Contrasting Rational and Psychological Analysis of Political Choice.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 451–72Google Scholar
Quillen, Gwyn D. (1988). ‘Contract Damages and Cross-Subsidization.’ Southern California Law Review 61: 1125–41Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew (1998). ‘Psychology and Economics.’ Journal of Economic Literature 36: 11–46Google Scholar
Rabin, Matthew(2002). ‘A Perspective on Psychology and Economics.’ European Economic Review 46: 657–85CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rachlin, Howard (2001). ‘Behavioural Analysis, Cognitive Analysis, and Economics.’ Behavioral and Experimental Economics Nobel Symposium, 4–6 December 2001, at http://www.iies.su.se/nobel/papers/stockholm text3.pdf
Rachlinski, Jeffrey J. (2000). ‘A Positive Psychological Theory of Judging in Hindsight.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 95–115CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rachlinski, Jeffrey J.(2003). ‘The Uncertain Psychological Case for Paternalism.’ Northwestern University Law Review 97: 1165–225Google Scholar
Rapoport, Anatol and Chammah, Albert M. (1965). Prisoner's Dilemma. A Study in Conflict and Cooperation. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rasmusen, Eric (1989). Games and Information. An Introduction to Game Theory. Oxford and New York, Basil BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Rawls, John (1999). A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, Mass., Belknap Press of Harvard Univeristy PressGoogle Scholar
Redelmeier, Donald A. and Tversky, Amos (1992). ‘On the Framing of Multiple Prospects.’ Psychological Science 3: 191–3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ripperger, Tanja (1998). Ökonomik des Vertrauens. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Risse, Thomas (2000). ‘“Let's Argue!”. Communicative Action in World Politics.’ International Organization 54: 1–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ritov, Ilana and Jonathan Baron (2000). ‘Reluctance to Vaccinate. Omission Bias and Ambiguity.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 168–86CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, Brent W. and Donahue, Eileen M. (1994). ‘One Personality, Multiple Selves. Integrating Personality and Social Roles.’ Journal of Personality 62: 199–218CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rohe, Mathias (1998). Netzverträge. Rechtsprobleme komplexer Vertragsbindungen. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Ronis, D. L., J. F. Yates and J. P. Kirscht (1989). ‘Attitudes, Decisions, and Habits as Determinants of Repeated Behavior.’ Attitude Structure and Function, ed. Pratkanis, A. R., Breckler, S. J. and Greenwald, A. G.. Hillsdale, Erlbaum: 213–39Google Scholar
Rosa, Jose Antonio, Porac, Joseph F., Runser-Spanjol, Jelena and Saxan, Michael S. (1999). ‘Sociocognitive Dynamics in a Product Market.’ Journal of Marketing 63: 64–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Lee and Nisbett, Richard E. (1991). The Person and the Situation. Perspectives of Social Psychology. New York, McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Ross, Lee, Greene, David and House, Pamela (1977a). ‘The False Consensus Effect: an Egocentric Bias in Social Perception and Attribution Processes.’ Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 13: 279–301CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Lee, Lepper, Mark R., Strack, Fritz and Steinmetz, Julia (1977b). ‘Social Explanation and Social Expectation. Effects of Real and Hypothetical Explanations on Subjective Likelihood.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 35: 817–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rostain, Tanina (2000). ‘Educating Homo Economicus. Cautionary Notes on the New Behavioral Law and Economics Movement.’ Law and Society Review 34: 973–1006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rousseau, Jean-Jacques (1763). Du contrat social; ou, Principes du droit politique. n.p
Rutherford, Malcolm (1994). Institutions in Economics. The Old and the New Institutionalism. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandler, Todd (2001). Economic Concepts for the Social Sciences. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sanna, Lawrence J. and Schwarz, Norbert (2003). ‘Debiasing the Hindsight Bias. The Role of Accessibility Experiences and (Mis)attributions.’ Journal of Experimental Social Psychology 39 (3): 287–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sansone, Carol and Harackiewicz, Judith M. (2000). Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation. The Search for Optimal Motivation and Performance. San Diego, Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Satz, Debra and Ferejohn, John A. (1994). ‘Rational Choice and Social Theory.’ The Journal of Philosophy 91: 71–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, Leonard J. (1954). The Foundations of Statistics. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, Fritz Wilhelm (1997). Games Real Actors Play. Actor-Centered Institutionalism in Policy Research. Boulder, Colo., Westview PressGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, Fritz Wilhelm(1998). ‘Die Problemlösungsfähigkeit der Mehrebenenpolitik in Europa.’ Politische Viertelsjahresschrift 39: 121–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scharpf, Fritz Wilhelm(1999). Governing in Europe. Effective and Democratic?Oxford and New York, Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheler, Max (1928). Die Stellung des Menschen im Kosmos. Darmstadt, ReichlGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. (1960). The Strategy of Conflict. Cambridge, Mass.,Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C.(1984). ‘Self-Command in Practice, in Policy, and in a Theory of Rational Choice.’ American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 74: 1–11Google Scholar
Schimank, Uwe (1992). ‘Erwartungssicherheit und Zielverfolgung. Sozialität zwischen Prisoners' Dilemma und Battle of the Sexes.’ Soziale Welt 43: 182–200Google Scholar
Schlicht, Ekkehart (1998). On Custom in the Economy. Oxford, Clarendon PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmeidler, David (1989). ‘Subjective Probability and Expected Utility without Additivity.’ Econometrica 57: 571–87CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schöch, Heinz (1999). ‘Verzicht auf Sanktionsnormen im Straβenverkehrsrecht – ein Beitrag zur Effektivität von Verhaltensnormen?’ Wirkungsforschung zum Recht I. Wirkungen und Erfolgsbedingungen von Gesetzen, ed. Hof, Hagen and Lübbe-Wolff, Gertrude. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 235–44Google Scholar
Schulte, Martin (2002). ‘Zum Umgang mit Wissen, Nichtwissen and Unsicherem Wissen im Recht – dargestellt am Beispiel des BSE- and MKS-Konflikts.’ Wissen, Nichtwissen, Unsicheres Wissen, ed. Engel, Christoph, Halfmann, Jost and Schulte, Martin. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 351–70Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph Alois (1912). Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Leipzig, Duncker & HumblotGoogle Scholar
Schweizer, Urs (1999). Vertragstheorie. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Sedikides, Constantine, Schopler, John and Insko, Chester A. (1998). Intergroup Cognition and Intergroup Behavior. Mahwah, N. J., Lawrence ErlbaumGoogle Scholar
Selten, Reinhard (1978). ‘The Chain Store Paradox.’ Theory and Decision 9: 127–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Selten, Reinhard(1998). ‘Features of Experimentally Observed Bounded Rationality.’ European Economic Review 42: 413–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shackle, George L. (1992). ‘Risk, Uncertainty and Imagination.’ The Theory of Choice. A Critical Guide, ed. Shaun, H. Heap, Hollis, Martin, Lyons, Bruce, Sudgen, Robert and Wale, Albert. Oxford, Blackwell: 51–61Google Scholar
Shafir, Eldar, Itamar Simonson and Amos Tversky (2000). ‘Reason-Based Choice.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 597–619Google Scholar
Shavitt, Sharon and Fazio, Russell H. (1991). ‘Effects of Attribute Salience on the Consistency between Attitudes and Behaviour Predictions.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 17: 506–17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sheposh, J. P. and Gallo, P. S. (1973). ‘Asymmetry of Payoff Structure and Cooperative Behaviour in the Prisoner's Dilemma Game.’ Journal of Conflict Resolution 17: 321–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sherrington, Charles Scott (1906). The Integrative Action of the Nervous System. New York, C. Scribner's SonsGoogle Scholar
Shoda, Yuichi (1999). ‘A Unified Framework for the Study of Behavioral Consistency. Briding Person x Situation Interaction and the Consistency Paradox.’ European Journal of Personality 13: 361–873.0.CO;2-X>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shoemaker, Paul J. (1982). ‘The Expected Utility Model. Its Variants, Purposes, Evidence and Limitations.’ Journal of Economic Literature 20: 529–63Google Scholar
Siebert, Horst (1996). ‘Institutionelle Arrangements für die Zuweisung von Opportunitätskosten.’ Festschrift für Ernst-Joachim Mestmäcker, ed. Immenga, Ulrich, Möschel, Wernhard and Reuter, Dieter. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 309–20Google Scholar
Sil, Rudra (2000). ‘The Division of Labor in Social Science Research. Unified Methodology or “Organic Solidarity”?’ Polity 32: 499–531CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander (1957). Models of Man: Social and Rational. Mathematical Essays on Rational Human Behavior in a Society Setting. New York, WileyGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1962). ‘The Architecture of Complexity.’ Proceedings of the American Philosophical Society 106: 467–82Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1976). Administrative Behavior. A Study of Decision-Making Processes in Administrative Organization. New York, Free PressGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1987). ‘Rational Decision Making in Business Organisations.’ Advances in Behavioural Economics 1, ed. Green, Leonard and Kagel, John H.. Norwood, Ablex: 18–47Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1990). ‘Invariants of Human Behavior.’ Annual Review of Psychology 41: 1–19CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1991). ‘Cognitive Architectures and Rational Analysis. Comment.’ Architectures for Intelligence, ed. VanLehn, Kurt. Hillsdale, Erlbaum: 25–39Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert Alexander(1993). ‘Altruism and Economics.’ American Economic Review 83: 156– 61Google Scholar
Simon, Jürgen and Braun, Susanne (2002). ‘Legal Aspects of Genetic Data Banking in Germany.’ Eubios Journal of Asian and International Bioethics 12: 171–6Google Scholar
Simonson, Itamar (2000). ‘The Effect of Purchasing Quantity and Timing on Variety-Seeking Behavior.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 735–57Google Scholar
Singer, O. (1993). ‘Policy Communities und Diskurs-Koalitionen. Experten und Expertise in der Wirtschaftspolitik.’ Policy Analyse. Kritik und Neuorientierung, ed. Héritier, Adrienne. Opladen, Westdeutscher Verlag: 149–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slembeck, Tilman and Jean-Robert Tyran (2002). ‘Do Institutions Promote Rationality? An Experimental Study of the Three-Door Anomaly.’ http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=345721CrossRef
Slovic, Paul (1995). ‘The Construction of Preference.’ American Psychologist 50: 364–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slovic, Paul and Fischhoff, Baruch (1977). ‘On the Psychology of Experimental Surprises.’ Journal of Experimental Psychology 3: 544–51Google Scholar
Smend, Rudolf (1968). ‘Verfassung und Verfassungsrecht.’ Staatsrechtliche Abhandlungen und andere Aufsätze, ed. Smend, Rudolf. Berlin, Duncker & Humblot: 119–276Google Scholar
Smith, Adam (1790). The Theory of Moral Sentiments, or, An Essay Towards an Analysis of the Principles by which Men Naturally Judge Concerning the Conduct and Character, First of Their Neighbours, and Afterwards of Themselves. To which is Added, a Dissertation on the Origin of Languages. London, StrahanGoogle Scholar
Smith, Eliot R. and Coster, Jamie (2000). ‘Dual-Process Models in Social and Cognitive Psychology: Conceptual Integration and Links to Underlying Memory Systems.’ Personality and Social Psychology Review 4: 108–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Trenton G. (2003). ‘Obesity and Nature's Thumbprint. How Institutions Make Behaviour Predictable. How Modern Waistlines can Inform Economic Theory.’ University of California at Santa Barbara, Working Paper in Economics 18-02, 23 August 2003
Smith, Vernon L. (1989). ‘Theory, Experiment and Economics.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives: 3 (1): 151–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L.(1991). ‘Rational Choice. The Contrast between Economics and Psychology.’ Journal of Political Economy 99: 877–97CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L.(1994). ‘Economics in the Laboratory.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 8: 112–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L. and Walker, James M. (1993). ‘Monetary Rewards and Decision Cost in Experimental Economics.’ Economic Inquiry 31: 245–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Vernon L., Suchanek, Gerry L. and Arlington, W. Williams (1988). ‘Bubbles, Crashes, and Endogenous Expectations in Experimental Spot Asset Markets.’ Econometrica 56: 1119–51CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Snyder, Mark and Swann, William B. (1976). ‘When Actions Reflect Attitudes. The Politics of Impression Management.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 34: 1034–42CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sobota, Katharina (1997). Das Prinzip Rechtsstaat. Verfassungs- und verwaltungsrechtliche Aspekte. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Spiecker gen. Döhmann, Indra (2001). ‘Staatliche Entscheidungen unter Unsicherheit. Juristische und ökonomische Vorgaben.’ Gentechnik im nicht–menschlichen Bereich – was kann und was sollte das Recht regeln?, ed. Lege, Joachim. Berlin, Arno Spitz: 51–88Google Scholar
Stanovich, Keith E. and West, Richard F. (2000). ‘Individual Differences in Reasoning. Implications for the Rationality Debate?Behavioral and Brain Sciences 23: 645–65CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Stark, Oded (1995). Altruism and Beyond. An Economic Analysis of Transfers and Exchanges within Families and Groups. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steinmo, Sven, Thelen, Kathleen Ann and Frank, Longstreth (1992). Structuring Politics. Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Analysis. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephens, David W. and Krebs, J. R. (1986). Foraging Theory. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2000). ‘Formal and Informal Institutions.’ Social Capital. A Multifaceted Perspective, ed. Dasgupta, Partha and Serageldin, Ismail. Washington, D.C., World Bank: 59–68Google Scholar
Strack, Fritz and Roland Deutsch (2002). ‘Reflective and Impulsive Determinants of Social Behaviour’ (mimeo)
Strack, Fritz and Deutsch, Roland(forthcoming). ‘Urteilsheuristiken.’ Theorien der Sozialpsychologie – Motivations- und Informationsverarbeitungstheorien, ed. Frey, Dieter and Irle, Martin
Strack, Fritz and Mussweiler, Thomas (1997). ‘Explaining the Enigmatic Anchoring Effect. Mechanisms of Selective Accessibility.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 73: 437–46CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ströbele, Wolfgang (1987). Rohstoffökonomik Theorie natürlicher Ressourcen mit Anwendungsbeispielen Öl, Kupfer, Uran und Fischerei. Munich, VahlenGoogle Scholar
Stults, Daniel M. and Messe, Lawrence A. (1985). ‘Behavioral Consistency: the Impact of Public Versus Private Statements of Intentions.’ Journal of Social Psychology 125: 277–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. (1996). ‘Legislative Foreword. Congress, Constitutional Moments, and the Cost-Benefit State.’ Stanford Law Review 48: 247–309CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(1998). ‘How Law Constructs Preferences.’ Georgetown Law Journal 86: 2637–52Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.,ed. (2000a). Behavioral Law and Economics. Cambridge Series on Judgment and Decision Making. Cambridge, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(2000b). ‘Cost–Benefit Default Principles.’ Chicago, John M. Olin Law & Economics Working Paper 104. http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=247884
Sunstein, Cass R.(2000c). ‘Introduction.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 1–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(2001). ‘Cost–Benefit Default Principles.’ Michigan Law Review 99: 1651–723CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R.(2002). ‘The Law of Group Polarization.’ Journal of Political Philosophy 10: 175–95CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. and Edna Ullmann-Margalit (2000). ‘Second-Order Decisions.’ Behavioral Law and Economics, ed. Sunstein, Cass R.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 187–208CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svenson, Ola (1981). ‘Are We All Less Risky and More Skilful than Our Fellow Drivers?Acta Psychologica 47: 143–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sweet, Alec Stone (1999). ‘Judicialization and the Construction of Governance.’ Comparative Political Studies 32: 147–84CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Symposium, (2000). ‘Cost–Benefit Analysis. Legal, Economic, and Philosophical Perspectives.’ Journal of Legal Studies 29: 837–1177Google Scholar
Tack, Werner H. (2003). ‘Kooperative Rationalität in sozialen Situationen.’ Grenzen rationaler Orientierung, ed. Astroh, Michael. Hildesheim, Olms: 103–35Google Scholar
Takacs, Karoly (2001). ‘Structural Embeddedness and Intergroup Conflict.’ Journal of Conflict Resolution 45: 743–69CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tedeschi, James T. (1981). Impression Management Theory and Social Psychological Research. New York, Academic PressGoogle Scholar
Tetlock, Philip E. (1985). ‘Accountability. The Neglected Social Context of Judgement and Choice.’ Research in Organizational Behaviour 7: 297–332Google Scholar
Tetlock, Philip E.(1999). ‘Accountability Theory. Mixing Properties of Human Agents with Properties of Social Systems.’ Shared Cognition in Organizations. The Management of Knowledge, ed. Thompson, Leigh L., Levine, John M. and Messick, David M.. Mahwah, N. J., Lawrence Erlbaum: 117–37Google Scholar
Tetlock, Philip E., Skitka, Linda and Boettger, Richard (1989). ‘Social and Cognitive Strategies for Coping with Accountability. Conformity, Complexity, and Bolstering.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 57: 632–40CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Teubner, Gunther and Vaios Karavas (2003). ‘http://www.CompanyNameSucks.com: Drittwirkung der Grundrechte gegenüber “Privaten” im autonomen Recht des Internet.’ Innovationsoffene Regulierung des Internet, ed. Ladeur., Karl-Heinz, Baden-Baden, Nomos: 249–72Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. (1999). ‘Mental Accounting Matters.’ Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 12: 183–2063.0.CO;2-F>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, Richard H.(2000). ‘Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 269–87Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard H. and Shefrin, H. M. (1981). ‘An Economic Theory of Self-Control.’ Journal of Political Economy 89: 392–406CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Theissen, Eric (2002). ‘Floor versus Screen Trading. Evidence from the German Stock Market.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 158: 32–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thompson, Leigh L.,Levine, John M. and Messick, David M. (1999). Shared Cognition in Organizations. The Management of Knowledge. Mahwah, N. J., Lawrence ErlbaumGoogle Scholar
Thompson, M.,Ellis, Richard and Wildavsky, Aaron B. (1990). Cultural Theory. Boulder, Colo., Westview PressGoogle Scholar
Thorburn, W. M. (1915). ‘Occam's Razor.’ Mind 24: 287–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tietenberg, Thomas H. (1982). ‘Transferable Discharge Permits and the Control of Air Pollution – a Survey and Synthesis.’ Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht 3: 477–508Google Scholar
Tietenberg, Thomas H.(1998). Environmental Economics and Policy. Reading, Mass., Addison-WesleyGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean (1986). ‘Hierarchies and Bureaucracies: On the Role of Collusion in Organizations.’ Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 2: 181–214Google Scholar
Tirole, Jean(1988). The Theory of Industrial Organization. Cambridge, Mass., MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Tirole, Jean(2002). ‘Rational Irrationality. Some Economics of Self-Management.’ European Economic Review 46: 633–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Turner, Mark (2001). Cognitive Dimensions of Social Science. New York, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Dale W. Griffin (2000). ‘Endowments and Contrasts in Judgements of Well-Being.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 709–25Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel (1973). ‘Availability. A Heuristic for Judging Frequency and Probability.’ Cognitive Psychology 5: 207–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel(1974). ‘Judgement under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases.’ Science 185: 1124–31CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel(1991). ‘Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice. A Reference-Dependent Model.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 1039–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Kahneman, Daniel(2000). ‘Rational Choice and the Framing of Decisions.’ Choices, Values and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 209–23Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos and Itamar Simonson (2000). ‘Context-Dependent Preferences.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 518–27Google Scholar
Tversky, Amos, Shmuel Sattath and Paul Slovic (2000). ‘Contingent Weighting in Judgement and Choice.’ Choices, Values, and Frames, ed. Kahneman, Daniel and Tversky, Amos. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 503–17Google Scholar
Tyler, Tom R. (1990). Why People Obey the Law. New Haven, Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Tyler, Tom R.(1997). ‘The Psychology of Legitimacy.’ Personality and Social Psychology Review 1: 323–44CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Underwood, Bill and Moore, Bert S. (1981). ‘Sources of Behavioral Consistency.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 40: 780–5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanberg, Victor (2002). ‘Rational Choice vs. Program-Based Behavior. Alternative Theoretical Approaches and their Relevance for the Study of Institutions.’ Rationality and Society 14: 7–54CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanberg, Victor and Buchanan, James M. (1989). ‘Interests and Theories in Constitutional Choice.’ Journal of Theoretical Politics 1: 49–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veer, Donald (1986). Paternalistic Intervention. The Moral Bounds of Benevolence. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein (1919). The Place of Science in Modern Civilisation and Other Essays. New York, B. W.HuebschGoogle Scholar
Verweij, Marco (2000). Transboundary Environmental Problems and Cultural Theory. The Protection of the Rhine and the Great Lakes. Houndmills, Basingstoke, and New York, PalgraveGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich-August (1967). Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics. London, RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar (1944). Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Savigny, Friedrich Karl (1814). Vom Beruf unsrer Zeit für Gesetzgebung und Rechtswissenschaft. Heidelberg, Mohr and ZimmerGoogle Scholar
Wade-Benzoni, Kimberly A., Tenbrunsel, Ann E. and Bazerman, Max H. (1996). ‘Egocentric Interpretations of Fairness in Asymmetric, Environmental Social Dilemmas. Explaining Harvesting Behavior and the Role of Communication.’ Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 67: 111–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagenaar, Willem A., Gideon Keren and Sarah Lichtenstein (1997). ‘Islanders and Hostages. Deep and Surface Structures of Decision Problems.’ Research on Judgement and Decision Making, ed. Goldstein, William M. and Hogarth, Robin M.. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press: 552–65Google Scholar
Walker, James M., Gardner, Roy, Herr, Andrew and Ostron, Elinor (2000). ‘Collective Choice in the Commons. Experimental Results on Proposed Allocation Rules and Votes.’ The Economic Journal 110: 212–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, Elke U. and Patrizia G. Lindemann (2002). ‘Decision Modes or Choosing How to Choose. Making Decisions with Our Head, Our Heart, or by the Book’ (mimeo)
Weber, Elke U., William M. Goldstein and S. Barlas (1995). ‘And Let Us not Forget Memory. The Role of Memory Processes and Techniques in the Study of Judgement and Choice.’ The Psychology of Learning and Motivation, 32. Decision Making from a Cognitive Perspective, ed. Busemeyer, J. R., Hastie, Reid and Medin, D. L.. San Diego, Academic Press: 33–81Google Scholar
Weber, Max (1976). Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Grundriss der verstehenden Soziologie. Tübingen, MohrGoogle Scholar
Webster, Hutton and H. Milford (1942). Taboo. A Sociological Study. Stanford, Stanford University Press; London, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Weck-Hannemann, Hannelore (1999). ‘Rationale Auβensteuerung menschlichen Verhaltens – Möglichkeiten und Grenzen.’ Rationale Umweltpolitik - Rationales Umweltrecht. Konzepte, Kriterien und Grenzen rationaler Steuerung im Umweltschutz, ed. Gawel, Erik and Lübbe-Wolff, Gertrude. Baden-Baden, Nomos: 67–92Google Scholar
Wegner, Gerhard (1996). Wirtschaftspolitik zwischen Selbst- und Fremdsteuerung – ein neuer Ansatz. Baden-Baden, NomosGoogle Scholar
Weigend, A (1994). ‘On Overfitting and the Effective Number of Hidden Units.’ Proceedings of the 1993 Connectionist Models Summer School, ed. Mozer, Michael C.. Hillsdale, N. J., Lawrence Erlbaum: 335–42Google Scholar
Welch, Ivo (1992). ‘Sequential Sales, Learning, and Cascades.’ Journal of Finance 47: 695–732CrossRefGoogle Scholar
White, Harrison C. (1992). Identity and Control. A Structural Theory of Social Action. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
White, Harrison C.(1995). ‘Social Networks Can Resolve Actor Paradoxes in Economics and in Psychology.’ Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 151: 58–74Google Scholar
Wicker, Allan W. (1969). ‘Attitudes versus Actions. The Relationship of Verbal and Overt Behavioral Responses to Attitude Objects.’ Journal of Social Issues 25: 41–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiersma, Uco J. (1992). ‘The Effects of Extrinsic Rewards in Intrinsic Motivation. A Meta-Analysis.’ Journal of Occupational and Organizational Psychology 65: 101–14CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilder, David A. (1978). ‘Effect of Predictability on Units of Perception and Attribution.’ Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 4: 281–4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York, Free Press; London, Collier MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Timothy D., Houston, Christopher E., Etling, Kathryn M. and Brekke, Nancy (1996). ‘A New Look at Anchoring Effects. Basic Anchoring and its Antecedents.’ Journal of Experimental Psychology 125: 387–402CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilson, Timothy D., Lindsey, Samuel and Schooler, Tonya Y. (2000). ‘A Model of Dual Attitudes.’ Psychological Review 107: 101–26CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Windhoff-Héritier, Adrienne (1980). Politikimplementation. Ziel und Wirklichkeit politischer Entscheidungen. Königstein/Ts., HainGoogle Scholar
Winter, Gerd (1975). Das Vollzugsdefizit im Wasserrecht. Ein Beitrag zur Soziologie des Öffentlichen Rechts. Berlin, SchmidtGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ulrich (2000a). ‘Changing Cognitive Frames – Changing Organizational Forms: an Entrepreneurial Theory of Organizational Development.’ Industrial and Corporate Change 9: 733–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Witt, Ulrich(2000b). ‘Genetic Adaptation, Cultural Learning, and the Utilitarian Program in Economics.’ Paper prepared for the AEA Panel ‘Consilience: the Unity of Knowledge in the 21st Century’, Boston, 7 January 2000
Wright, Jack C. and Mischel, Walter (1987). ‘A Conditional Approach to Dispositional Constructs. The Local Predictability of Social Behavior.’ Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 53: 1159–77CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Yee, Albert S. (1996). ‘The Causal Effects of Ideas on Policies.’ International Organization 50: 66–108CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, H. Eyton (1994). Equity. In Theory and Practice. Princeton, Princeton University PressGoogle Scholar
Zhou Xueguang (1997). ‘Organizational Decision Making as Rule Following.’ Organizational Decision Making, ed. Shapira, Zur. New York, Cambridge University Press: 257–81Google Scholar
Zweigert, Konrad and Kötz, Hein (1998). Introduction to Comparative Law. Oxford, Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Christoph Engel
  • Book: Generating Predictability
  • Online publication: 22 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511490033.011
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Christoph Engel
  • Book: Generating Predictability
  • Online publication: 22 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511490033.011
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Christoph Engel
  • Book: Generating Predictability
  • Online publication: 22 September 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511490033.011
Available formats
×