Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-r6qrq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-29T20:56:25.067Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

4 - Does firm ownership matter? POEs vs. FOEs in the developing world

from Part I - Introduction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 July 2009

Ravi Ramamurti
Affiliation:
Northeastern University, Boston
Jitendra V. Singh
Affiliation:
Nanyang Technological University, Singapore
Get access

Summary

The nationality of a firm's owner doesn't matter for economic development in perfectly competitive markets. A foreign-owned enterprise (FOE) from a developed country or a privately owned enterprise (POE) from a developing country are equally capable if both have access to the same inputs and marketing opportunities (ignoring SOEs and tiny enterprises). Where the theory of free competition reigns, developing countries should open their arms to investments from all types of firms in order to maximize jobs, as many Asian countries did using export processing zones. Ownership, measured by votes of shareholders or boards of directors, is immaterial to performance.

Matters change drastically, though, when competition depends on monopolistic assets and market theory no longer rigorously holds, as in “mid-tech” industries such as shipbuilding, steel, and heavy machinery, and “mature” high-tech industries, such as calculators, computers, and cell phones, after millions of units from advanced countries have already been sold but demand is still booming. Knowledge, brand names, political clout, and other sources of market power vary by firm and influence market outcomes. Then, ownership matters.

Because FOEs have controlled more competitive assets than POEs since the First Industrial Revolution, they have gained the upper hand and the respect of the elite business schools, that tend to view them as the best policy choice for backward countries to follow. FOEs are highly productive, the argument runs, and somehow transfer knowledge (measured by “spillovers”) to local enterprise, so invite them into your midst.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Amsden, A. H. (2001). The Rise of “the Rest”: Challenges to the West from Late-Industrializing Economies. New York, Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amsden, A. H. (2007). Escape from Empire: The Developing World's Journey Through Heaven and Hell. Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Amsden, A. H. and Chu, W. W. (2003). Beyond Late Development: Taiwan's Upgrading Policies. Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.Google Scholar
Amsden, A. H. and Hikino, T. (1994). Project Execution Capability, Organizational Know-how and Conglomerate Corporate Growth in Late Industrialization. Industrial and Corporate Change 3(1): 111–147.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bagchi, A. K. (1972). Private Investment in India, 1900–1939. Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A. K. (1963). India's Balance of Payments: Estimates of Current and Capital Accounts from 1921–22 to 1938–39. Bombay, Asia Publishing House.
Chandavarkar, R. (1994). The Bombay Cotton Textile Industry, 1900–1940. Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Das, N. (1962). Industrial Enterprise in India. Bombay, Orient Longmans.Google Scholar
Dori, G. (1988). Sources, Procedures, and Microeconomic Effects of Innovation. Journal of Economic Literature Vol. 26, No. 3: 1120–1171.Google Scholar
Ferguson, N. (2003). Empire: The Rise and Demise of the British World Order and the Lessons for Global Power. New York, Basic Books.Google Scholar
Feuerwerker, A. (1958). China's Early Industrialization: Cheng Hsuan-Huai (1844–1916) and Mandarin Enterprise. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feuerwerker, A. (1967). Industrial Enterprise in Twentieth-Century China: The Chee Hsin Cement Co. Approaches to Modern Chinese History. Feuerwerker, A., Murphey, R. and Wright, M. C. (eds.). Berkeley, and Los Angeles, , CA, University of California Press: 304–341.Google Scholar
Fraser, L. (1919). Iron and Steel in India. Bombay, Times Press.Google Scholar
Hao, Y. -p. i. (1986). The Commercial Revolution in Nineteenth-Century China: The Rise of Sino-Western Mercantile Capitalism. Berkeley, CA, University of California Press.Google Scholar
Khanna, T. and Yafeh, Y. (2007). Business Groups in Emerging Markets: Paragons or Parasites?Journal of Economic Literature Vol. 45: 331–372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawrence, R. Z. (1993). Japan's Low Levels of Inward Investment: The Role of Inhibitions on Acquisitions. Foreign direct Investment. Froot, K. (ed.). Chicago, University of Chicago for the National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Lieu, D. K. (1936). The Growth and Industrialization of Shanghai. Shanghai: China Institute of Pacific Relations.Google Scholar
Maddison, A. (1971). Class Structure and Economic Growth: India and Pakistan Since the Moghuls. New York, W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Mathiar, P. (1973). Capital, Credit and Enterprise in the Industrial Revolution. Journal of European Economic History Vol. 2: 121–143.Google Scholar
Morris, M. D. (1983). The Growth of Large-Scale Industry to 1947. The Cambridge Economic History of India. Vol. 2 Kumar, D. and Desai, M.(eds.). Cambridge, UK, Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mourshed, M. (1999). Technology Transfer Dynamics: Lessons from the Egyptian and Indian Pharmaceutical Industries. Urban Studies and Planning Ph.D. thesis. Cambridge, MA, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Nakaoka, T. (1991). The Transfer of Cotton Manufacturing Technology from Britain to Japan. International Technology Transfer, Europe, Japan and the USA, 1700–1914. Jeremy, D. J. (ed.). Aldershot, UK, Edward Elgar: 181–198.Google Scholar
Riskin, C. (1975). Surplus and Stagnation in Modern China. China's Modern Economy in Historical Perspective. Perkins, D. H.(ed.). Stanford, CA, Stanford University Press: 49–84.Google Scholar
Rungta, R. S. (1970). The Rise of Corporations in India, 1851–1900. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rutnagur, S. M. (1927). Bombay Industries: The Cotton Mills. Bombay, The Indian Textile Journal, Ltd.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×