Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pjpqr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-20T02:46:44.201Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 November 2009

Johann Graf Lambsdorff
Affiliation:
Universität Passau, Germany
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
The Institutional Economics of Corruption and Reform
Theory, Evidence and Policy
, pp. 256 - 281
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbink, K. (2004), “Staff Rotation as an Anti-corruption Policy: An Experimental Study,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 20 (4): 887–906.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., and Renner, E. (2000), “The Moonlighting Game,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 22: 265–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abed, G. T. and H. R. Davoodi (2002), “Corruption, Structural Reforms, and Economic Performance,” Governance, Corruption & Economic Performance, ed. by Abed, G. T. and Gupta, S., Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund 489–537.Google Scholar
Aburish, S. (1985), Pay-Off: Wheeling and Dealing in the Arab World (New York: Harper Collins Publishers).Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Verdier, T. (1998), “Property Rights, Corruption and the Allocation of Talent: A General Equilibrium Approach,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 108: 1381–1403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Verdier, T. (2000), “The Choice Between Market Failures and Corruption,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 90: 194–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1995), “Competition and Corruption,” Draft Paper, Oxford: Keble College, Oxford University.Google Scholar
Ades, A. and R. Di Tella (1996), “The Causes and Consequences of Corruption: A Review of Recent Empirical Contributions,” Liberalization and the New Corruption, ed. by White, B. Harris and White, G. (Brighton: Institute of Development Studies Bulletin, 27): 6–12.Google Scholar
Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1997), “National Champions and Corruption: Some Unpleasant Interventionist Arithmetic,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 107: 1023–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1999), “Rents, Competition, and Corruption,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 89: 982–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adsera, A., C. Boix, and M. Payne (2000), “Are You Being Served? Political Accountability and Quality of Government,” Inter-American Development Bank Research Department Working Paper 438, Washington, DC.
Aidt, Toke S. (2003), “Economic Analysis of Corruption: A Survey,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 113: 632–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aizenman, J. and M. Spiegel (2003), “Institutional Efficiency, Monitoring Costs, and the Investment Share of FDI,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2003–06.
Alam, S. M. (1990), “Some Economic Costs of Corruption in LDC's,” Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 27: 89–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A. and Weder, B. (1999), “Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid?,” NBER Working Paper 7108, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Alesina, A. and Weder, B. (2002), “Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid?,”American Economic Review, Vol. 92 (4): 1126–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., and Wacziarg, R. (2003), “Fractionalization,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 8: 155–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ali, A. M. and Isse, H. S. (2003), “Determinants of Economic Corruption: A Cross-Country Comparison,” Cato Journal, Vol. 22 (3): 445–66.Google Scholar
Al-Marhubi, F. A. (2000), “Corruption and Inflation,” Economics Letters, Vol. 66 (2): 199–202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, A. (1995), “Organized Crime, Mafia and Governments,” The Economics of Organized Crime, ed. by Fiorentini, G. and Peltzman, S. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press): 33–54.Google Scholar
Anderson, C. J. and Tverdova, Y. V. (2003), “Corruption, Political Allegiances, and Attitudes toward Government in Contemporary Democracies,” American Journal of Political Sciences, Vol. 47 (1): 91–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andvig, J. (1995), “Corruption in the North Sea Oil Industry: Issues and Assessments,” Crime, Law and Social Change, Vol. 23: 289–313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andvig, J. C. (1991), “The Economics of Corruption: A Survey,” Studi Economici, Vol. 43: 57–94.Google Scholar
Andvig, J. C. and O. H. Fjeldstadt (2000), “Research on Corruption. A Policy Oriented Survey,” Chr. Michelsen Institute and Norwegian Institute for International Affairs. Online version at: www.icgg.org/downloads/contribution07_andrig.pdf
Andvig, J. C. and Moene, K. (1990), “How Corruption May Corrupt,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 13: 63–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anoruo, E. and Braha, H. (2005), “Corruption and Economic Growth: The African Experience,” Journal of Sustainable Development in Africa, Vol. 7 (1).Google Scholar
Appelbaum, E. and Katz, E. (1987), “Seeking Rents by Setting Rents: The Political Economy of Rent Seeking,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 97: 685–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arikan, G. (2004), “Fiscal Decentralization: A Remedy for Corruption?,”International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 11: 175–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arlen, J. (1994), “The Potentially Perverse Effects of Corporate Criminal Liability,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 23: 833–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books).Google Scholar
Bannenberg, B. (2002), Korruption in Deutschland und ihre strafrechtliche Kontrolle: Eine kriminologisch-strafrechtliche Analyse (Neuwied/Kriftel, Germany: Luchterhand).Google Scholar
Bardhan, P. (1997), “Corruption and Development: A Review of Issues,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35: 1320–46.Google Scholar
Bartsch, E. and Thomas, I. (1993), “Spieltheoretische Ansätze in der Rent-Seeking Theorie: Ein Literaturüberblick,” Kieler Arbeitspapiere, Institut für Weltwirtschaft, Kiel, Germany, No. 564.Google Scholar
Bartsch, E. and Thomas, I. (1995), “Rent-Seeking, Umverteilung und soziale Kosten,” WiSt –wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium, Vol. 24: 174–9.Google Scholar
Bates, R. (1981), Markets and States in Tropical Africa (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press).Google Scholar
Bavarian Criminal Division (2005), unpublished conviction, 4th Criminal Division of the Munich District Court.
Bayley, D. H. (1966), “The Effects of Corruption in a Developing Nation,” The Western Political Quartely, Vol. 19 (4): 719–32. Reprinted in A. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston and V. LeVine (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers): 935–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, P. J. and Maher, M. (1986), “A Comparison of Bribery and Bidding in Thin Markets,” Economics Letters, Vol. 20: 1–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, P. J., Maher, M. W. and Tschoegl, A. E. (1991), “The Impact of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act on US Exports,” Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 12: 295–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1968), “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76: 169–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1994), “To Root Out Corruption, Boot Out Big Government,” Business Week, January 31: 18.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. and Stigler, G. J. (1974), “Law Enforcement, Malfeasance, and Compensation of Enforcers,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 3: 1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Porath, Y. (1980), “The F-Connection: Families, Friends, and Firms and the Organization of Exchange,” Population and Development Review, Vol. 6 (1): 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and McLaren, J. (1993), “Taxes and Bribery: The Role of Wage Incentives,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 103: 119–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and Prat, A. (2006), “Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability,” American Economic Review, Vol. 96(3): 720–736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, J. N. (1982), “Directly Unproductive, Profit Seeking (DUP) Activities,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90: 998–1002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, J. N. and Srinivasan, T. N. (1980), “Revenue Seeking: A Generalization of the Theory of tariffs,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 87: 1069–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, J. N., R. A. Brecher, and T. N. Srinivasan (1984), “DUP activities and Economic Theory,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 17–32.Google Scholar
Björnskov, C. and M. Paldam (2004), “Corruption Trends,” The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, ed. by Lambsdorff, J. Graf, Schramm, M. and Taube, M.(London: Routledge): 59–75.Google Scholar
Borner, S. and C. Schwyzer (1999), “Bekämpfung der Bestechung im Lichte der Neuen Politischen Ökonomie,” Korruption im internationalen Geschäftsverkehr, Bestandsaufnahme, Bekämpfung, Prävention, ed. by Pieth, M. and Eigen, P. (Basel, Frankfurt am Main: Luchterhand): 17–39.Google Scholar
Boycko, M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1995), Privatizing Russia (Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press).Google Scholar
Boyko, M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1996), “A Theory of Privatization,” Economic Journal, Vol. 106 (435): 309–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braun, M. and Di Tella, R. (2000), “Inflation and Corruption,” Harvard Business School, Division of Research Working Paper00–053.Google Scholar
Bray, J. (1999), “Beyond Compliance: Corruption as a Business Risk,” Conference on Fighting Corruption in Developing Countries and Emerging Countries: The Role of the Private Sector, Organisation for Economic Co-operation (OECD) Development Centre, Washington, DC, February.
Bray, J. (2004), “The Use of Intermediaries and other ‘Alternatives’ to Bribery,” The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, ed. by Lambsdorff, J. Graf, Schramm, M., and Taube, M. (London: Routledge): 112–37.Google Scholar
Bray, J. (2006), International Business Attitudes to Corruption-Survey 2006. Report (London: Control Risks Group). Online version at www.control-risks.com/pdf/corruption_survey_2006_v3.pdf
Breton, A. and Wintrobe, R. (1975), “The Equilibrium Size of a Budget-maximizing Bureau: A Note on Niskanen's Theory of Bureaucracy (in Communications),” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 83 (1): 195–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadman, H. G. and Recanatini, F. (1999), “Seeds of Corruption – Do Market Institutions Matter?,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2368, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Brock, W. A. and Magee, St. P. (1978), “The Economics of Special Interest Politics: The Case of the Tariff,” The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 68: 246–50.Google Scholar
Brock, W. A. and St. P. Magee (1984), “The Invisible Foot and the Waste of Nations,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 177–86.Google Scholar
Browning, E. K. (1974), “On the Welfare Costs of Transfers,” Kyklos, Vol. 27: 374–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunetti, A. and Weder, B. (1998), “Investment and Institutional Uncertainty: A Comparative Study of Different Uncertainty Measures,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 134: 513–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunetti, A. and Weder, B. (2003), “A Free Press is Bad News for Corruption,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 87 (7–8): 1801–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunetti, A., G. Kisunko, and B. Weder (1997), “Institutional Obstacles for Doing Business. Data Description and Methodology of a Worldwide Private Sector Survey,” Background Paper for the World Development Report 1997, Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Brunetti, A., Kisunko, G., and Weder, B. (1998), “Credibility of Rules and Economic Growth: Evidence from a World Wide Private Sector Survey,” The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 12 (3): 353–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunner, K. and Meckling, W. H. (1977), “The Perception of Man and the Conception of Government,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 9 (1): 70–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1980), “Rent-Seeking and Profit-Seeking,” Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, ed. by Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., and Tullock, G. (College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press): 3–15.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1993), “Public Choice after Socialism,” Public Choice, Vol. 72: 67–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Tullock, G. (1962), The Calculus of Consent. Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bundeskriminalamt (2004), “Lagebild Korruption Bundesrepublik Deutschland 2003,” August. Online version at www.bka.de/lageberichte/ko/blkorruption2003.pdf, retreived July, 2005
Button, K. J. and Weyman-Jones, T. G. (1994), “X-Efficiency and Technical Efficiency,” Public Choice, Vol. 80: 83–104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campos, J. E., Lien, D., and Pradhan, S. (1999), “The Impact of Corruption on Investment: Predictability Matters,” World Development, Vol. 27 (6): 1059–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cartier-Bresson, J. (1997), “The Economics of Corruption,” Democracy and Corruption in Europe, ed. by Porta, D. Della and Mény, Y. (London: Pinter): 148–65.Google Scholar
Center for the Study of Democracy (1998), “Relations between Citizens and Public Administration and Public Opinion on Corruption in Bulgaria,” Draft Paper, Sofia, Bulgaria.
Chang, E. and M. Golden (2004), “Electoral Systems, District Magnitude and Corruption,” mimeo, Departments of Political Science, Michigan State University and the University of California at Los Angeles, CA.
Choi, J. P. and Thum, M. (2005), “Corruption and the Shadow Economy,” International Economic Review, Vol. 46 (3): 817–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ciocchini, F., Durbin, E., and Ng, D. T. C. (2003), “Does Corruption Increase Emerging Market Bond Spreads?,” Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 55: 503–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937), “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, Vol. 4: 386–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colombo, G. (1995), “Korruption als Flächenbrand. Bekämpfungsstrategien in Italien,” Korruption in Deutschland – Ursachen, Erscheinungsformen, Bekämpfungsstrategien, (Berlin: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung): 37–44.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. (1980), “Competitive Process, Competitive Waste, and Institutions,” Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, ed. by Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., and Tullock, G. (College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press): 153–79.Google Scholar
Coolidge, J. and Rose-Ackerman, S. (1997), “High-Level Rent-Seeking and Corruption in African Regimes: Theory and Cases,” Policy Research Working Paper 1780, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Coronel, S. S. (2000), “The Jueteng Republic,” Investigating Estrada: Millions, Mansions and Mistresses, ed. by Coroner, Sheila S.(Manila: PCIJ) 26–36.
Crain, W. M. and Tollison, R. D. (1979), “The Executive Branch in an Interest-Group Perspective,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 8: 555–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Damania, R., Fredriksson, P. G., and Mani, M. (2004), The Persistence of Corruption and Regulatory Compliance Failures: Theory and Evidence,” Public Choice, Vol. 121: 363–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darroch, Fiona (2004), Lesotho – “A sheep or a springbock? The herd boy tackles Goliath,” commissioned case study, Anti-Corruption Strategies Programme, Three Strikes Against Graft, Assessing the Impact of Groundbreaking Corruption Cases in Lesotho, Mozambique and South Africa; The Implications for Countering Corruption in Southern Africa, 2004. www.iss.co.za/SEMINARS/2004/1503graft/lesotho.pdf
Davidson, S. (1999), “Okeahalam and Bah on Corruption: A Comment,” South African Journal of Economics, Vol. 67 (1) March: 157–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soto, H. (1989), The Other Path (New York: Harper and Row).Google Scholar
della Porta, D. and Vanucci, A. (1999), Corrupt Exchanges, Actors, Resources and Mechanisms of Political Corruption (New York: de Gruyter).Google Scholar
Dick, A. R. (1995), “When does Organized Crime Pay? A Transaction Cost Analysis,” International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 15: 25–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Tella, R. and Schargrodsky, E., (2003) “The Role of Wages and Auditing during a Crackdown on Corruption in the City of Buenos Aires.” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 46(1): 269–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Djankov, S., Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (2002), “The Regulation of Entry,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117 (1): 1–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doh, J. and Teegen, H. (2003), “Private Telecommunications Investment in Emerging Economies – Comparing the Latin American and Asian Experience,” Management Research, Vol. 1 (1): 9–26.Google Scholar
Dollar, D., Fisman, R., and Gatti, R. (2001), “Are Women Really the ‘Fairer’ Sex? Corruption and Women in Government,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 46 (4): 423–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper and Row).Google Scholar
Drew, E. (1983), Politics and Money. The New Road to Corruption (New York: Macmillan).Google Scholar
Dušek, L., A. Ortmann, and L. Lízal (2005), “Understanding Corruption and Corruptibility through Experiments: A Primer, Prague Economic Papers 2. University of Economics, Prague, Czech Republic.
Efron, B. and Tibshirani, R. (1993), An Introduction to the Bootstrap, New York and London: Chapman & Hall.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
EIRIS (2005), “Corporate Codes of Business Ethics: An International Survey of Bribery and Ethical Standards in Companies.” Publication of the Ethical Investment Research Services, London. Online version at www.eiris.org/files/research%20publications/corporatecodesofbusinessethicse p05. pdf, retrieved December 2006.
Elliott, K. A. (1997), “Corruption as an International Policy Problem: Overview and Recommendations,” Corruption and the Global Economy, ed. by Elliott, K. A. (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics): 175–233.Google Scholar
Esty, D. and M. Porter (2002), “National Environmental Performance Measurement and Determinants,” in ed. by Esty, D. and Cornelius, P., Environmental Performance Measurement: The Global Report 2001–2002, (New York: Oxford University Press): 24–43.Google Scholar
Evans, P. B. and Rauch, J. E. (2000), “Bureaucratic Structures and Economic Performance in Less Developed Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 75: 49–71.Google Scholar
Faccio, M. and D. C. Parsley (2006), “Sudden Deaths: Taking Stock of Political Connections,” ECGI – Finance Working Paper 113/2006.
Fikentscher, W. (1987), “Ersatz im Ausland gezahlter Bestechungsgelder,” Praxis des internationalen Privat– und Verfahrensrechts, (2): 86–90.Google Scholar
Findlay, R. and St. Wellisz (1984), “Toward a Model of Endogenous Rent-Seeking,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, Colander, D. C. (ed.) (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 89–100.Google Scholar
Fisman, R. and Gatti, R. (2002), “Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence Across Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 83 (3): 325–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fjeldstad, O. -H. and Tungodden, B. (2001), “Skatteunndragelse og korrupsjon i Tanzania. En studie av Tanzania Revenue Authority,” Den Ny Verden, Vol. 34 (3): 55–79.Google Scholar
Flowers, M. R. (1987), “Rent-Seeking and Rent Dissipation: A Critical View,” Cato Journal, Vol. 7: 431–40.Google Scholar
Fons, J. (1999), “Improving Transparency in Asian Banking Systems,” Internet Center for Corruption Research, Contribution No. 4. Online version at www.icgg.org/downloads/contribution04_fons.pdf
Foreign Policy (2001), “Measuring Globalization,” Foreign Policy. Online at www.foreignpolicy.com/story/cms.php?story_id=2493, accessed December 2006.
Friedman, E., S.Johnson, , Kaufmann, D., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (2000), “Dodging the Grabbing Hand: The Determinants of Unofficial Activity in 69 Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 76: 459–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M. (1970), “The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits,” New York Times Magazine, September 13. Reprint, L. P. Hartmann, Business Ethics (Chicago, IL: Irwin/McGraw-Hill): 246–51.
Frisch, D. (1999), “Entwicklungspolitische Gesichtspunkte der Korruption,” Korruption im internationalen Geschäftsverkehr: Bestandsaufnahme, Bekämpfung, Prävention, ed. by Pieth, M. and Eigen, P. (Basel, Frankfurt am Main: Luchterhand): 89–100.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. G. and Richter, R. (1998), Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of New Institutional Economics (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press).Google Scholar
Galeotti, G. and A. Merlo (1994), “Political Collusion and Corruption in a Representative Democracy,” Unpublished manuscript. Universita'di Roma “La Sapienza” and University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN.
Galtung, F. (1999), “BPI Framework Document,” Transparency International Background Paper. Online version at www.transparency.org/cpi/1999/bpi_framework.html, retrieved March, 2004.
Gambetta, D. (1998), “Comment on ‘Corruption and Development,’ by Susan Rose-Ackerman,” Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics 1997, ed. by. Pleskovic, B. and Stiglitz, J. E. (Washington D.C.: The World Bank): 58–61.Google Scholar
Gardiner, J. A. and Olson, D. J. (1974), Theft of the City (Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press).Google Scholar
Gastil, R. D. (1986), Freedom in the World. Political Rights and Civil Liberties 1985–86 (New York: Greenwood Press).Google Scholar
Gatti, R. (1999), “Corruption and Trade Tariffs, or a Case for Uniform Tariffs,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2216.
Gerring, J. and Thacker, S. (2004), “Political Institutions and Governance: Pluralism versus Centralism,” British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 34 (2): 295–3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerring, J. and Thacker, S. (2005), “Do Neoliberal Policies Deter Political Corruption?,” International Organization, Vol. 59: 233–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghura, D. (2002), “Tax Revenue in Sub-Saharan Africa: Effects of Economic Policies and Corruption,” Governance, Corruption & Economic Performance, ed. by Abed, G. T. and Gupta, S., Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 369–95.Google Scholar
Githongo, J. (1997), “Independency, Investigation and Denunciation of Corruption from the Press – The Case of Kenya,” 8th International Anti-Corruption Conference, Lima, Peru, September.
Glaeser, E. and Saks, R. E. (2006), “Corruption in America,” Journal of Public Economics Vol. 90(6–7): 1053–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goel, R. K. and Nelson, M. A. (1998), “Corruption and Government Size: A Disaggregated Analysis,” Public Choice, Vol. 97 (1): 107–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goel, R. K. and Nelson, M. A. (2005), “Economic Freedom versus Political Freedom: Cross-Country Influences on Corruption,” Australian Economic Papers, Vol. 44: 121–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goetz, C. J. and Scott, R. E. (1981), “Principles of Relational Contracts,” Virginia Law Review, Vol. 67: 1089–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldsmith, A. A. (1999), “Slapping the Grasping Hand: Correlates of Political Corruption in Emerging Markets,” The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 58 (4): 866–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graeff, P. and Mehlkop, G. (2003), “The Impact of Economic Freedom on Corruption: Different Patterns for Rich and Poor Countries,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 19: 605–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, M. (1992), “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness,” The Sociology of Economic Life, ed. by Granovetter, M. and Swedberg, R. (Boulder, CO: Westview Press): 53–81.Google Scholar
Grossman, H. I. (1995), “Rival Kleptocrats: The Mafia versus the State,” The Economics of Organized Crime, ed. by Fiorentini, G. and Peltzman, S. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press): 143–56.Google Scholar
Gupta, M. R. and Chaudhuri, S. (1997), “Formal Credit, Corruption and the Informal Credit Market in Agriculture: A Theoretical Analysis,” Economica, 64: 331–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, S., Mello, L., and Sharan, R. (2001a), “Corruption and Military Spending,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 17 (4): 749–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, S., H. Davoodi, and E. R. Tiongson (2001b), “Corruption and the Provision of Health Care and Education Services,” The Political Economy of Corruption, ed. by Jain, A. K. (London: Routledge): 111–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, S., Davoodi, H., and Alonso-Terme, R. (2002), “Does Corruption Affect Income Inequality and Poverty?,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 3: 23–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gylfason, T. (2001), “Nature, Power and Growth,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 48: 558–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gymiah-Brempong, K. (2002), “Corruption, Economic Growth, and Income Inequality in Africa,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 3: 183–209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, J. and Lawson, R. (2000), “Economic Freedom of the World: 2000 Annual Report,” (Vancouver, BC): Fraser Institute.Google Scholar
Habib, M. and Zurawicki, L. (2001), “Country-Level Investments and the Effect of Corruption: Some Empirical Evidence,” International Business Review, Vol. 10 (6): 687–700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Habib, M. and Zurawicki, L. (2002), “Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment,” Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 33 (2): 291–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. and Jones, C. (1999), “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker than Others,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114: 83–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, T. and G. Yago (2000), “Estimating the Cost of Opacity Using Sovereign Bond Spreads,” unpublished manuscript, Milken Institute, Santa Monica, CA.
Harden, B. (1993), Africa. Dispatches from a Fragile Continent (London: Harper Collins Publishers, paperback edition).Google Scholar
Hart, A. G. (1970), “Fiscal Policy in Latin America,” Part 2: Key Problems of Economic Policy in Latin America, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78 (4): 857–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, O. D. (1987), “Incomplete Contracts,” The New Palgrave-Allocation, Information and Markets, Vol. 2, ed. by Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P., (London: Macmillan): 752–9.Google Scholar
Hart, O. D. (1991), “Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of the Firm,” The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development, ed. by Williamson, O. D. and Winter, S. G. (New York: Oxford University Press): 138–58.Google Scholar
Hasker, K. and C. Okten (2004), Intermediaries and Corruption, unpublished working paper, Ankara, Turkey: Bilkent University. Forthcoming in Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization.
Heidenheimer, A., Johnston, M. and LeVine, V. (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook, 2nd ed. (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers).Google Scholar
Henderson, D. R. (1999), “Power Corrupts – Editorial Comment,” The Wall Street Journal, April 19.Google Scholar
Henisz, W. (2000), “The institutional environment for multinational investment,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 16 (2): 334–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hepkema, S. and Booysen, W. (1997), “The Bribery of Public Officials: An IBA Survey,” International Business Lawyer, Vol. 25 (9): 415–16, 422.Google Scholar
Herrera, A. and P. Rodriguez (2003), “Bribery and the Nature of Corruption,”unpublished manuscript, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI and The Darden School, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, VA, July.
Herzfeld, T. and Weiss, C. (2003), “Corruption and legal (in)effectiveness: an empirical investigation,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 19: 621–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heymann, P. B. (1995), “Korruption in den USA. Rechtliche, wirtschaftliche und ethische Aspekte,” Korruption in Deutschland – Ursachen, Erscheinungsformen, Bekämpfungsstrategien, (Berlin: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung): 49–56.Google Scholar
Hillman, A. L. and Katz, E. (1984), “Risk Averse Rent Seekers and the Social Cost of Monopoly Power,” Economic Journal, Vol. 94: 104–10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hines, J. R. (1995), “Forbidden Payment: Foreign Bribery and American Business after 1977,” NBER Working Paper 5266, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. (1976), “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation: Comment,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 19: 241–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hofstede, G. (1997), Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind (New York: McGraw Hill).Google Scholar
Huntington, S. P. (1968), “Modernization and Corruption,” Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press): 59–71. Reprinted in A. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, and V. LeVine (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers): 377–88.Google Scholar
Husted, B. (1999), “Wealth, Culture, and Corruption,” Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 30 (2): 339–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Husted, B. W. (1994), “Honor Among Thieves: A Transaction-Cost Interpretation of Corruption in Third World Countries,” Business Ethics Quarterly, Vol. 4: 17–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huther, J. and A. Shah, (1998), “A Simple Measure of Good Governance and its Application to the Debate on the Appropriate Level of Fiscal Decentralization,” World Bank Working Paper, 1894, Washington, DC.
Hwang, J. (2002), “A Note on the Relationship between Corruption and Government,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 27 (2): 161–77.Google Scholar
Isham, J. and Kaufmann, D. (1999), “The Forgotten Rationale for Policy Reform: The Productivity of Investment Projects,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114: 149–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jagannathan, N. V. (1986), “Corruption, Delivery Systems, and Property Rights,” World Development, Vol. 14: 127–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jain, A. K. (1998), “Models of Corruption,” Economics of Corruption, ed. by Jain, A. K. (Boston, London, and Dordrecht): 13–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jarvin, S. (1986), “Aus der Praxis des ICC Schiedgerichtshofes,” Recht und Praxis der Schiedsgerichtsbarkeit der Internationalen Handelskammer. Schriftenreihe des Deutschen Instituts für Schiedsgerichtsverfahren, ed. by Böckstiegel, K. -H. (Köln: Heymann): 7–51.Google Scholar
Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1998), “Regulatory Discretion and the Unofficial Economy,” The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 88: 387–92.Google Scholar
Kapstein, E. (2001), “Five Basic Principles for a Worldwide Code of Business Ethics,” International Herald Tribune, January 24.Google Scholar
Kargl, W. (2002), “Über die Bekämpfung des Anscheins der Kriminalität bei der Vorteilsannahme (§ 331 StGB),” Zeitschrift für die gesamte Strafrechtswissenschaft (ZStW), Vol. 114 (4): 763–81.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D. and Wei, S. -J. (1999), “Does ‘Grease Money’ Speed up the Wheels of Commerce?,” NBER Working Paper 7093, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1999a), “Aggregating Governance Indicators,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2195, Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1999b), “Governance Matters,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2196, October, Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Khalil, F. and Lawarree, J. (1995), “Collusive Auditors,” The American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 85 (2): 442–6.Google Scholar
Klein, B. (1996), “Why Hold-Ups Occur: The Self-Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships,” Economic Inquiry, Vol. 34: 444–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., and Alchian, A. A. (1978), “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 21: 297–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleinschmidt, P., H. Achatz, and J. Graf Lambsdorff (2005), “The Corruption Perceptions Index and the Linear Ordering Problem,” presented at the Annual International Conference of the German Operations Research Society (GOR), September 9, 2005.
Klitgaard, R. (1988), Controlling Corruption (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press).Google Scholar
Knack, S. and Azfar, O. (2003), “Trade Intensity, Country Size and Corruption,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 4 (1): 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1995), “Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 7: 207–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knapp, W. (1986), “Sittenwidrige Vermittlung von Regierungsaufträgen durch Bestechungsgelder,” RIW – Recht der Internationalen Wirtschaft: 999–1001.Google Scholar
Kofman, F. and Lawarree, J. (1996), “On the Optimality of Allowing Collusion,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 61: 383–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kranton, R. E. (1996), “Reciprocal Exchange: A Self-Sustaining System,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 86 (4): 830–51.Google Scholar
Kreps, D. M. (1990), “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory,” Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. by Alt, J. and Shepsle, K. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press): 90–143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. M. and Wilson, R. (1982), “Reputation and Imperfect Information,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 27: 253–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, A. (1974), “The Political Economy of the Rent Seeking Society,” American Economic Review, Vol. 64: 291–303.Google Scholar
Krueger, A. (1990), “Government Failures in Development,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 4: 9–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunicova, J. (2005), “Are Presidential Systems More Susceptible to Political Corruption?,” mimeo, Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Kunicova, J. (2002), “When Are Opposition's Lips Sealed? Comparative Political Corruption in Democracies,” mimeo, Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Kunicova, J. and Rose-Ackerman, S. (2005), “Electoral Rules and Constitutional Structures as Constraints on Corruption,” British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 35 (4): 573–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1997), “Trust in Large Organizations,” The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 137 (2): 333–8.Google Scholar
Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1999), “The Quality of Government,” The Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 15 (1): 222–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, J. -J. and Tirole, J. (1993), A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
Lambert-Mogiliansky, A. (2002), “Why Firms Pay Occasional Bribes: The Connection Economy,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 18: 47–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (1998a), “An Empirical Investigation of Bribery in International Trade,” European Journal for Development Research, Vol. 10: 40–59. Reprinted in Corruption and Development, ed. by M. Robinson (London: Frank Cass Publishers): 40–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (1999), “Korruption im internationalen Geschäftsverkehr. Bestandsaufnahme, Bekämpfung, Prävention,” Korruption als mühseliges Geschäft –eine Transaktionskostenanalyse, ed. by Pieth, M. and Eigen, P. (Basel, Frankfurt am Main: Luchterhand): 56–88.Google Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2000), “De la propension des exportateurs à verser des pots-de-vin –l'impact sur les échanges,” Revue Tiers Monde, Vol. 41 (161): 89–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2002a), “Making Corrupt Deals – Contracting in the Shadow of Law,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 48 (3): 221–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2002b), “Corruption and Rent-Seeking,” Public Choice, Vol. 113 (1/2): 97–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2002c), “How Confidence facilitates illegal Transactions,” American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 61 (4): 829–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2003a), “How Corruption Affects Productivity,” Kyklos, Vol. 56 (4): 459–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2003b), “How Corruption Affects Persistent Capital Flows,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 4 (3): 229–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2005a), “Between Two Evils – Investors Prefer Grand Corruption!,” University of Passau, Discussion Paper V-31–05, January.
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2005b), “Determining Trends for Perceived Levels of Corruption,” Passau University, Discussion Paper V-38–06.
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2006), “Ten Years of the CPI: Determining trends,” Global Corruption Report 2006, Transparency International.
Lambsdorff, J. Graf and M. Nell (2005), “Let Them Take Gifts, and Cheat Those Who Seek Influence,” Economics Faculty of Passau University, Discussion Paper 41–05, December 2005.
Lambsdorff, J. Graf and P. Cornelius (2000), “Corruption, Foreign Investment and Growth,” The Africa Competitiveness Report 2000/2001, ed. by Schwab, K., Cook, L., Cornelius, P., Sachs, J. D., Sievers, S., and Warner, A. joint publication of the World Economic Forum and the Institute for International Development, (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University and Oxford: Oxford University Press: 70–78.Google Scholar
Lambsdorff, J.Graf, M. Schramm, and Taube, M. (2004), The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, (London: Routledge).Google Scholar
Landes, W. M. and Posner, R. A. (1975), “The Independent Judiciary in an Interest-Group Perspective,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 18: 875–901.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LaPalombara, J. (1994), “Structural and Institutional Aspects of Corruption,” Social Research, Vol. 61: 325–50.Google Scholar
Lederman, D., N. Loayza, and R. Reis Soares (2001), “Accountability and Corruption. Political Institutions Matter,” The World Bank Working Paper 2708.
Lee, C. M. and D. Ng (2004), “Corruption and International Valuation. Does Virtue Pay?,” unpublished manuscript, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.
Leff, N. H. (1964), “Economic Development Through Bureaucratic Corruption,” American Behavioral Scientist, Vol. 8 (3): 8–14. Reprinted in A. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, and V. LeVine (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers) 389–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leite, C. and Weidemann, J. (1999), “Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption, and Economic Growth,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper 99/85, July.Google Scholar
Li, H., Xu, L. C., and Zou, H. -F. (2000), “Corruption, Income Distribution, and Growth,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 12 (2): 155–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lien, D. H. D. (1986), “A Note on Competitive Bribery Games,” Economics Letters, Vol. 22: 337–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindstedt, C. and D. Naurin (2005), “Transparency and Corruption. A Cross-Country Study of the Significance of a Free Press,” paper prepared for the 3rd ECPR Conference, The Quality of Democracy, Budapest, September.
Lipset, S. M. and G. S. Lenz (2000), “Corruption, Culture, and Markets,” In Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress, ed. by Harrison, L. E. and Huntington, S. P. (New York: Basic Books): 112–24.Google Scholar
Lui, F. T. (1985), “An Equilibrium Queuing Model of Bribery,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93: 760–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacGuire, M. C. and Olson, M. (1996), “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule: The Invisible Hand and the Use of Force,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 34: 72–96.Google Scholar
Macneil, I. R. (1974), “The Many Futures of Contracts,” Southern California Law Review, Vol. 47: 691–816.Google Scholar
Macneil, I. R. (1978), “Contracts: Adjustment of Long Term Economic Relations under Classical, Neoclassical and Relational Contract Law,” Northwestern University Law Review, Vol. 72: 854–905.Google Scholar
Magee, St. P. (1984), “Endogenous Tariff Theory,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 41–54.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. G. (2000), Principles of Economics, 2nd ed. (Fort Worth, TX, Harcourt College Publishers).Google Scholar
Manow, P. (2005), “Politische Korruption und politischer Wettbewerb: Probleme der quantitativen Analyse,” Dimensionen politischer Korruption, ed. by U. von Alemann, PVS – Politische Vierteljahresschrift, VS – Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften: Wiesbaden, Sonderheft 35: 249–66.CrossRef
Marcoullier, D. and Young, L. (1995), “The Black Hole of Graft: The Predatory State and the Informal Economy,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 85 (3): 630–46.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1897), “The Old Generation of Economists and the New,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 11 (2): 115–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mauro, P. (1995), “Corruption and Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110 (3): 681–712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mauro, P. (1997a), “The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment, and Government Expenditure: A Cross-Country Analysis,” Corruption and the Global Economy, ed. by Elliott, K. (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics): 83–107.Google Scholar
Mauro, P. (1997b), “Why Worry about Corruption?,” Economic Issues No. 6 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).Google Scholar
Mauro, P. (1998), “Corruption and the Composition of Government Expenditure,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 69: 263–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mbaku, J. M. (1992), “Bureaucratic Corruption as Rent-Seeking Behavior,” Konjunkturpolitik, Vol. 38: 247–65.Google Scholar
Mbaku, J. M. (1998), “Corruption and Rent-Seeking,” The Political Dimension of Economic Growth, ed. by Borner, S. and Paldam, M. (London and New York: Macmillan Press and St. Martins Press): 193–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McChesney, F. S. (1987), “Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in the Economic Theory of Regulation,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 16: 101–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McChesney, F. S. (1997), Money for Nothing. Politicians, Rent Extraction, and Political Extortion (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
McGuire, M. C. and Olson, M. (1996), “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule: The Invisible Hand and the Use of Force,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 34: 72–96.Google Scholar
Méon, P. -G. and Sekkat, K. (2004), “Does the Quality of Institutions Limit the MENA's Integration in the World Economy?,” The World Economy, Vol. 27 (9): 1475–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Méon, P. -G. and Sekkat, K. (2005), “Does Corruption Grease or Sand the Wheels of Growth?,” Public Choice, Vol. 122: 69–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, W. L., Grødeland, Å, and Koshechkina, T. Y. (2001), A Culture of Corruption – Coping with Government in Post-communist Europe (Budapest: Central European University Press).Google Scholar
Mo, P. H. (2001), “Corruption and Economic Growth,” Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 29: 66–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mocan, N. (2004), “What Determines Corruption? International Evidence from Micro Data,” NBER Working Paper 10460.
Moe, T. M. (1984), “The New Economics of Organization,” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 28 (4): 739–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montinola, G. and Jackman, R. W. (2002), “Sources of Corruption: A Cross-Country Study,” British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 32: 147–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moody-Stuart, G. (1994), “Grand Corruption in Third World Development,” Transparency International (TI) Working Paper, Berlin: Transparency International.Google Scholar
Moody-Stuart, George (1997), Grand Corruption. How Business Bribes Damage Developing Countries (Oxford, UK: WorldView Publishing).Google Scholar
Mookherjee, D. and Png, I. P. L. (1995), “Corruptible Law Enforcers: How should they be compensated?,”The Economic Journal, Vol. 105: 145–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moran, Th. (2006), “How Multinational Investors Evade Developed Country Laws,” Center for Global Development Working Paper 79. online version at www.cgdev.org/content/publications/detail/6113
Morgan, Th. (1964), “The Theory of Error in Centrally-Directed Economic Systems,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 78 (3): 395–419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moselle, B. and Polak, B. (2001), “A Model of a Predatory State,” Journal of Law Economics and Organization, Vol. 17 (1): 1–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1993), “Why is Rent-Seeking so Costly to Growth?,”The American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 82 (2): 409–14.Google Scholar
Myrdal, G. (1956), An International Economy (New York: Harper and Bros.).Google Scholar
Myrdal, G. (1968), Asian Drama. Vol. II (New York: Random House).Google Scholar
Neeman, Z., Paserman, M., and Simhon, A. (2003), “Corruption and Openness,” CEPR Discussion Paper 4057. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.Google Scholar
Nelson, W. and Winter, S. G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change (Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Neugebauer, G. (1978), Grundzüge einer ökonomischen Theorie der Korruption. Eine Studie über die Bestechung. Basler sozialökonomische Studien (Zürich: Schulthess Polygraphischer Verlag).Google Scholar
Niskanen, W. (1971), Bureaucracy and Representative Government (Chicago, IL: Aldine Press).Google Scholar
Niskanen, W. (1975), “Bureaucrats and Politicians,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 18: 617–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History (New York and London: Norton).Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1984), “Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 33–40.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1993), “Institutions and Credible Commitment,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol. 149: 11–23.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. R. (1989), “The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 49: 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nye, J. S. (1967), “Corruption and Political Development: A Cost Benefit Analysis,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 61 (2): 417–27. Reprinted in A. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, and V. LeVine (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers): 963–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2003), Business Approaches to Combating Corrupt Practices, Study prepared by the Capital Movements, International Investment and Services Division, OECD Directorate for Financial, Fiscal and Enterprise Affairs, September.
Okeahalam, C. C. and Bah, I. (1998), “Perceived Corruption and Investment in Sub-Saharan African,” South African Journal of Economics, Vol. 67 (1), March: 386.Google Scholar
Oldenburg, P. (1987), “Middlemen in Third-World Corruption: Implications of an Indian Case,” World Politics, Vol. 39: 508–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olsen, T. and Torsvik, G. (1998), “Collusion and Renegotiation in Hierarchies: A Case of Beneficial Corruption,” International Economic Review, Vol. 39 (2), May: 413–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1982), The Rise and Decline of Nations (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Orchard, L. and Stretton, H. (1997), “Public Choice,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 21 (3): 409–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M. (2001), “Corruption and Religion. Adding to the Economic Model,” Kyklos, Vol. 54 (2/3): 383–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M. (2002), “The Big Pattern of Corruption. Economics, Culture and the Seesaw Dynamics,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 18: 215–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Panizza, U. (2001), “Electoral Rules, Political Systems, and Institutional Quality,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 13 (3): 311–42.Google Scholar
Pechlivanos, L. (1998), “Self-Enforcing Corruption and Optimal Deterrence,” unpublished manuscript, Université des Sciences Sociales, Toulouse, France.
Pechlivanos, L. (2004), “Self-Enforcing Corruption: Information Transmission and Organizational Response,” The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, ed. by Lambsdorff, J. Graf, Schramm, M., and Taube, M.London: Routledge: 93–111.Google Scholar
Pellegrini, L. and Gerlagh, R. (2004), “Corruption's Effect on Growth and its Transmission Channels,” Kyklos, Vol. 57 (3): 429–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pellegrini, L. and S. Vujic (2003), “Corruption, Economic Development and Environmental Policy,” Political Economy of the Environment, Institute for Environmental Studies, IVM, Working Paper, the Netherlands.
Peltzman, S. (1976), “Towards a More General Theory of Regulation,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 20: 322–40.Google Scholar
Peltzman, S. (1989), “The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation,” Brooking Papers of Economic Activity: Microeconomics, ed. by Baily, M. N. and Winston, C. (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution): 1–41.Google Scholar
Persson, T., Tabellini, G., and Trebbi, F. (2003), “Electoral Rules and Corruption,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 1 (4): 958–89, formerly published in: NBER Working Paper 8154, March 2001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poirson, H. (1998), “Economic Security, Private Investment, and Growth in Developing Countries,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper 98/4, January.
Pope, J. (2000), The Transparency International Source Book 2000 – Confronting Corruption: The Elements of a National Integrity System (Berlin: Transparency International). Online version at www.transparency.org/sourcebook/, retrieved December 2006.
Posner, R. A. (1974), “Theories of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management, Vol. 5 (2): 335–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, R. A. (1975), “The Social Cost of Monopoly and Regulation,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 83: 807–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pritzl, R. F. J. (1995), “La Corrupción pública: una forma dinámica e ilegal de rentismo o rent-seeking en la lucha distributiva de los grupos de interés organizados,” Corrupción. Contribuciones. Publication Trimestral 4 (Buenos Aires: Konrad Adenauer Stiftung and CIEDLA).
Pryor, F. L. (1984), “Rent-Seeking and the Growth and Fluctuations of Nations. Empirical Tests of Some Recent Hypothesis,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colande, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 155–75.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D. (1993), Making Democracy Work. Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Rasmusen, E. and Ramseyer, J. M. (1994), “Cheap Bribes and the Corruption Ban: A Coordination Game among Rational Legislators,” Public Choice, Vol. 74: 305–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, C. J. and Watson, A. (2004), “Corruption and Change: The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment,” Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 25 (4): 385–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rock, M. T. and Bonnett, H. (2004), “The comparative politics of corruption: Accounting for the East Asian paradox in empirical studies of corruption growth and investment,” World Development, 32 (6): 999–1017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Root, H. (1999), “The Importance of Being Small,” Center for International Studies Working Paper 99–13, Los Angeles, CA: University of Southern California.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1975), “The Economics of Corruption,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 4: 187–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978), Corruption – A Study in Political Economy (New Haven, CT: Academic Press).Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1998), “The Role of the World Bank in Controlling Corruption,” Law and Policy in International Business, Vol. 29: 93–114.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1999), Corruption and Government. Causes, Consequences and Reform (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (2005), From Elections to Democracy. Building Accountable Government in Hungary and Poland (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, J. and Warner, A. (1995), “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 25 (1): 1–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandholtz, W. and Gray, M. (2003), “International Integration and National Corruption,” International Organization, Vol. 57 (4): 761–800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandholtz, W. and Koetzle, W. (2000), “Accounting for Corruption: Economic Structure, Democracy, and Trade,” Industrial Studies Quarterly, Vol. 44: 31–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandholtz, W. and Taagepera, R. (2005), “Corruption, Culture, and Communism,” International Review of Sociology, Vol. 15 (1): 109–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sayed, A. (2004): Corruption in International Trade and Commercial Arbitration (The Hague.: Kluwer Law International).Google Scholar
Schrag, J. and Scotchmer, S. (1997), “The Self-Reinforcing Nature of Crime,” International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 17: 325–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schramm, M. and M. Taube (2003), “The Institutional Economics of Legal Institutions, Guanxi, and Corruption in the PR China,” Fighting Corruption in Asia. Causes, Effects and Remedies ed. by Kidd, J. and Richter, J., New Jersey, London, Singapore, and Hong Kong): 271–96.Google Scholar
Schulze, G. and Frank, B. (2003), “Deterrence versus Intrinsic Motivation: Experimental Evidence on the Determinants of Corruptibility,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 4 (2): 143–60.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (New York: Harper & Bros.).Google Scholar
Scott, J. C. (1972), Comparative Political Corruption (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall).Google Scholar
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. W. (1993), “Corruption,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108: 599–617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. W. (1998), The Grabbing Hand – Government Pathologies and their Cures. Cambridge, MA: (Harvard University Press): 1–17.Google Scholar
Shugart, M. S. (1999), “Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and the Provision of Collective Goods in Less-Developed Countries,” Constitutional Political Economy, Vol. 10: 53–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smarzynska, B. K. and Wei, S. (2000), “Corruption and the Composition of Foreign Direct Investment: Firm-Level Evidence,” World Bank Discussion Paper 2360, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Smith, R. J., Muir, R. D. J., Walpole, M. J., Balmford, A. and Leader-Williams, N. (2003), “Governance and the loss of biodiversity,” Nature, Vol. 426: 67–70.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Soskice, D. (1999), “Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1990s,” Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, ed. by Kitschelt, H., Lange, P., Marks, G., and Stephens, J. (New York: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stansbury, N. (2004), Anti-corruption Initiative in the Construction and Engineering Industry, Report Five: The Prevention of Bribery Through Agency Commissions, Transparency International (UK).
Stigler, G. J. (1971), “The Theory of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 2: 3–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. (1998a), “Redefining the Role of the State – What Should it do? How Should it do it? And How Should these Decisions be Made?,” Paper presented on the Tenth Anniversary of MITI Research Institute, Tokyo. Online version at www.worldbank.org/html/extdr/extme/redefine.pdf, retrieved December 2006.
Stiglitz, J. (1998b), “Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: The Private Uses of Public Interests: Incentives and Institutions,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 12 (2): 3–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stratmann, T. (2003), “Do Strict Electoral Campaign Finance Rules Limit Corruption?,” CESifo DICE Report 1: 24–27.
Straub, S. (2003), “Opportunism, Corruption and the Multinational Firm's Mode of Entry,” Edinburgh School of Economics, Discussion Paper 102.
Strausz, R. (1995), “Collusion and Renegotiation in a Principal – Supervisior – Agent Relationship,” Center for Economic Research, Discussion Paper 9548, Netherlands: Tilburg University.Google Scholar
Sung, H. -E. (2002), “A Convergence Approach to the Analysis of Political Corruption: A Cross-National Study,” Crime, Law and Social Change, Vol. 38 (2): 137–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sung, H. -E. (2003), “Fairer Sex or Fairer System? Gender and Corruption Revisited,” Social Forces, Vol. 82 (2): 703–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sung, H. -E. (2004), “Democracy and Political Corruption: A Cross-National Comparison,” Crime, Law and Social Change, Vol. 41 (2): 179–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sung, H. -E. and Chu, D. (2003), “Does Participation in the Global Economy Reduce Political Corruption? An Empirical Inquiry,” International Journal of Comparative Criminology, Vol. 3 (2): 94–118.Google Scholar
Svensson, J. (2003), “Who Must Pay Bribes and How Much? Evidence from a Cross Section of Firms,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118 (1): 207–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, J. (2005), “Eight Questions about Corruption,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 19 (3): 19–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swamy, A., Knack, St., Lee, Y., and Azfar, O. (2001), “Gender and Corruption,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 64: 25–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tanzi, V. (1995), “Corruption: Arm's–length Relationships and Markets,” The Economics of Organized Crime, ed. by Fiorentini, G. and Peltzman, S. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press): 161–180.Google Scholar
Tanzi, V. and H. Davoodi (1997), “Corruption, Public Investment, and Growth,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper 97/139.
Tanzi, V. and H. Davoodi (2001), “Corruption, Growth, and Public Finances,” Political Economy of Corruption, ed. by Jain, A. K. (London: Routledge): 89–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavares, S. (2005), “Does Rapid Trade Liberalization Increase Corruption?,” paper presented at the European Public Choice Society Conference 2005.
Tellenbach, S. (1997), “Türkei,” Korruptionsbekämpfung durch Strafrecht, ed. by Eser, A., Überhofen, M., and Huber, B.. Freiburg, Germany: Max-Planck-Institut für ausländisches und internationales Strafrecht.Google Scholar
Testa, C. (2003), “Government Corruption and Legislative Procedures: Is One Chamber Better than Two?,” mimeo, Royal Holloway College, University of London.Google Scholar
Thompson, D. F. (1993), “Mediated Corruption: The Case of the Keating Five,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 87: 369–381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tollison, R. D. (1982), “Rent Seeking: A Survey,” Kyklos, Vol. 35: 575–602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tonoyan, V. (2004), “The Bright and Dark Sides of Trust: Corruption and Entrepreneurship,” Trust and Entrepreneurship: A West-East-Perspective, ed. by H. Höhmann and F. Welter (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar). Online version at: www.icgg.org/downloads/contribution11_tonoyan.pdf
Transparency International, (1999), Newsletter. Berlin: Transparency International, September.
Treisman, D. (1999), “Decentralization and Corruption: Why are Federal States Perceived to be More Corrupt,” paper prepared for the presentation at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, September.
Treisman, D. (2000), “The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National Study,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 76: 399–457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. (1967), “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft,” Western Economic Journal, Vol. 5 (3): 224–32.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1971), “The Cost of Transfers,” Kyklos, Vol. 24: 629–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. (1975), “Competing for Aid,” Public Choice, Vol. 21: 41–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. (1980a), “Rent Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game,” Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, ed. by Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., and Tullock, G. (College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press): 16–36.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1980b), “Efficient Rent Seeking,” Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, ed. by Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., and Tullock, G. (College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press): 97–112.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1989), “Klitgaard, Robert, Controlling Corruption,” The Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 27: 658–9.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1993), Rent Seeking, The Shaftesbury Papers 2, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Uhlenbruck, K., P. Rodriguez, J. Doh, and L. Eden (2006), “The Impact of Corruption on Entry Strategy: Evidence from Telecommunication Projects in Emerging Economies,” Organization Science, Vol. 17(3): 402–14.CrossRef
United Nations (2006), “Seventh United Nations Survey of Crime Trends and Operations of Criminal Justice Systems, covering the period 1998–2000” Report by the United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime. Retrieved in December 2006 from: www.unodc.org/unodc/crime_cicp_survey_ seventh.html
Uslaner, E. (2004), “Trust and Corruption,” The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, ed. by Lambsdorff, J. Graf, Schramm, M., and Taube, M. (London: Routledge): 76–92.Google Scholar
Rijckeghem, C. and Weder, B. (2001), “Bureaucratic Corruption and the Rate of Temptation: Do Wages in the Civil Service affect Corruption, and by How Much?,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 65 (2): 307–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanucci, A. (2000), “Corruption, Political Parties and Political Protection,” European University Institute Economics Department, Working Paper 62, Badia Fiesolana: San Domenico.
Voigt, S., Feld, L., and Aaken, A. (2004), “Power over Prosecutors Corrupts Politicians: Cross Country Evidence Using a New Indicator,” Draft Version, Economics Faculty, University of Kassel, Germany.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1920), Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie (Tübingen, Germany: Mohr & Siebeck). Reprinted 1988.Google Scholar
Wedeman, A. (1997), “Looters, Rent-scrapers, and Dividend–Collectors: Corruption and Growth in Zaire, South Korea, and the Philippines,” The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 31: 457–78.Google Scholar
Wei, S. -J. (1997), “Why is Corruption so Much More Taxing than Tax? Arbitrariness Kills,” NBER Working Paper 6255, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Wei, S. -J. (2000a), “Natural Openness and Good Government,” World Bank Poliy Research Working Paper 2411 and NBER Working Paper 7765.
Wei, S. -J. (2000b), “How Taxing is Corruption on International Investors,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 82 (1): 1–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wei, S. -J. (2000c), “Corruption, Composition of Capital Flows, and Currency Crises,” World Bank Working Paper 2429.
Wei, S. -J. and Sievers, S. (1999), “The Cost of Crony Capitalism,” The Asian Competitiveness Report 1999. Geneva: World Economic Forum, 50–55.Google Scholar
Wei, S. -J. and Y. Wu (2001), “Negative Alchemy? Corruption, Composition of Capital Flows, and Currency Crises,” NBER Working Paper 8187, March.
Weingast, B. R. (1993), “Constitutions as Governance Structures: The Political Foundations of Secure Markets,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol. 149: 286–311.Google Scholar
Wellisz, St. and R. Findlay (1984), “Protection and Rent-Seeking in Developing Countries,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 141–54.Google Scholar
Welsch, H. (2004), “Corruption, Growth, and the Environment: A Cross-Country Analysis,” Environment and Development Economics, Vol. 9: 663–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wheeler, D. and Mody, A. (1992), “International Investment Location Decisions: The Case of U.S. Firms,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 33: 57–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiehen, M. (1996), “OECD Recommendations and Enquiry,” Uganda International Conference on Good Governance in Africa (Berlin: Transparency International): 115–22.Google Scholar
Wiggins, S. (1991), “The Economics of the Firm and Contracts: A Selective Survey,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol. 147: 603–61.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. (1993), “Exchange Rate Management,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 103: 188–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1983), “Credible Commitments: The Use of Hostages to Support Exchange,” American Economic Review, Vol. 83: 519–40.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting (New York: The Free Press).Google Scholar
Winston, G. C. (1979), “The Appeal of Inappropriate Technologies: Self-Inflicted Wages, Ethnic Price and Corruption,” World Development, Vol. 7 (8/9): 835–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wintrobe, R. (1998a), “Some Lessons on the Efficiency of Democracy from a Study of Dictatorship,” The Political Dimension of Economic Growth, ed. by Borner, S. and Paldam, M. (London and New York: Macmillan Press and St. Martin Press): 20–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wintrobe, R. (1998b), The Political Economy of Dictatorship (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wintrobe, R. and Breton, A. (1986), “Organizational Structure and Productivity,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 76 (3): 530–8.Google Scholar
World Bank (1997), World Development Report 1997 (Washington, DC: World Bank).
Wyatt, G. (2002), “Corruption, Productivity and Transition,” Centre for Economic Reform and Transformation, (CERT) Discussion Paper 205, Heriot Watt University, Edinburgh, United Kingdom.
You, J. -S. and Khagram, S. (2005), “Inequality and Corruption,” American Sociological Review, Vol. 70 (1): 136–57.Google Scholar
Abbink, K. (2004), “Staff Rotation as an Anti-corruption Policy: An Experimental Study,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 20 (4): 887–906.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abbink, K., Irlenbusch, B., and Renner, E. (2000), “The Moonlighting Game,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 22: 265–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abed, G. T. and H. R. Davoodi (2002), “Corruption, Structural Reforms, and Economic Performance,” Governance, Corruption & Economic Performance, ed. by Abed, G. T. and Gupta, S., Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund 489–537.Google Scholar
Aburish, S. (1985), Pay-Off: Wheeling and Dealing in the Arab World (New York: Harper Collins Publishers).Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Verdier, T. (1998), “Property Rights, Corruption and the Allocation of Talent: A General Equilibrium Approach,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 108: 1381–1403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and Verdier, T. (2000), “The Choice Between Market Failures and Corruption,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 90: 194–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1995), “Competition and Corruption,” Draft Paper, Oxford: Keble College, Oxford University.Google Scholar
Ades, A. and R. Di Tella (1996), “The Causes and Consequences of Corruption: A Review of Recent Empirical Contributions,” Liberalization and the New Corruption, ed. by White, B. Harris and White, G. (Brighton: Institute of Development Studies Bulletin, 27): 6–12.Google Scholar
Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1997), “National Champions and Corruption: Some Unpleasant Interventionist Arithmetic,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 107: 1023–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ades, A. and Di Tella, R. (1999), “Rents, Competition, and Corruption,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 89: 982–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adsera, A., C. Boix, and M. Payne (2000), “Are You Being Served? Political Accountability and Quality of Government,” Inter-American Development Bank Research Department Working Paper 438, Washington, DC.
Aidt, Toke S. (2003), “Economic Analysis of Corruption: A Survey,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 113: 632–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aizenman, J. and M. Spiegel (2003), “Institutional Efficiency, Monitoring Costs, and the Investment Share of FDI,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2003–06.
Alam, S. M. (1990), “Some Economic Costs of Corruption in LDC's,” Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 27: 89–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A. and Weder, B. (1999), “Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid?,” NBER Working Paper 7108, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Alesina, A. and Weder, B. (2002), “Do Corrupt Governments Receive Less Foreign Aid?,”American Economic Review, Vol. 92 (4): 1126–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A., Devleeschauwer, A., Easterly, W., Kurlat, S., and Wacziarg, R. (2003), “Fractionalization,” Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 8: 155–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ali, A. M. and Isse, H. S. (2003), “Determinants of Economic Corruption: A Cross-Country Comparison,” Cato Journal, Vol. 22 (3): 445–66.Google Scholar
Al-Marhubi, F. A. (2000), “Corruption and Inflation,” Economics Letters, Vol. 66 (2): 199–202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, A. (1995), “Organized Crime, Mafia and Governments,” The Economics of Organized Crime, ed. by Fiorentini, G. and Peltzman, S. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press): 33–54.Google Scholar
Anderson, C. J. and Tverdova, Y. V. (2003), “Corruption, Political Allegiances, and Attitudes toward Government in Contemporary Democracies,” American Journal of Political Sciences, Vol. 47 (1): 91–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andvig, J. (1995), “Corruption in the North Sea Oil Industry: Issues and Assessments,” Crime, Law and Social Change, Vol. 23: 289–313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andvig, J. C. (1991), “The Economics of Corruption: A Survey,” Studi Economici, Vol. 43: 57–94.Google Scholar
Andvig, J. C. and O. H. Fjeldstadt (2000), “Research on Corruption. A Policy Oriented Survey,” Chr. Michelsen Institute and Norwegian Institute for International Affairs. Online version at: www.icgg.org/downloads/contribution07_andrig.pdf
Andvig, J. C. and Moene, K. (1990), “How Corruption May Corrupt,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 13: 63–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anoruo, E. and Braha, H. (2005), “Corruption and Economic Growth: The African Experience,” Journal of Sustainable Development in Africa, Vol. 7 (1).Google Scholar
Appelbaum, E. and Katz, E. (1987), “Seeking Rents by Setting Rents: The Political Economy of Rent Seeking,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 97: 685–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arikan, G. (2004), “Fiscal Decentralization: A Remedy for Corruption?,”International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 11: 175–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arlen, J. (1994), “The Potentially Perverse Effects of Corporate Criminal Liability,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 23: 833–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books).Google Scholar
Bannenberg, B. (2002), Korruption in Deutschland und ihre strafrechtliche Kontrolle: Eine kriminologisch-strafrechtliche Analyse (Neuwied/Kriftel, Germany: Luchterhand).Google Scholar
Bardhan, P. (1997), “Corruption and Development: A Review of Issues,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35: 1320–46.Google Scholar
Bartsch, E. and Thomas, I. (1993), “Spieltheoretische Ansätze in der Rent-Seeking Theorie: Ein Literaturüberblick,” Kieler Arbeitspapiere, Institut für Weltwirtschaft, Kiel, Germany, No. 564.Google Scholar
Bartsch, E. and Thomas, I. (1995), “Rent-Seeking, Umverteilung und soziale Kosten,” WiSt –wirtschaftswissenschaftliches Studium, Vol. 24: 174–9.Google Scholar
Bates, R. (1981), Markets and States in Tropical Africa (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press).Google Scholar
Bavarian Criminal Division (2005), unpublished conviction, 4th Criminal Division of the Munich District Court.
Bayley, D. H. (1966), “The Effects of Corruption in a Developing Nation,” The Western Political Quartely, Vol. 19 (4): 719–32. Reprinted in A. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston and V. LeVine (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers): 935–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, P. J. and Maher, M. (1986), “A Comparison of Bribery and Bidding in Thin Markets,” Economics Letters, Vol. 20: 1–5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beck, P. J., Maher, M. W. and Tschoegl, A. E. (1991), “The Impact of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act on US Exports,” Managerial and Decision Economics, Vol. 12: 295–303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1968), “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 76: 169–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. S. (1994), “To Root Out Corruption, Boot Out Big Government,” Business Week, January 31: 18.Google Scholar
Becker, G. S. and Stigler, G. J. (1974), “Law Enforcement, Malfeasance, and Compensation of Enforcers,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 3: 1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ben-Porath, Y. (1980), “The F-Connection: Families, Friends, and Firms and the Organization of Exchange,” Population and Development Review, Vol. 6 (1): 1–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and McLaren, J. (1993), “Taxes and Bribery: The Role of Wage Incentives,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 103: 119–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and Prat, A. (2006), “Handcuffs for the Grabbing Hand? Media Capture and Government Accountability,” American Economic Review, Vol. 96(3): 720–736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, J. N. (1982), “Directly Unproductive, Profit Seeking (DUP) Activities,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90: 998–1002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, J. N. and Srinivasan, T. N. (1980), “Revenue Seeking: A Generalization of the Theory of tariffs,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 87: 1069–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, J. N., R. A. Brecher, and T. N. Srinivasan (1984), “DUP activities and Economic Theory,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 17–32.Google Scholar
Björnskov, C. and M. Paldam (2004), “Corruption Trends,” The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, ed. by Lambsdorff, J. Graf, Schramm, M. and Taube, M.(London: Routledge): 59–75.Google Scholar
Borner, S. and C. Schwyzer (1999), “Bekämpfung der Bestechung im Lichte der Neuen Politischen Ökonomie,” Korruption im internationalen Geschäftsverkehr, Bestandsaufnahme, Bekämpfung, Prävention, ed. by Pieth, M. and Eigen, P. (Basel, Frankfurt am Main: Luchterhand): 17–39.Google Scholar
Boycko, M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1995), Privatizing Russia (Cambridge, MA and London: MIT Press).Google Scholar
Boyko, M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. (1996), “A Theory of Privatization,” Economic Journal, Vol. 106 (435): 309–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Braun, M. and Di Tella, R. (2000), “Inflation and Corruption,” Harvard Business School, Division of Research Working Paper00–053.Google Scholar
Bray, J. (1999), “Beyond Compliance: Corruption as a Business Risk,” Conference on Fighting Corruption in Developing Countries and Emerging Countries: The Role of the Private Sector, Organisation for Economic Co-operation (OECD) Development Centre, Washington, DC, February.
Bray, J. (2004), “The Use of Intermediaries and other ‘Alternatives’ to Bribery,” The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, ed. by Lambsdorff, J. Graf, Schramm, M., and Taube, M. (London: Routledge): 112–37.Google Scholar
Bray, J. (2006), International Business Attitudes to Corruption-Survey 2006. Report (London: Control Risks Group). Online version at www.control-risks.com/pdf/corruption_survey_2006_v3.pdf
Breton, A. and Wintrobe, R. (1975), “The Equilibrium Size of a Budget-maximizing Bureau: A Note on Niskanen's Theory of Bureaucracy (in Communications),” The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 83 (1): 195–208.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broadman, H. G. and Recanatini, F. (1999), “Seeds of Corruption – Do Market Institutions Matter?,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2368, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Brock, W. A. and Magee, St. P. (1978), “The Economics of Special Interest Politics: The Case of the Tariff,” The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 68: 246–50.Google Scholar
Brock, W. A. and St. P. Magee (1984), “The Invisible Foot and the Waste of Nations,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 177–86.Google Scholar
Browning, E. K. (1974), “On the Welfare Costs of Transfers,” Kyklos, Vol. 27: 374–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunetti, A. and Weder, B. (1998), “Investment and Institutional Uncertainty: A Comparative Study of Different Uncertainty Measures,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 134: 513–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunetti, A. and Weder, B. (2003), “A Free Press is Bad News for Corruption,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 87 (7–8): 1801–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunetti, A., G. Kisunko, and B. Weder (1997), “Institutional Obstacles for Doing Business. Data Description and Methodology of a Worldwide Private Sector Survey,” Background Paper for the World Development Report 1997, Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Brunetti, A., Kisunko, G., and Weder, B. (1998), “Credibility of Rules and Economic Growth: Evidence from a World Wide Private Sector Survey,” The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 12 (3): 353–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brunner, K. and Meckling, W. H. (1977), “The Perception of Man and the Conception of Government,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 9 (1): 70–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1980), “Rent-Seeking and Profit-Seeking,” Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, ed. by Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., and Tullock, G. (College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press): 3–15.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. (1993), “Public Choice after Socialism,” Public Choice, Vol. 72: 67–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J. M. and Tullock, G. (1962), The Calculus of Consent. Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bundeskriminalamt (2004), “Lagebild Korruption Bundesrepublik Deutschland 2003,” August. Online version at www.bka.de/lageberichte/ko/blkorruption2003.pdf, retreived July, 2005
Button, K. J. and Weyman-Jones, T. G. (1994), “X-Efficiency and Technical Efficiency,” Public Choice, Vol. 80: 83–104.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campos, J. E., Lien, D., and Pradhan, S. (1999), “The Impact of Corruption on Investment: Predictability Matters,” World Development, Vol. 27 (6): 1059–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cartier-Bresson, J. (1997), “The Economics of Corruption,” Democracy and Corruption in Europe, ed. by Porta, D. Della and Mény, Y. (London: Pinter): 148–65.Google Scholar
Center for the Study of Democracy (1998), “Relations between Citizens and Public Administration and Public Opinion on Corruption in Bulgaria,” Draft Paper, Sofia, Bulgaria.
Chang, E. and M. Golden (2004), “Electoral Systems, District Magnitude and Corruption,” mimeo, Departments of Political Science, Michigan State University and the University of California at Los Angeles, CA.
Choi, J. P. and Thum, M. (2005), “Corruption and the Shadow Economy,” International Economic Review, Vol. 46 (3): 817–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ciocchini, F., Durbin, E., and Ng, D. T. C. (2003), “Does Corruption Increase Emerging Market Bond Spreads?,” Journal of Economics and Business, Vol. 55: 503–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1937), “The Nature of the Firm,” Economica, Vol. 4: 386–405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colombo, G. (1995), “Korruption als Flächenbrand. Bekämpfungsstrategien in Italien,” Korruption in Deutschland – Ursachen, Erscheinungsformen, Bekämpfungsstrategien, (Berlin: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung): 37–44.Google Scholar
Congleton, R. (1980), “Competitive Process, Competitive Waste, and Institutions,” Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, ed. by Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., and Tullock, G. (College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press): 153–79.Google Scholar
Coolidge, J. and Rose-Ackerman, S. (1997), “High-Level Rent-Seeking and Corruption in African Regimes: Theory and Cases,” Policy Research Working Paper 1780, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Coronel, S. S. (2000), “The Jueteng Republic,” Investigating Estrada: Millions, Mansions and Mistresses, ed. by Coroner, Sheila S.(Manila: PCIJ) 26–36.
Crain, W. M. and Tollison, R. D. (1979), “The Executive Branch in an Interest-Group Perspective,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 8: 555–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Damania, R., Fredriksson, P. G., and Mani, M. (2004), The Persistence of Corruption and Regulatory Compliance Failures: Theory and Evidence,” Public Choice, Vol. 121: 363–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darroch, Fiona (2004), Lesotho – “A sheep or a springbock? The herd boy tackles Goliath,” commissioned case study, Anti-Corruption Strategies Programme, Three Strikes Against Graft, Assessing the Impact of Groundbreaking Corruption Cases in Lesotho, Mozambique and South Africa; The Implications for Countering Corruption in Southern Africa, 2004. www.iss.co.za/SEMINARS/2004/1503graft/lesotho.pdf
Davidson, S. (1999), “Okeahalam and Bah on Corruption: A Comment,” South African Journal of Economics, Vol. 67 (1) March: 157–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Soto, H. (1989), The Other Path (New York: Harper and Row).Google Scholar
della Porta, D. and Vanucci, A. (1999), Corrupt Exchanges, Actors, Resources and Mechanisms of Political Corruption (New York: de Gruyter).Google Scholar
Dick, A. R. (1995), “When does Organized Crime Pay? A Transaction Cost Analysis,” International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 15: 25–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Di Tella, R. and Schargrodsky, E., (2003) “The Role of Wages and Auditing during a Crackdown on Corruption in the City of Buenos Aires.” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 46(1): 269–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Djankov, S., Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (2002), “The Regulation of Entry,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117 (1): 1–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doh, J. and Teegen, H. (2003), “Private Telecommunications Investment in Emerging Economies – Comparing the Latin American and Asian Experience,” Management Research, Vol. 1 (1): 9–26.Google Scholar
Dollar, D., Fisman, R., and Gatti, R. (2001), “Are Women Really the ‘Fairer’ Sex? Corruption and Women in Government,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 46 (4): 423–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, A. (1957), An Economic Theory of Democracy (New York: Harper and Row).Google Scholar
Drew, E. (1983), Politics and Money. The New Road to Corruption (New York: Macmillan).Google Scholar
Dušek, L., A. Ortmann, and L. Lízal (2005), “Understanding Corruption and Corruptibility through Experiments: A Primer, Prague Economic Papers 2. University of Economics, Prague, Czech Republic.
Efron, B. and Tibshirani, R. (1993), An Introduction to the Bootstrap, New York and London: Chapman & Hall.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
EIRIS (2005), “Corporate Codes of Business Ethics: An International Survey of Bribery and Ethical Standards in Companies.” Publication of the Ethical Investment Research Services, London. Online version at www.eiris.org/files/research%20publications/corporatecodesofbusinessethicse p05. pdf, retrieved December 2006.
Elliott, K. A. (1997), “Corruption as an International Policy Problem: Overview and Recommendations,” Corruption and the Global Economy, ed. by Elliott, K. A. (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics): 175–233.Google Scholar
Esty, D. and M. Porter (2002), “National Environmental Performance Measurement and Determinants,” in ed. by Esty, D. and Cornelius, P., Environmental Performance Measurement: The Global Report 2001–2002, (New York: Oxford University Press): 24–43.Google Scholar
Evans, P. B. and Rauch, J. E. (2000), “Bureaucratic Structures and Economic Performance in Less Developed Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 75: 49–71.Google Scholar
Faccio, M. and D. C. Parsley (2006), “Sudden Deaths: Taking Stock of Political Connections,” ECGI – Finance Working Paper 113/2006.
Fikentscher, W. (1987), “Ersatz im Ausland gezahlter Bestechungsgelder,” Praxis des internationalen Privat– und Verfahrensrechts, (2): 86–90.Google Scholar
Findlay, R. and St. Wellisz (1984), “Toward a Model of Endogenous Rent-Seeking,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, Colander, D. C. (ed.) (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 89–100.Google Scholar
Fisman, R. and Gatti, R. (2002), “Decentralization and Corruption: Evidence Across Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 83 (3): 325–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fjeldstad, O. -H. and Tungodden, B. (2001), “Skatteunndragelse og korrupsjon i Tanzania. En studie av Tanzania Revenue Authority,” Den Ny Verden, Vol. 34 (3): 55–79.Google Scholar
Flowers, M. R. (1987), “Rent-Seeking and Rent Dissipation: A Critical View,” Cato Journal, Vol. 7: 431–40.Google Scholar
Fons, J. (1999), “Improving Transparency in Asian Banking Systems,” Internet Center for Corruption Research, Contribution No. 4. Online version at www.icgg.org/downloads/contribution04_fons.pdf
Foreign Policy (2001), “Measuring Globalization,” Foreign Policy. Online at www.foreignpolicy.com/story/cms.php?story_id=2493, accessed December 2006.
Friedman, E., S.Johnson, , Kaufmann, D., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (2000), “Dodging the Grabbing Hand: The Determinants of Unofficial Activity in 69 Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 76: 459–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, M. (1970), “The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits,” New York Times Magazine, September 13. Reprint, L. P. Hartmann, Business Ethics (Chicago, IL: Irwin/McGraw-Hill): 246–51.
Frisch, D. (1999), “Entwicklungspolitische Gesichtspunkte der Korruption,” Korruption im internationalen Geschäftsverkehr: Bestandsaufnahme, Bekämpfung, Prävention, ed. by Pieth, M. and Eigen, P. (Basel, Frankfurt am Main: Luchterhand): 89–100.Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. G. and Richter, R. (1998), Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of New Institutional Economics (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press).Google Scholar
Galeotti, G. and A. Merlo (1994), “Political Collusion and Corruption in a Representative Democracy,” Unpublished manuscript. Universita'di Roma “La Sapienza” and University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, MN.
Galtung, F. (1999), “BPI Framework Document,” Transparency International Background Paper. Online version at www.transparency.org/cpi/1999/bpi_framework.html, retrieved March, 2004.
Gambetta, D. (1998), “Comment on ‘Corruption and Development,’ by Susan Rose-Ackerman,” Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics 1997, ed. by. Pleskovic, B. and Stiglitz, J. E. (Washington D.C.: The World Bank): 58–61.Google Scholar
Gardiner, J. A. and Olson, D. J. (1974), Theft of the City (Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press).Google Scholar
Gastil, R. D. (1986), Freedom in the World. Political Rights and Civil Liberties 1985–86 (New York: Greenwood Press).Google Scholar
Gatti, R. (1999), “Corruption and Trade Tariffs, or a Case for Uniform Tariffs,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2216.
Gerring, J. and Thacker, S. (2004), “Political Institutions and Governance: Pluralism versus Centralism,” British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 34 (2): 295–3.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerring, J. and Thacker, S. (2005), “Do Neoliberal Policies Deter Political Corruption?,” International Organization, Vol. 59: 233–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghura, D. (2002), “Tax Revenue in Sub-Saharan Africa: Effects of Economic Policies and Corruption,” Governance, Corruption & Economic Performance, ed. by Abed, G. T. and Gupta, S., Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, 369–95.Google Scholar
Githongo, J. (1997), “Independency, Investigation and Denunciation of Corruption from the Press – The Case of Kenya,” 8th International Anti-Corruption Conference, Lima, Peru, September.
Glaeser, E. and Saks, R. E. (2006), “Corruption in America,” Journal of Public Economics Vol. 90(6–7): 1053–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goel, R. K. and Nelson, M. A. (1998), “Corruption and Government Size: A Disaggregated Analysis,” Public Choice, Vol. 97 (1): 107–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goel, R. K. and Nelson, M. A. (2005), “Economic Freedom versus Political Freedom: Cross-Country Influences on Corruption,” Australian Economic Papers, Vol. 44: 121–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goetz, C. J. and Scott, R. E. (1981), “Principles of Relational Contracts,” Virginia Law Review, Vol. 67: 1089–150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldsmith, A. A. (1999), “Slapping the Grasping Hand: Correlates of Political Corruption in Emerging Markets,” The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 58 (4): 866–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Graeff, P. and Mehlkop, G. (2003), “The Impact of Economic Freedom on Corruption: Different Patterns for Rich and Poor Countries,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 19: 605–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granovetter, M. (1992), “Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness,” The Sociology of Economic Life, ed. by Granovetter, M. and Swedberg, R. (Boulder, CO: Westview Press): 53–81.Google Scholar
Grossman, H. I. (1995), “Rival Kleptocrats: The Mafia versus the State,” The Economics of Organized Crime, ed. by Fiorentini, G. and Peltzman, S. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press): 143–56.Google Scholar
Gupta, M. R. and Chaudhuri, S. (1997), “Formal Credit, Corruption and the Informal Credit Market in Agriculture: A Theoretical Analysis,” Economica, 64: 331–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, S., Mello, L., and Sharan, R. (2001a), “Corruption and Military Spending,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 17 (4): 749–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, S., H. Davoodi, and E. R. Tiongson (2001b), “Corruption and the Provision of Health Care and Education Services,” The Political Economy of Corruption, ed. by Jain, A. K. (London: Routledge): 111–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gupta, S., Davoodi, H., and Alonso-Terme, R. (2002), “Does Corruption Affect Income Inequality and Poverty?,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 3: 23–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gylfason, T. (2001), “Nature, Power and Growth,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 48: 558–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gymiah-Brempong, K. (2002), “Corruption, Economic Growth, and Income Inequality in Africa,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 3: 183–209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gwartney, J. and Lawson, R. (2000), “Economic Freedom of the World: 2000 Annual Report,” (Vancouver, BC): Fraser Institute.Google Scholar
Habib, M. and Zurawicki, L. (2001), “Country-Level Investments and the Effect of Corruption: Some Empirical Evidence,” International Business Review, Vol. 10 (6): 687–700.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Habib, M. and Zurawicki, L. (2002), “Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment,” Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 33 (2): 291–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, R. and Jones, C. (1999), “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker than Others,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114: 83–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, T. and G. Yago (2000), “Estimating the Cost of Opacity Using Sovereign Bond Spreads,” unpublished manuscript, Milken Institute, Santa Monica, CA.
Harden, B. (1993), Africa. Dispatches from a Fragile Continent (London: Harper Collins Publishers, paperback edition).Google Scholar
Hart, A. G. (1970), “Fiscal Policy in Latin America,” Part 2: Key Problems of Economic Policy in Latin America, The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 78 (4): 857–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, O. D. (1987), “Incomplete Contracts,” The New Palgrave-Allocation, Information and Markets, Vol. 2, ed. by Eatwell, J., Milgate, M., and Newman, P., (London: Macmillan): 752–9.Google Scholar
Hart, O. D. (1991), “Incomplete Contracts and the Theory of the Firm,” The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development, ed. by Williamson, O. D. and Winter, S. G. (New York: Oxford University Press): 138–58.Google Scholar
Hasker, K. and C. Okten (2004), Intermediaries and Corruption, unpublished working paper, Ankara, Turkey: Bilkent University. Forthcoming in Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization.
Heidenheimer, A., Johnston, M. and LeVine, V. (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook, 2nd ed. (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers).Google Scholar
Henderson, D. R. (1999), “Power Corrupts – Editorial Comment,” The Wall Street Journal, April 19.Google Scholar
Henisz, W. (2000), “The institutional environment for multinational investment,” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 16 (2): 334–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hepkema, S. and Booysen, W. (1997), “The Bribery of Public Officials: An IBA Survey,” International Business Lawyer, Vol. 25 (9): 415–16, 422.Google Scholar
Herrera, A. and P. Rodriguez (2003), “Bribery and the Nature of Corruption,”unpublished manuscript, Michigan State University, East Lansing, MI and The Darden School, University of Virginia, Charlottesville, VA, July.
Herzfeld, T. and Weiss, C. (2003), “Corruption and legal (in)effectiveness: an empirical investigation,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 19: 621–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heymann, P. B. (1995), “Korruption in den USA. Rechtliche, wirtschaftliche und ethische Aspekte,” Korruption in Deutschland – Ursachen, Erscheinungsformen, Bekämpfungsstrategien, (Berlin: Friedrich Ebert Stiftung): 49–56.Google Scholar
Hillman, A. L. and Katz, E. (1984), “Risk Averse Rent Seekers and the Social Cost of Monopoly Power,” Economic Journal, Vol. 94: 104–10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hines, J. R. (1995), “Forbidden Payment: Foreign Bribery and American Business after 1977,” NBER Working Paper 5266, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. (1976), “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation: Comment,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 19: 241–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hofstede, G. (1997), Cultures and Organizations: Software of the Mind (New York: McGraw Hill).Google Scholar
Huntington, S. P. (1968), “Modernization and Corruption,” Political Order in Changing Societies (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press): 59–71. Reprinted in A. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, and V. LeVine (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers): 377–88.Google Scholar
Husted, B. (1999), “Wealth, Culture, and Corruption,” Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 30 (2): 339–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Husted, B. W. (1994), “Honor Among Thieves: A Transaction-Cost Interpretation of Corruption in Third World Countries,” Business Ethics Quarterly, Vol. 4: 17–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huther, J. and A. Shah, (1998), “A Simple Measure of Good Governance and its Application to the Debate on the Appropriate Level of Fiscal Decentralization,” World Bank Working Paper, 1894, Washington, DC.
Hwang, J. (2002), “A Note on the Relationship between Corruption and Government,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 27 (2): 161–77.Google Scholar
Isham, J. and Kaufmann, D. (1999), “The Forgotten Rationale for Policy Reform: The Productivity of Investment Projects,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114: 149–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jagannathan, N. V. (1986), “Corruption, Delivery Systems, and Property Rights,” World Development, Vol. 14: 127–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jain, A. K. (1998), “Models of Corruption,” Economics of Corruption, ed. by Jain, A. K. (Boston, London, and Dordrecht): 13–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jarvin, S. (1986), “Aus der Praxis des ICC Schiedgerichtshofes,” Recht und Praxis der Schiedsgerichtsbarkeit der Internationalen Handelskammer. Schriftenreihe des Deutschen Instituts für Schiedsgerichtsverfahren, ed. by Böckstiegel, K. -H. (Köln: Heymann): 7–51.Google Scholar
Johnson, S., Kaufmann, D., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1998), “Regulatory Discretion and the Unofficial Economy,” The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 88: 387–92.Google Scholar
Kapstein, E. (2001), “Five Basic Principles for a Worldwide Code of Business Ethics,” International Herald Tribune, January 24.Google Scholar
Kargl, W. (2002), “Über die Bekämpfung des Anscheins der Kriminalität bei der Vorteilsannahme (§ 331 StGB),” Zeitschrift für die gesamte Strafrechtswissenschaft (ZStW), Vol. 114 (4): 763–81.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D. and Wei, S. -J. (1999), “Does ‘Grease Money’ Speed up the Wheels of Commerce?,” NBER Working Paper 7093, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1999a), “Aggregating Governance Indicators,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2195, Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Zoido-Lobaton, P. (1999b), “Governance Matters,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 2196, October, Washington, DC: The World Bank.Google Scholar
Khalil, F. and Lawarree, J. (1995), “Collusive Auditors,” The American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 85 (2): 442–6.Google Scholar
Klein, B. (1996), “Why Hold-Ups Occur: The Self-Enforcing Range of Contractual Relationships,” Economic Inquiry, Vol. 34: 444–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., and Alchian, A. A. (1978), “Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 21: 297–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kleinschmidt, P., H. Achatz, and J. Graf Lambsdorff (2005), “The Corruption Perceptions Index and the Linear Ordering Problem,” presented at the Annual International Conference of the German Operations Research Society (GOR), September 9, 2005.
Klitgaard, R. (1988), Controlling Corruption (Berkeley, CA: University of California Press).Google Scholar
Knack, S. and Azfar, O. (2003), “Trade Intensity, Country Size and Corruption,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 4 (1): 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, S. and Keefer, P. (1995), “Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 7: 207–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knapp, W. (1986), “Sittenwidrige Vermittlung von Regierungsaufträgen durch Bestechungsgelder,” RIW – Recht der Internationalen Wirtschaft: 999–1001.Google Scholar
Kofman, F. and Lawarree, J. (1996), “On the Optimality of Allowing Collusion,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 61: 383–407.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kranton, R. E. (1996), “Reciprocal Exchange: A Self-Sustaining System,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 86 (4): 830–51.Google Scholar
Kreps, D. M. (1990), “Corporate Culture and Economic Theory,” Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. by Alt, J. and Shepsle, K. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press): 90–143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kreps, D. M. and Wilson, R. (1982), “Reputation and Imperfect Information,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 27: 253–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, A. (1974), “The Political Economy of the Rent Seeking Society,” American Economic Review, Vol. 64: 291–303.Google Scholar
Krueger, A. (1990), “Government Failures in Development,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 4: 9–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kunicova, J. (2005), “Are Presidential Systems More Susceptible to Political Corruption?,” mimeo, Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Kunicova, J. (2002), “When Are Opposition's Lips Sealed? Comparative Political Corruption in Democracies,” mimeo, Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Kunicova, J. and Rose-Ackerman, S. (2005), “Electoral Rules and Constitutional Structures as Constraints on Corruption,” British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 35 (4): 573–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1997), “Trust in Large Organizations,” The American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 137 (2): 333–8.Google Scholar
Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1999), “The Quality of Government,” The Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, Vol. 15 (1): 222–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, J. -J. and Tirole, J. (1993), A Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press).Google Scholar
Lambert-Mogiliansky, A. (2002), “Why Firms Pay Occasional Bribes: The Connection Economy,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 18: 47–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (1998a), “An Empirical Investigation of Bribery in International Trade,” European Journal for Development Research, Vol. 10: 40–59. Reprinted in Corruption and Development, ed. by M. Robinson (London: Frank Cass Publishers): 40–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (1999), “Korruption im internationalen Geschäftsverkehr. Bestandsaufnahme, Bekämpfung, Prävention,” Korruption als mühseliges Geschäft –eine Transaktionskostenanalyse, ed. by Pieth, M. and Eigen, P. (Basel, Frankfurt am Main: Luchterhand): 56–88.Google Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2000), “De la propension des exportateurs à verser des pots-de-vin –l'impact sur les échanges,” Revue Tiers Monde, Vol. 41 (161): 89–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2002a), “Making Corrupt Deals – Contracting in the Shadow of Law,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 48 (3): 221–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2002b), “Corruption and Rent-Seeking,” Public Choice, Vol. 113 (1/2): 97–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2002c), “How Confidence facilitates illegal Transactions,” American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 61 (4): 829–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2003a), “How Corruption Affects Productivity,” Kyklos, Vol. 56 (4): 459–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2003b), “How Corruption Affects Persistent Capital Flows,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 4 (3): 229–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2005a), “Between Two Evils – Investors Prefer Grand Corruption!,” University of Passau, Discussion Paper V-31–05, January.
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2005b), “Determining Trends for Perceived Levels of Corruption,” Passau University, Discussion Paper V-38–06.
Lambsdorff, J. Graf (2006), “Ten Years of the CPI: Determining trends,” Global Corruption Report 2006, Transparency International.
Lambsdorff, J. Graf and M. Nell (2005), “Let Them Take Gifts, and Cheat Those Who Seek Influence,” Economics Faculty of Passau University, Discussion Paper 41–05, December 2005.
Lambsdorff, J. Graf and P. Cornelius (2000), “Corruption, Foreign Investment and Growth,” The Africa Competitiveness Report 2000/2001, ed. by Schwab, K., Cook, L., Cornelius, P., Sachs, J. D., Sievers, S., and Warner, A. joint publication of the World Economic Forum and the Institute for International Development, (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University and Oxford: Oxford University Press: 70–78.Google Scholar
Lambsdorff, J.Graf, M. Schramm, and Taube, M. (2004), The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, (London: Routledge).Google Scholar
Landes, W. M. and Posner, R. A. (1975), “The Independent Judiciary in an Interest-Group Perspective,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 18: 875–901.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LaPalombara, J. (1994), “Structural and Institutional Aspects of Corruption,” Social Research, Vol. 61: 325–50.Google Scholar
Lederman, D., N. Loayza, and R. Reis Soares (2001), “Accountability and Corruption. Political Institutions Matter,” The World Bank Working Paper 2708.
Lee, C. M. and D. Ng (2004), “Corruption and International Valuation. Does Virtue Pay?,” unpublished manuscript, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.
Leff, N. H. (1964), “Economic Development Through Bureaucratic Corruption,” American Behavioral Scientist, Vol. 8 (3): 8–14. Reprinted in A. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, and V. LeVine (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers) 389–403.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leite, C. and Weidemann, J. (1999), “Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption, and Economic Growth,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper 99/85, July.Google Scholar
Li, H., Xu, L. C., and Zou, H. -F. (2000), “Corruption, Income Distribution, and Growth,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 12 (2): 155–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lien, D. H. D. (1986), “A Note on Competitive Bribery Games,” Economics Letters, Vol. 22: 337–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindstedt, C. and D. Naurin (2005), “Transparency and Corruption. A Cross-Country Study of the Significance of a Free Press,” paper prepared for the 3rd ECPR Conference, The Quality of Democracy, Budapest, September.
Lipset, S. M. and G. S. Lenz (2000), “Corruption, Culture, and Markets,” In Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress, ed. by Harrison, L. E. and Huntington, S. P. (New York: Basic Books): 112–24.Google Scholar
Lui, F. T. (1985), “An Equilibrium Queuing Model of Bribery,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 93: 760–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
MacGuire, M. C. and Olson, M. (1996), “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule: The Invisible Hand and the Use of Force,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 34: 72–96.Google Scholar
Macneil, I. R. (1974), “The Many Futures of Contracts,” Southern California Law Review, Vol. 47: 691–816.Google Scholar
Macneil, I. R. (1978), “Contracts: Adjustment of Long Term Economic Relations under Classical, Neoclassical and Relational Contract Law,” Northwestern University Law Review, Vol. 72: 854–905.Google Scholar
Magee, St. P. (1984), “Endogenous Tariff Theory,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 41–54.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. G. (2000), Principles of Economics, 2nd ed. (Fort Worth, TX, Harcourt College Publishers).Google Scholar
Manow, P. (2005), “Politische Korruption und politischer Wettbewerb: Probleme der quantitativen Analyse,” Dimensionen politischer Korruption, ed. by U. von Alemann, PVS – Politische Vierteljahresschrift, VS – Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften: Wiesbaden, Sonderheft 35: 249–66.CrossRef
Marcoullier, D. and Young, L. (1995), “The Black Hole of Graft: The Predatory State and the Informal Economy,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 85 (3): 630–46.Google Scholar
Marshall, A. (1897), “The Old Generation of Economists and the New,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 11 (2): 115–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mauro, P. (1995), “Corruption and Growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110 (3): 681–712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mauro, P. (1997a), “The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment, and Government Expenditure: A Cross-Country Analysis,” Corruption and the Global Economy, ed. by Elliott, K. (Washington, DC: Institute for International Economics): 83–107.Google Scholar
Mauro, P. (1997b), “Why Worry about Corruption?,” Economic Issues No. 6 (Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund).Google Scholar
Mauro, P. (1998), “Corruption and the Composition of Government Expenditure,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 69: 263–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mbaku, J. M. (1992), “Bureaucratic Corruption as Rent-Seeking Behavior,” Konjunkturpolitik, Vol. 38: 247–65.Google Scholar
Mbaku, J. M. (1998), “Corruption and Rent-Seeking,” The Political Dimension of Economic Growth, ed. by Borner, S. and Paldam, M. (London and New York: Macmillan Press and St. Martins Press): 193–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McChesney, F. S. (1987), “Rent Extraction and Rent Creation in the Economic Theory of Regulation,” Journal of Legal Studies, Vol. 16: 101–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McChesney, F. S. (1997), Money for Nothing. Politicians, Rent Extraction, and Political Extortion (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
McGuire, M. C. and Olson, M. (1996), “The Economics of Autocracy and Majority Rule: The Invisible Hand and the Use of Force,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 34: 72–96.Google Scholar
Méon, P. -G. and Sekkat, K. (2004), “Does the Quality of Institutions Limit the MENA's Integration in the World Economy?,” The World Economy, Vol. 27 (9): 1475–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Méon, P. -G. and Sekkat, K. (2005), “Does Corruption Grease or Sand the Wheels of Growth?,” Public Choice, Vol. 122: 69–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miller, W. L., Grødeland, Å, and Koshechkina, T. Y. (2001), A Culture of Corruption – Coping with Government in Post-communist Europe (Budapest: Central European University Press).Google Scholar
Mo, P. H. (2001), “Corruption and Economic Growth,” Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 29: 66–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mocan, N. (2004), “What Determines Corruption? International Evidence from Micro Data,” NBER Working Paper 10460.
Moe, T. M. (1984), “The New Economics of Organization,” American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 28 (4): 739–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montinola, G. and Jackman, R. W. (2002), “Sources of Corruption: A Cross-Country Study,” British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 32: 147–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moody-Stuart, G. (1994), “Grand Corruption in Third World Development,” Transparency International (TI) Working Paper, Berlin: Transparency International.Google Scholar
Moody-Stuart, George (1997), Grand Corruption. How Business Bribes Damage Developing Countries (Oxford, UK: WorldView Publishing).Google Scholar
Mookherjee, D. and Png, I. P. L. (1995), “Corruptible Law Enforcers: How should they be compensated?,”The Economic Journal, Vol. 105: 145–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moran, Th. (2006), “How Multinational Investors Evade Developed Country Laws,” Center for Global Development Working Paper 79. online version at www.cgdev.org/content/publications/detail/6113
Morgan, Th. (1964), “The Theory of Error in Centrally-Directed Economic Systems,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 78 (3): 395–419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moselle, B. and Polak, B. (2001), “A Model of a Predatory State,” Journal of Law Economics and Organization, Vol. 17 (1): 1–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1993), “Why is Rent-Seeking so Costly to Growth?,”The American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 82 (2): 409–14.Google Scholar
Myrdal, G. (1956), An International Economy (New York: Harper and Bros.).Google Scholar
Myrdal, G. (1968), Asian Drama. Vol. II (New York: Random House).Google Scholar
Neeman, Z., Paserman, M., and Simhon, A. (2003), “Corruption and Openness,” CEPR Discussion Paper 4057. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research.Google Scholar
Nelson, W. and Winter, S. G. (1982), An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change (Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Neugebauer, G. (1978), Grundzüge einer ökonomischen Theorie der Korruption. Eine Studie über die Bestechung. Basler sozialökonomische Studien (Zürich: Schulthess Polygraphischer Verlag).Google Scholar
Niskanen, W. (1971), Bureaucracy and Representative Government (Chicago, IL: Aldine Press).Google Scholar
Niskanen, W. (1975), “Bureaucrats and Politicians,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 18: 617–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History (New York and London: Norton).Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1984), “Three Approaches to the Study of Institutions,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 33–40.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1993), “Institutions and Credible Commitment,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol. 149: 11–23.Google Scholar
North, D. C. and Weingast, B. R. (1989), “The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 49: 803–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nye, J. S. (1967), “Corruption and Political Development: A Cost Benefit Analysis,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 61 (2): 417–27. Reprinted in A. Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, and V. LeVine (1989), Political Corruption – A Handbook (New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers): 963–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
OECD (2003), Business Approaches to Combating Corrupt Practices, Study prepared by the Capital Movements, International Investment and Services Division, OECD Directorate for Financial, Fiscal and Enterprise Affairs, September.
Okeahalam, C. C. and Bah, I. (1998), “Perceived Corruption and Investment in Sub-Saharan African,” South African Journal of Economics, Vol. 67 (1), March: 386.Google Scholar
Oldenburg, P. (1987), “Middlemen in Third-World Corruption: Implications of an Indian Case,” World Politics, Vol. 39: 508–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olsen, T. and Torsvik, G. (1998), “Collusion and Renegotiation in Hierarchies: A Case of Beneficial Corruption,” International Economic Review, Vol. 39 (2), May: 413–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olson, M. (1965), The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press).Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1982), The Rise and Decline of Nations (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press).Google Scholar
Orchard, L. and Stretton, H. (1997), “Public Choice,” Cambridge Journal of Economics, Vol. 21 (3): 409–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M. (2001), “Corruption and Religion. Adding to the Economic Model,” Kyklos, Vol. 54 (2/3): 383–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paldam, M. (2002), “The Big Pattern of Corruption. Economics, Culture and the Seesaw Dynamics,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 18: 215–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Panizza, U. (2001), “Electoral Rules, Political Systems, and Institutional Quality,” Economics and Politics, Vol. 13 (3): 311–42.Google Scholar
Pechlivanos, L. (1998), “Self-Enforcing Corruption and Optimal Deterrence,” unpublished manuscript, Université des Sciences Sociales, Toulouse, France.
Pechlivanos, L. (2004), “Self-Enforcing Corruption: Information Transmission and Organizational Response,” The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, ed. by Lambsdorff, J. Graf, Schramm, M., and Taube, M.London: Routledge: 93–111.Google Scholar
Pellegrini, L. and Gerlagh, R. (2004), “Corruption's Effect on Growth and its Transmission Channels,” Kyklos, Vol. 57 (3): 429–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pellegrini, L. and S. Vujic (2003), “Corruption, Economic Development and Environmental Policy,” Political Economy of the Environment, Institute for Environmental Studies, IVM, Working Paper, the Netherlands.
Peltzman, S. (1976), “Towards a More General Theory of Regulation,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 20: 322–40.Google Scholar
Peltzman, S. (1989), “The Economic Theory of Regulation after a Decade of Deregulation,” Brooking Papers of Economic Activity: Microeconomics, ed. by Baily, M. N. and Winston, C. (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution): 1–41.Google Scholar
Persson, T., Tabellini, G., and Trebbi, F. (2003), “Electoral Rules and Corruption,” Journal of the European Economic Association, Vol. 1 (4): 958–89, formerly published in: NBER Working Paper 8154, March 2001.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poirson, H. (1998), “Economic Security, Private Investment, and Growth in Developing Countries,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper 98/4, January.
Pope, J. (2000), The Transparency International Source Book 2000 – Confronting Corruption: The Elements of a National Integrity System (Berlin: Transparency International). Online version at www.transparency.org/sourcebook/, retrieved December 2006.
Posner, R. A. (1974), “Theories of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management, Vol. 5 (2): 335–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, R. A. (1975), “The Social Cost of Monopoly and Regulation,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 83: 807–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pritzl, R. F. J. (1995), “La Corrupción pública: una forma dinámica e ilegal de rentismo o rent-seeking en la lucha distributiva de los grupos de interés organizados,” Corrupción. Contribuciones. Publication Trimestral 4 (Buenos Aires: Konrad Adenauer Stiftung and CIEDLA).
Pryor, F. L. (1984), “Rent-Seeking and the Growth and Fluctuations of Nations. Empirical Tests of Some Recent Hypothesis,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colande, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 155–75.Google Scholar
Putnam, R. D. (1993), Making Democracy Work. Civic Traditions in Modern Italy (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press).Google Scholar
Rasmusen, E. and Ramseyer, J. M. (1994), “Cheap Bribes and the Corruption Ban: A Coordination Game among Rational Legislators,” Public Choice, Vol. 74: 305–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robertson, C. J. and Watson, A. (2004), “Corruption and Change: The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment,” Strategic Management Journal, Vol. 25 (4): 385–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rock, M. T. and Bonnett, H. (2004), “The comparative politics of corruption: Accounting for the East Asian paradox in empirical studies of corruption growth and investment,” World Development, 32 (6): 999–1017.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Root, H. (1999), “The Importance of Being Small,” Center for International Studies Working Paper 99–13, Los Angeles, CA: University of Southern California.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1975), “The Economics of Corruption,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 4: 187–203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1978), Corruption – A Study in Political Economy (New Haven, CT: Academic Press).Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. (1998), “The Role of the World Bank in Controlling Corruption,” Law and Policy in International Business, Vol. 29: 93–114.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (1999), Corruption and Government. Causes, Consequences and Reform (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, Susan (2005), From Elections to Democracy. Building Accountable Government in Hungary and Poland (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sachs, J. and Warner, A. (1995), “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 25 (1): 1–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandholtz, W. and Gray, M. (2003), “International Integration and National Corruption,” International Organization, Vol. 57 (4): 761–800.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandholtz, W. and Koetzle, W. (2000), “Accounting for Corruption: Economic Structure, Democracy, and Trade,” Industrial Studies Quarterly, Vol. 44: 31–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandholtz, W. and Taagepera, R. (2005), “Corruption, Culture, and Communism,” International Review of Sociology, Vol. 15 (1): 109–131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sayed, A. (2004): Corruption in International Trade and Commercial Arbitration (The Hague.: Kluwer Law International).Google Scholar
Schrag, J. and Scotchmer, S. (1997), “The Self-Reinforcing Nature of Crime,” International Review of Law and Economics, Vol. 17: 325–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schramm, M. and M. Taube (2003), “The Institutional Economics of Legal Institutions, Guanxi, and Corruption in the PR China,” Fighting Corruption in Asia. Causes, Effects and Remedies ed. by Kidd, J. and Richter, J., New Jersey, London, Singapore, and Hong Kong): 271–96.Google Scholar
Schulze, G. and Frank, B. (2003), “Deterrence versus Intrinsic Motivation: Experimental Evidence on the Determinants of Corruptibility,” Economics of Governance, Vol. 4 (2): 143–60.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy (New York: Harper & Bros.).Google Scholar
Scott, J. C. (1972), Comparative Political Corruption (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall).Google Scholar
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. W. (1993), “Corruption,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108: 599–617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. W. (1998), The Grabbing Hand – Government Pathologies and their Cures. Cambridge, MA: (Harvard University Press): 1–17.Google Scholar
Shugart, M. S. (1999), “Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and the Provision of Collective Goods in Less-Developed Countries,” Constitutional Political Economy, Vol. 10: 53–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smarzynska, B. K. and Wei, S. (2000), “Corruption and the Composition of Foreign Direct Investment: Firm-Level Evidence,” World Bank Discussion Paper 2360, Washington, DC: World Bank.Google Scholar
Smith, R. J., Muir, R. D. J., Walpole, M. J., Balmford, A. and Leader-Williams, N. (2003), “Governance and the loss of biodiversity,” Nature, Vol. 426: 67–70.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Soskice, D. (1999), “Divergent Production Regimes: Coordinated and Uncoordinated Market Economies in the 1990s,” Continuity and Change in Contemporary Capitalism, ed. by Kitschelt, H., Lange, P., Marks, G., and Stephens, J. (New York: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stansbury, N. (2004), Anti-corruption Initiative in the Construction and Engineering Industry, Report Five: The Prevention of Bribery Through Agency Commissions, Transparency International (UK).
Stigler, G. J. (1971), “The Theory of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, Vol. 2: 3–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stiglitz, J. (1998a), “Redefining the Role of the State – What Should it do? How Should it do it? And How Should these Decisions be Made?,” Paper presented on the Tenth Anniversary of MITI Research Institute, Tokyo. Online version at www.worldbank.org/html/extdr/extme/redefine.pdf, retrieved December 2006.
Stiglitz, J. (1998b), “Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: The Private Uses of Public Interests: Incentives and Institutions,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 12 (2): 3–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stratmann, T. (2003), “Do Strict Electoral Campaign Finance Rules Limit Corruption?,” CESifo DICE Report 1: 24–27.
Straub, S. (2003), “Opportunism, Corruption and the Multinational Firm's Mode of Entry,” Edinburgh School of Economics, Discussion Paper 102.
Strausz, R. (1995), “Collusion and Renegotiation in a Principal – Supervisior – Agent Relationship,” Center for Economic Research, Discussion Paper 9548, Netherlands: Tilburg University.Google Scholar
Sung, H. -E. (2002), “A Convergence Approach to the Analysis of Political Corruption: A Cross-National Study,” Crime, Law and Social Change, Vol. 38 (2): 137–160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sung, H. -E. (2003), “Fairer Sex or Fairer System? Gender and Corruption Revisited,” Social Forces, Vol. 82 (2): 703–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sung, H. -E. (2004), “Democracy and Political Corruption: A Cross-National Comparison,” Crime, Law and Social Change, Vol. 41 (2): 179–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sung, H. -E. and Chu, D. (2003), “Does Participation in the Global Economy Reduce Political Corruption? An Empirical Inquiry,” International Journal of Comparative Criminology, Vol. 3 (2): 94–118.Google Scholar
Svensson, J. (2003), “Who Must Pay Bribes and How Much? Evidence from a Cross Section of Firms,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 118 (1): 207–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, J. (2005), “Eight Questions about Corruption,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 19 (3): 19–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swamy, A., Knack, St., Lee, Y., and Azfar, O. (2001), “Gender and Corruption,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 64: 25–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tanzi, V. (1995), “Corruption: Arm's–length Relationships and Markets,” The Economics of Organized Crime, ed. by Fiorentini, G. and Peltzman, S. (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press): 161–180.Google Scholar
Tanzi, V. and H. Davoodi (1997), “Corruption, Public Investment, and Growth,” International Monetary Fund Working Paper 97/139.
Tanzi, V. and H. Davoodi (2001), “Corruption, Growth, and Public Finances,” Political Economy of Corruption, ed. by Jain, A. K. (London: Routledge): 89–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tavares, S. (2005), “Does Rapid Trade Liberalization Increase Corruption?,” paper presented at the European Public Choice Society Conference 2005.
Tellenbach, S. (1997), “Türkei,” Korruptionsbekämpfung durch Strafrecht, ed. by Eser, A., Überhofen, M., and Huber, B.. Freiburg, Germany: Max-Planck-Institut für ausländisches und internationales Strafrecht.Google Scholar
Testa, C. (2003), “Government Corruption and Legislative Procedures: Is One Chamber Better than Two?,” mimeo, Royal Holloway College, University of London.Google Scholar
Thompson, D. F. (1993), “Mediated Corruption: The Case of the Keating Five,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 87: 369–381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tollison, R. D. (1982), “Rent Seeking: A Survey,” Kyklos, Vol. 35: 575–602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tonoyan, V. (2004), “The Bright and Dark Sides of Trust: Corruption and Entrepreneurship,” Trust and Entrepreneurship: A West-East-Perspective, ed. by H. Höhmann and F. Welter (Cheltenham: Edward Elgar). Online version at: www.icgg.org/downloads/contribution11_tonoyan.pdf
Transparency International, (1999), Newsletter. Berlin: Transparency International, September.
Treisman, D. (1999), “Decentralization and Corruption: Why are Federal States Perceived to be More Corrupt,” paper prepared for the presentation at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Atlanta, September.
Treisman, D. (2000), “The Causes of Corruption: A Cross-National Study,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 76: 399–457.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. (1967), “The Welfare Costs of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft,” Western Economic Journal, Vol. 5 (3): 224–32.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1971), “The Cost of Transfers,” Kyklos, Vol. 24: 629–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. (1975), “Competing for Aid,” Public Choice, Vol. 21: 41–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tullock, G. (1980a), “Rent Seeking as a Negative-Sum Game,” Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, ed. by Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., and Tullock, G. (College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press): 16–36.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1980b), “Efficient Rent Seeking,” Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society, ed. by Buchanan, J. M., Tollison, R. D., and Tullock, G. (College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press): 97–112.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1989), “Klitgaard, Robert, Controlling Corruption,” The Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 27: 658–9.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. (1993), Rent Seeking, The Shaftesbury Papers 2, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Uhlenbruck, K., P. Rodriguez, J. Doh, and L. Eden (2006), “The Impact of Corruption on Entry Strategy: Evidence from Telecommunication Projects in Emerging Economies,” Organization Science, Vol. 17(3): 402–14.CrossRef
United Nations (2006), “Seventh United Nations Survey of Crime Trends and Operations of Criminal Justice Systems, covering the period 1998–2000” Report by the United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime. Retrieved in December 2006 from: www.unodc.org/unodc/crime_cicp_survey_ seventh.html
Uslaner, E. (2004), “Trust and Corruption,” The New Institutional Economics of Corruption – Norms, Trust, and Reciprocity, ed. by Lambsdorff, J. Graf, Schramm, M., and Taube, M. (London: Routledge): 76–92.Google Scholar
Rijckeghem, C. and Weder, B. (2001), “Bureaucratic Corruption and the Rate of Temptation: Do Wages in the Civil Service affect Corruption, and by How Much?,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 65 (2): 307–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vanucci, A. (2000), “Corruption, Political Parties and Political Protection,” European University Institute Economics Department, Working Paper 62, Badia Fiesolana: San Domenico.
Voigt, S., Feld, L., and Aaken, A. (2004), “Power over Prosecutors Corrupts Politicians: Cross Country Evidence Using a New Indicator,” Draft Version, Economics Faculty, University of Kassel, Germany.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1920), Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Religionssoziologie (Tübingen, Germany: Mohr & Siebeck). Reprinted 1988.Google Scholar
Wedeman, A. (1997), “Looters, Rent-scrapers, and Dividend–Collectors: Corruption and Growth in Zaire, South Korea, and the Philippines,” The Journal of Developing Areas, Vol. 31: 457–78.Google Scholar
Wei, S. -J. (1997), “Why is Corruption so Much More Taxing than Tax? Arbitrariness Kills,” NBER Working Paper 6255, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Wei, S. -J. (2000a), “Natural Openness and Good Government,” World Bank Poliy Research Working Paper 2411 and NBER Working Paper 7765.
Wei, S. -J. (2000b), “How Taxing is Corruption on International Investors,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 82 (1): 1–11.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wei, S. -J. (2000c), “Corruption, Composition of Capital Flows, and Currency Crises,” World Bank Working Paper 2429.
Wei, S. -J. and Sievers, S. (1999), “The Cost of Crony Capitalism,” The Asian Competitiveness Report 1999. Geneva: World Economic Forum, 50–55.Google Scholar
Wei, S. -J. and Y. Wu (2001), “Negative Alchemy? Corruption, Composition of Capital Flows, and Currency Crises,” NBER Working Paper 8187, March.
Weingast, B. R. (1993), “Constitutions as Governance Structures: The Political Foundations of Secure Markets,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol. 149: 286–311.Google Scholar
Wellisz, St. and R. Findlay (1984), “Protection and Rent-Seeking in Developing Countries,” Neoclassical Political Economy. The Analysis of Rent-Seeking and DUP Activities, ed. by Colander, D. C. (Cambridge, MA: Ballinger Publishing Company): 141–54.Google Scholar
Welsch, H. (2004), “Corruption, Growth, and the Environment: A Cross-Country Analysis,” Environment and Development Economics, Vol. 9: 663–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wheeler, D. and Mody, A. (1992), “International Investment Location Decisions: The Case of U.S. Firms,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 33: 57–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiehen, M. (1996), “OECD Recommendations and Enquiry,” Uganda International Conference on Good Governance in Africa (Berlin: Transparency International): 115–22.Google Scholar
Wiggins, S. (1991), “The Economics of the Firm and Contracts: A Selective Survey,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, Vol. 147: 603–61.Google Scholar
Williamson, J. (1993), “Exchange Rate Management,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 103: 188–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1983), “Credible Commitments: The Use of Hostages to Support Exchange,” American Economic Review, Vol. 83: 519–40.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting (New York: The Free Press).Google Scholar
Winston, G. C. (1979), “The Appeal of Inappropriate Technologies: Self-Inflicted Wages, Ethnic Price and Corruption,” World Development, Vol. 7 (8/9): 835–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wintrobe, R. (1998a), “Some Lessons on the Efficiency of Democracy from a Study of Dictatorship,” The Political Dimension of Economic Growth, ed. by Borner, S. and Paldam, M. (London and New York: Macmillan Press and St. Martin Press): 20–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wintrobe, R. (1998b), The Political Economy of Dictatorship (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wintrobe, R. and Breton, A. (1986), “Organizational Structure and Productivity,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 76 (3): 530–8.Google Scholar
World Bank (1997), World Development Report 1997 (Washington, DC: World Bank).
Wyatt, G. (2002), “Corruption, Productivity and Transition,” Centre for Economic Reform and Transformation, (CERT) Discussion Paper 205, Heriot Watt University, Edinburgh, United Kingdom.
You, J. -S. and Khagram, S. (2005), “Inequality and Corruption,” American Sociological Review, Vol. 70 (1): 136–57.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Johann Graf Lambsdorff
  • Book: The Institutional Economics of Corruption and Reform
  • Online publication: 05 November 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511492617.013
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Johann Graf Lambsdorff
  • Book: The Institutional Economics of Corruption and Reform
  • Online publication: 05 November 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511492617.013
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Johann Graf Lambsdorff
  • Book: The Institutional Economics of Corruption and Reform
  • Online publication: 05 November 2009
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511492617.013
Available formats
×