Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-p2v8j Total loading time: 0.001 Render date: 2024-05-15T20:53:23.923Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - The evolution of market structure, information, and spreads in American investment banking (with Daniel M. G. Raff)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 September 2009

Charles W. Calomiris
Affiliation:
Columbia University, New York
Get access

Summary

Introduction

The fees investment bankers earn for placing primary securities issued by their clients have occupied a central place in the debate over the proper regulation of investment banking since at least the beginning of the twentieth century. In his classic attack on the “money trust,” Other People's Money and How the Bankers Use It, Louis Brandeis argued that the enormous fees earned by investment bankers – particularly on stock issues – offered conclusive proof of the existence of substantial rent extraction by the “money trust.” Brandeis (1914, p. 95) noted that Morgan's gross commission (or “spread”) exceeded 20 percent for the organization of U.S. Steel and was 25 percent for underwriting the Tube Trust. More generally, Brandeis (p. 95) wrote:

Nor were monster commissions limited to trust promotions. More recently, bankers' syndicates have, in many instances, received for floating preferred stocks of recapitalized industrial concerns, one-third of all the common stock issued, besides a considerable sum in cash. And for the sale of preferred stock of well established manufacturing concerns, cash commissions (or profits) of from 7½ to 10 percent of the cash raised are often exacted. On bonds of high-class industrial concerns, bankers' commissions (or profits) of from 5 to 10 points have been common.

Brandeis considered it self-evident that such commissions could only be produced by an excessive concentration of power in the investment banking industry that gave rise to an effective monopoly over the financial market.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2000

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×