Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-wzw2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-04T06:03:40.441Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

4 - Blurring firm R&D boundaries

Integrating transaction costs and knowledge-based perspectives

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  10 January 2011

Andrea Martinez-Noya
Affiliation:
University of Oviedo, Spain
Esteban Garcia-Canal
Affiliation:
University of Oviedo, Spain
Farok J. Contractor
Affiliation:
Rutgers University, New Jersey
Vikas Kumar
Affiliation:
University of Sydney
Sumit K. Kundu
Affiliation:
Florida International University
Torben Pedersen
Affiliation:
Copenhagen Business School
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Firm boundary decisions have been traditionally studied through the lens of transaction cost theory (TCT) (Masten et al., 1991; Monteverde, 1995; Williamson, 1975, 1985). However, the challenging evidence associated with the worldwide diffusion of new outsourcing practices, such as advanced subcontracting in the automobile industry, has driven researchers to analyze this phenomenon using alternative – although somewhat complementary – paradigms like the knowledge-based view of the firm (KBVF) (Grant, 1997; Kogut and Zander, 1993; Madhok and Tallman, 1998; Malhotra, 2003; Moran and Ghoshal, 1996) or the relational view (RV) (Dyer and Singh, 1998).

Although these paradigms question some of the predictions of TCT, the underlying hypothesis of this paradigm – the minimization of production and transaction costs – remains valid (Barney and Ouchi, 1986). In relation to this, a new trend is drawing the attention of both academics and practitioners: increased outsourcing of high-value and knowledge-based services that have traditionally been conducted internally by the firm, even to emerging countries (Bunyaratavej et al., 2007, 2008; Doh, 2005; Lewin and Peeters, 2006; Kedia and Mukherjee, 2008; Kotabe and Murray, 1990, 2004; Mol et al., 2004, 2005; UNCTAD, 2004, 2005). As far as these services are concerned, this chapter will focus on R&D specifically. Like advanced subcontracting, the outsourcing phenomenon of R&D services is another example of a boundary decision that does not perfectly fit with TCT. Due to the fact that firms are both increasingly fragmenting their product development activities and outsourcing some of these stages to external specialized providers (UNCTAD, 2005), we analyze the governance-mode decision related to R&D services.

Type
Chapter
Information
Global Outsourcing and Offshoring
An Integrated Approach to Theory and Corporate Strategy
, pp. 107 - 136
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Afuah, A. 2001. “Dynamic boundaries of the firm: are firms better off being vertically integrated in the face of a technological change?Academy of Management Journal 44: 1211–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Afuah, A. 2003. “Redefining firm boundaries in the face of the internet: are firms really shrinking?Academy of Management Review 28(1): 34–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almeida, P. and Kogut, B. 1999. “Localization of knowledge and the mobility of engineers in regional networks,” Management Science 45(7): 905–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, R. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Barney, J.B. and Hansen, M.H. 1994. “Trustworthiness as a source of competitive advantage,” Strategic Management Journal 15: 175–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barney, J.B. and Ouchi, W.G. 1986. Organizational Economics. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.Google Scholar
Belderbos, R. 2003. “Entry mode, organizational learning, and R&D in foreign affiliates: evidence from Japanese firms,” Strategic Management Journal 24: 235–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bensaou, M. and Anderson, E. 1999. “Buyer-supplier relations in industrial markets: when do buyers risk making idiosyncratic investments?Organization Science 10(4): 460–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besanko, D., Dranove, D., and Shanley, M. 2002. Economics of Strategy. 2nd edn. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Buckley, P. 1988. “The limits of explanation: testing the internalization theory of the multinational enterprise,” Journal of International Business Studies 29: 181–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunyaratavej, K., Hahn, E.D., and Doh, J.P. 2007. “International offshoring of services: a parity study,” Journal of International Management 13(1): 7–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bunyaratavej, K., Hahn, E.D., and Doh, J.P. 2008. “Multinational investment and host country development: location efficiencies for services offshoring,” Journal of World Business 43: 227–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cantwell, J. 1989. Technological Innovations and Multinational Corporations. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Cantwell, J. 1991. “The theory of technological competence and its application to international production,” in McFridge, D (ed.), Foreign Investment, Technology, and Economic Growth. University of Calgary Press, pp. 33–67.Google Scholar
Cassiman, B. and Veugelers, R. 2002. “R&D cooperation and spillovers: some empirical evidence from Belgium,” American Economic Review 92(4): 1169–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chesbrough, H.W. and Teece, D.J. 1996. “When is virtual virtuous? Organizing for innovation,” Harvard Business Review (Jan.–Feb.): 65–73.
Christensen, C., Suarez, F.F., and Utterback, J.M. 1998. “Strategies for survival in fast-changing industries,” Management Science 44: 207–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chung, W. and Alcacer, J. 2002. “Knowledge seeking and location choice of foreign direct investment in the United States,” Management Science 48: 1534–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, W. and Levinthal, D. 1990. “Absorptive capacity: a new perspective on learning and innovation,” Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1): 128–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delios, A. and Henisz, W.J. 2000. “Japanese firms' investment strategies in emerging economies,” Academy of Management Journal 43: 305–23.Google Scholar
Doh, J. 2005. “Offshore outsourcing: implications for international business and strategic management theory and practice,” Journal of Management Studies 42: 695–705.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doh, J., Mudambi, R., Jones, G., and Teegen, H. 2005. “Foreign research and development and host country environment: an empirical examination of US international R&D,” Management International Review 45, Special Issue 2: 121–54.Google Scholar
Dyer, J.H. 1996. “Specialized supplier networks as a source of competitive advantage: evidence from the auto industry,” Strategic Management Journal 17(4): 271–91.3.0.CO;2-Y>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyer, J.H. 1997. “Effective interfirm collaboration: how transactors minimize transaction costs and maximize transaction value,” Strategic Management Journal 18(7): 535–56.3.0.CO;2-Z>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dyer, J.H. and Singh, H. 1998. “The relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage,” Academy of Management Review 23: 660–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fawcett, J.I. and Scully, S.E. 1998. “Worldwide sourcing: facilitating continued success,” Production and Inventory Management Journal 39(1): 1–9.Google Scholar
Fosfuri, A. and Roca, E. 2002. “Naturaleza y características del conocimiento tecnológico y limitaciones a la transferencia de tecnología,” Revista Europea de Dirección y Economía de la Empresa 11(3): 139–52.Google Scholar
Franko, L.G. 1971. Joint Venture Survival in Multinational Corporations. New York: Praeger.Google Scholar
Gatignon, H. and Anderson, E. 1988. “The multinational corporations' degree of control over foreign subsidiaries: an empirical test of a transaction cost explanation,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 4(2): 305–36.Google Scholar
Grant, R. 1997. “Toward a knowledge-based theory of the firm,” Strategic Management Journal 17 (Winter Special Issue): 109–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, W.J. 2000. “The institutional environment for multinational investment,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 16(2): 334–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henisz, W.J. and Williamson, O.E. 1999. “Comparative economic organization within and between countries,” Economics and Politics 1: 261–76.Google Scholar
Hill, C.W. 1990. “Cooperation, opportunism, and the invisible hand: implications for transaction cost theory,” Academy of Management Review 15: 500–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hill, C.W., Hwang, P., and Kim, W.C. 1990. “An eclectic theory of the choice of international entry mode,” Strategic Management Journal 11: 117–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hymer, S.H. 1960. The international operations of national firms: a study of direct investment. PhD Thesis, MIT, published 1976, Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Kedia, B.L. and Mukherjee, D. 2008. “Understanding offshoring: a research framework based on disintegration, location and externalization advantages,” Journal of World Business 44: 250–61.
Kessler, E.H., Bierly, P.E., and Gopalakrishnan, S. 2000. “Internal vs. external learning in new product development: effects on speed, costs and competitive advantage,” R&D Management 30(3): 213–23.Google Scholar
Kim, S.M. and Mahoney, J.T. 2006. “Mutual commitment to support exchange: relation-specific IT system as a substitute for managerial hierarchy,” Strategic Management Journal 27(5): 401–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B. 1996. “Why hold-ups occur: the self-enforcing range of contractual relationships,” Economic Inquiry 34: 444–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, B., Crawford, R.G., and Alchian, A.A. 1978. “Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process,” Journal of Law and Economics 21 (Oct.): 297–326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kobrin, S. 1987. “Testing the bargaining hypothesis in the manufacturing sector in developing countries,” International Organization 41: 609–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B. 1988. “Joint ventures: theoretical and empirical perspectives,” Strategic Management Journal 9(4): 319–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kogut, B. and Zander, U. 1993. “Knowledge of the firm and the evolutionary theory of the multinational corporation,” Journal of International Business Studies 4th Qt.: 625–45.CrossRef
Kotabe, M. and Murray, J.Y. 1990. “Linking product and process innovations and modes of international sourcing in global competition: a case of foreign multinational firms,” Journal of International Business Studies 213: 383–408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kotabe, M. and Murray, J.Y. 2004. “Global sourcing strategy and sustainable competitive advantage,” Industrial Marketing Management 33: 7–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuemmerle, W . 1999. “The drivers of foreign direct investment into research and development: an empirical investigation,” Journal of International Business Studies 30(1): 1–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, C. and Chen, Y.T. 2000. “Distributed visual reasoning for intelligent information retrieval on the web,” Interacting with Computers 12(5): 445–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewin, A. and Peeters, C. 2006. “Offshoring work: business hype or the onset of fundamental transformation?Long Range Planning 39: 221–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madhok, A. 1995. “Revisiting multinational firms' tolerance for joint ventures: a trust-based approach,” Journal of International Business Studies 26, 117–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madhok, A. 1997. “Cost, value and foreign market entry mode: the transaction and the firm,” Strategic Management Journal 18(1): 39–61.3.0.CO;2-J>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madhok, A. and Tallman, S.B. 1998. “Resources, transactions and rents: managing value in interfirm collaborative relationships,” Organization Science 9: 326–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malhotra, N. 2003. “The nature of knowledge and the entry mode decision,” Organization Studies 24(6): 935–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masten, S.E. 1984. “The organization of production: evidence from the aerospace industry,” Journal of Law and Economics 27: 403–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Masten, S.E., Meehan, J.W., and Snyder, E.A. 1991. “The costs of organization,” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 7: 1–25.Google Scholar
Merges, R.P. 1999. “Intellectual property rights, input markets, and the value of intangible assets.” Draft: www.law.berkeley.edu/institutes/ bclt/pubs/merges/iprights.pdf.
Mol, M.J., Pauwels, P., Matthyssens, P., and Quintens, L. 2004. “A technological contingency perspective on the depth and scope of international outsourcing,” Journal of International Management 10: 287– 305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mol, M.J., Tulder, V., Rob, J.M., and Beije, P.R. 2005. “Antecedents and performance consequences of international sourcing,” International Business Review 14: 599–617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Monteverde, K. 1995. “Technical dialog as an incentive for vertical integration in the semiconductor industry,” Management Science 41(10): 1624–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Monteverde, K. and Teece, D.J. 1982. “Supplier switching costs and vertical integration in the automobile industry,” Bell Journal of Economics 13: 206–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moran, P. and Ghoshal, S. 1996. “Theories of economic organization: the case for realism and balance,” Academy of Management Review 21(1): 58–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nachum, L. and Zaheer, S. 2005. “The persistence of distance? The impact of technology on MNE motivations for foreign investment,” Strategic Management Journal 26: 747–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Nicholls-Nixon, C. and Woo, C. 2003. “Technology sourcing and output of established firms in a regime of encompassing technological change,” Strategic Management Journal 24(7): 651–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oster, S. 1999. Modern Competitive Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Oxley, J.E. 1997. “Appropriability hazards and governance in strategic alliances: a transaction cost approach,” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 13(2): 387–409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patel, P. and Vega, M. 1999. “Patterns of internationalization of corporate technology: location versus home country advantages,” Research Policy 28: 145–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pavitt, K. 1999. Technology, Management and Systems of Innovation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Pearce, R. 1999. “Decentralised R&D and strategic competitiveness: globalised approaches to generation and use of technology in multinational enterprises MNEs,” Research Policy 28: 57–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pisano, G.P. 1989. “Using equity participation to support exchange: evidence from the biotechnology industry,” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 35: 109–26.Google Scholar
Pisano, G.P. 1990. “The R&D boundaries of the firm: an empirical analysis,” Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 153–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quinn, B.J. and Hilmer, F.G. 1994. “Strategic outsourcing,” MIT Sloan Management Review 34(4): 43–55.Google Scholar
Rangan, S. 2000. “Search and deliberation in international exchange: microfoundations to some macro patterns,” Journal of International Business Studies 31: 205–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenkopf, L. and Almeida, P. 2001. “Overcoming local search through alliances and mobility,” Working Paper, The Wharton School.
Rothaermel, F.T., Hitt, M.A., and Jobe, L.A. 2006. “Balancing vertical integration and strategic outsourcing: effects on product portfolio, product success, and firm performance,” Strategic Management Journal 27(11): 1033–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sampler, J.L. 1998. “Redefining industry structure for the information age,” Strategic Management Journal 15: 343–55.3.0.CO;2-G>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schilling, M.A. 2005. Strategic Management of Technological Innovation. Boston: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Scott, A. 1998. Regions and the World Economy: The Coming Shape of World Production, Competition, and Political Order. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Shaver, J.M. and Flyer, F. 2000. “Agglomeration economies, firm heterogeneity, and foreign direct investment in the United States,” Strategic Management Journal 21(12): 1175–93.3.0.CO;2-Q>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. 1991. “Bounded rationality and organizational learning,” Organization Science 21: 125–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stopford, J.M. and Wells, L.T. 1972. Managing Multinational Enterprise: Organization of the Firm and Ownership of the Subsidiaries. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. 1986. The Economics of Rights, Co-operation, and Welfare. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Swamidass, P.M. and Kotabe, M. 1993. “Component sourcing strategies of multinationals: an empirical study of European and Japanese multinationals,” Journal of International Business Studies 24(1): 81–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taggart, J.H. 1991. “Determinants of foreign R&D locational decisions in the pharmaceutical industry,” R&D Management 21(3): 229–40.Google Scholar
Teece, D.J. 1992. “Competition, cooperation, and innovation: organizational arrangements for regimes of rapid technological progress,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 18(1): 1–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,UNCTAD. 2004. World Investment Report 2004: The Shift towards Services. New York and Geneva: United Nations.Google Scholar
,UNCTAD. 2005. World Investment Report 2005: Transnational Corporations and the Internalization of R&D. New York and Geneva: United Nations.
Walker, G. and Weber, D. 1984. “A transaction cost approach to the make-or-buy decision,” Administrative Science Quarterly 29: 373–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wesson, T.J. 2004. Foreign Direct Investment and Competitive Advantage. Cheltenham, UK:Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Williamson, O.E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Anti-Trust Implications. New York: Free-Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O.E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free-Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, O.E. 1991. “Comparative economic organization: the analysis of discrete structural alternatives,” Administrative Science Quarterly 36: 269–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×