Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vvkck Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-29T09:35:48.541Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

1 - Rethinking the Resource Curse

Ownership Structure and Institutions in Mineral-Rich States

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Pauline Jones Luong
Affiliation:
Brown University, Rhode Island
Erika Weinthal
Affiliation:
Duke University, North Carolina
Get access

Summary

Petro-states share a similar path-dependent history and structuration of choice … the exploitation of petroleum produced a similarity in property rights, tax structures, vested interests, economic models, and thus frameworks for decision-making across different governments and regime types.

– Terry Lynn Karl (1997, 227)

For the quality of our understanding of current problems depends largely on the broadness of our frame of reference.

– Alexander Gershenkron (1962, 6)

The negative consequences of mineral abundance in developing countries – poor economic performance, unbalanced growth, impoverished populations, weak states, and authoritarian regimes – are widely accepted among highly respected academics, international nongovernmental organizations (INGOs), international financial institutions (IFIs), and even representatives of the popular media. This is particularly true of petroleum. Indeed, some have gone so far as to declare that the resource curse is “a reasonably solid fact” (Sachs and Warner 2001, 837), while others have proclaimed that there is a “Law of Petropolitics” whereby “[t]he price of oil and the pace of freedom always move in opposite directions in oil-rich states” (Friedman 2006, 31). Nigeria’s experience with petroleum provides a vivid illustration of this so-called “curse” of wealth. Although its government has accrued $350 billion in oil revenues since independence in 1960, between 1970 and 2000 its economy shrunk dramatically, its poverty rate “increased from close to 36 percent to just under 70 percent” (Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian 2003, 3) and its political regime “has become increasingly centralized and oppressive” (Jensen and Wantchekon 2004, 819).

But few seem to agree as to exactly why mineral wealth allegedly produces such negative outcomes. The most prominent explanations for economic stagnation focus on the direct effect that export windfalls have on the real exchange rate. In short, by shifting production inputs to the booming mineral sector and nontradable sector, they reduce the competitiveness of the nonbooming export sectors and hence precipitate their collapse (i.e., “Dutch Disease”) (see Auty 2001b). Others stress the indirect effects that export windfalls have on retarded economic growth through promoting corruption and indebtedness while discouraging productive long-term investment (see Gylfason 2001, Leite and Weidmann 1999). On the political side, the prevalence of authoritarian regimes in mineral-rich states, for example, is largely attributed to the effect that centralized access to export revenue, particularly during a boom, has on regime type by increasing the government’s fiscal independence and consequently decreasing both the ability and willingness of the general population to hold its leaders accountable (see Ross 2001a, Wantchekon 1999).

Type
Chapter
Information
Oil Is Not a Curse
Ownership Structure and Institutions in Soviet Successor States
, pp. 1 - 30
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×