Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-p2v8j Total loading time: 0.001 Render date: 2024-05-15T16:07:17.626Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Bruce Lyons
Affiliation:
University of East Anglia
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Cases in European Competition Policy
The Economic Analysis
, pp. 465 - 481
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abreu, Dilip (1986), ‘Extremal Equilibria of Oligopolistic Supergames’, Journal of Economic Theory, 39: 191–225CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip, Milgrom, Paul and Pearce, David (1991), ‘Information and Timing in Repeated Partnerships’, Econometrica, 59: 1713–1733CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip, Pearce, David and Stacchetti, Ennio (1986), ‘Optimal Cartel Equilibria with Imperfect Monitoring’, Journal of Economic Theory, 39: 251–269CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Abreu, Dilip, Pearce, David and Stacchetti, Ennio (1990), ‘Towards a Theory of Discounted Repeated Games with Imperfect Monitoring’, Econometrica, 58: 1041–1064CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Adilov, Peter and Alexander, Peter J. (2006), ‘Horizontal Merger – Pivotal Buyers and Bargaining Power’, Economics Letters, 91(3): 307–311CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, Philippe, Blundell, Richard, Griffith, Rachel, Howitt, Peter and Prantl, Susanne (2004), ‘Entry and Productivity Growth: Evidence from Microlevel Panel Data’, Journal of the European Economic Association, 2(2–3): 265–276CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahn, Sanghoon (2002), ‘Competition, Innovation and Productivity Growth: A Review of Theory and Evidence’, OECD Economics Department Working Paper No. 317CrossRef
Allen, Beth, Deneckere, Raymond, Faith, Tom and Kovenock, Dan (2000), ‘Capacity Precommitment as a Barrier to Entry: A Bertrand-Edgeworth Approach’, Economic Theory, 15: 501–530CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,American Bar Association, Section of Antitrust Law (1996), Proving Antitrust Damages – Legal and Economic Issues, Chicago: American Bar AssociationGoogle Scholar
Armstrong, Mark (2002), ‘The Theory of Access Pricing and Interconnection’ in Cave, Martin E., Majumdar, Sumit Kumar and Vogelsang, Ingo (eds.), Handbook of Telecommunications Economics, Volume 1, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Armstrong, Mark (2006), ‘Competition in Two-Sided Markets’, RAND Journal of Economics, Special Issue on Two-Sided Markets, 37(3): 668–691CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armstrong, Mark and Porter, Rob (2007), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Armstrong, Mark and Sappington, David (2007), ‘Recent Developments in the Theory of Regulation’ in Armstrong, and Porter, (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Armstrong, Mark and Wright, Julian (2007a), ‘Mobile Call Termination’, SSRN Working Paper, September
Armstrong, Mark and Wright, Julian (2007b), ‘Two-Sided Markets, Competitive Bottlenecks and Exclusive Contracts’, Economic Theory, 32(2): 353–380CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armstrong, Mark and Wright, Julian (2009), ‘Mobile Call Termination’, The Economic Journal, June
Arrow, Kenneth J. (1971), Essays in the Theory of Risk Bearing, Chicago: Markham Publishing Co.Google Scholar
Arrunada, Benito, Garicano, Luis and Vazquez, Luis (2005), ‘Completing Contracts Ex Post: How Car Manufacturers Manage Car Dealers’, Review of Law and Economics, 1(1): 1–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asker, John (2004), ‘Diagnosing Foreclosure due to Exclusive Dealing’, mimeo, Stern School of Business
Athey, Susan and Bagwell, Kyle (2001), ‘Optimal Collusion with Private Information’, RAND Journal of Economics, 32: 428–465CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Athey, Susan, Bagwell, Kyle and Sanchirico, Chris (2004), ‘Collusion and Price Rigidity’, Review of Economic Studies, 71: 317–349CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Autopolis (2000), ‘The Natural Link between Sales and Service: An Investigation for the Competition Directorate General of the European Commission’, available at: www.europa.eu.int/comm/competition/car_sector
Bagwell, Kyle and Staiger, Robert (1997), ‘Collusion over the Business Cycle’, RAND Journal of Economics, 28: 82–106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, Jonathan B. (1993), ‘Two Sherman Act Section 1 Dilemmas: Parallel Pricing, the Oligopoly Problem, and Contemporary Theory’, Antitrust Bulletin, Spring: 143–219Google Scholar
Banks, David (2001), Breaking Windows, New York: Macmillan Free PressGoogle Scholar
Baxter, William F. (1983), ‘Bank Interchange of Transactional Paper: Legal Perspectives’, Journal of Law and Economics, 26: 541–588CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. (1968), ‘Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach’, Journal of Political Economy, 76(2): 169–217CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benoit, Jean-Pierre and Krishna, Vijay (1987), ‘Dynamic Duopoly: Prices and Quantities’, Review of Economic Studies, 54: 23–36CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernheim, B. Douglas and Whinston, Michael D. (1998), ‘Exclusive Dealing’, Journal of Political Economy, 106(1): 64–103CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berry, Steven and Reiss, Peter (2007), ‘Empirical Models of Entry and Market Structure’ in Armstrong, and Porter, (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Besanko, David and Perry, Martin K. (1993), ‘Equilibrium Incentives for Exclusive Dealing in a Differentiated Goods Oligopoly’, RAND Journal of Economics, 24(4): 646–668CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,BEUC (1992), ‘Parallel Market for Cars in the EC’, European Bureau of Consumer Unions, 229/92
,BHA (2007), ‘Determination of the 47th Horserace Betting Levy Scheme’: Submission of British Horseracing Authority, available at: www.britishhorseracing.com/inside_horseracing/
Bishop, Simon and Walker, Mike (2002), The Economics of EC Competition Law, London: Sweet & MaxwellGoogle Scholar
Bloch, Kurt (1932), ‘On German Cartels’, Journal of Business, 5(3): 213–222Google Scholar
Bloom, Nicholas, Bond, Stephen R. and Reenen, John (2007), ‘Uncertainty and Company Investment Dynamics: Empirical Evidence for UK Firms’, Review of Economic Studies, 74: 391–415CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, Patrick and Scharfstein, David S. (1990), ‘A Theory of Predation Based on Agency Problems in Financial Contracting’, American Economic Review, 80(1): 93–106Google Scholar
Bolton, Ruth N. and Shankar, Venkatesh (2003), ‘An Empirically Derived Taxonomy of Retailer Pricing and Promotion Strategies’, Journal of Retailing, 79(4): 213–224CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bonanno, Giacomo and Vickers, John (1988), ‘Vertical Separation’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 36(3): 257–265CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bork, Robert (1978), The Antitrust Paradox, New York: Macmillan Free PressGoogle Scholar
Brenkers, Randy and Verboven, Frank (2006a), ‘Liberalizing a Distribution System: The European Car Market’, Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(1): 216–251CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brenkers, Randy and Verboven, Frank (2006b), ‘Market Definition with Differentiated Products: Lessons from the Car Market’ in Choi, Jay Pil (ed.), Recent Developments in Antitrust: Theory and Evidence, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Bresnahan, Timothy and Greenstein, Shane (1996), ‘Technical Progress and Co-invention in Computing and in the Uses of Computers’, Brooking Papers on Economic Activity: Microeconomics, 1–78Google Scholar
Bresnahan, Timothy and Reiss, Peter (1991), ‘Entry and Competition in Concentrated Markets’, Journal of Political Economy, 99(5): 977–1009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Brewers and Licensed Retailers Association (various years), Statistical Handbook, London
,British Beer and Pub Association (2005), Statistical Handbook, London
Brock, William A. and Scheinkman, José A. (1985), ‘Price Setting Supergames with Capacity Constraints’, Review of Economic Studies, 52(3): 371–382CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brod, Andrew and Shivakumar, Ram (1999), ‘Advantageous Semicollusion’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 47: 221–230CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bryant, Peter G. and Eckard, E. Woodrow (1991), ‘Price Fixing: The Probability of Getting Caught’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 73(3): 531–536CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cabellero, Ricardo J., Engel, Eduardo M. R. A. and Haltiwanger, John C. (1995), ‘Plant Level Adjustment and Aggregate Investment Dynamics’, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2: 1–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cabral, Luis M. B. (2000), Introduction to Industrial Organization, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Caillaud, Bernard and Jullien, Bruno (2003), ‘Chicken and Egg: Competition Among Intermediation Service Providers’, RAND Journal of Economics, 34(2): 309–328CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caillaud, Bernard and Rey, Patrick (1986), ‘A Note on Vertical Restraints with the Provision of Distribution Services’, mimeo, Paris: INSEE and Cambridge, Mass.: MITGoogle Scholar
Calzada, Joan and Valletti, Tommaso (2008), ‘Network Competition and Entry Deterrence’, Economic Journal, 118: 1223–1244CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camilli, Enrico L. (2006), ‘Optimal Fines in Cartel Cases and the Actual EC Fining Policy’, World Competition: Law & Economics Review, 29(4): 575–605Google Scholar
Carlton, Dennis W. and Frankel, Alan S. (1995), ‘Antitrust and Payment Technologies’, Review, Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis, November: 41–54Google Scholar
Carlton, Dennis W. and Perloff, Jeffrey M. (2000), Modern Industrial Organisation, 3rd edition, London: HarperCollinsGoogle Scholar
Carlton, Dennis W. and Waldman, Michael (2002), ‘The Strategic Use of Tying to Preserve and Create Market Power in Evolving Industries’, RAND Journal of Economics, 33(2): 194–220CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cestone, Giacinta and Fumagalli, Chiara (2003), ‘The Strategic Impact of Resource Flexibility in Business Groups’, RAND Journal of Economics, 36: 193–214Google Scholar
Chang, Howard, Evans, David S. and Garcia Swartz, Daniel D. (2005), ‘The Effect of Regulatory Intervention in Two-Sided Markets: An Assessment of Interchange-Fee Capping in Australia’, joint Center AEI-Brookings and Center for Regulatory Studies related publication 05–29
Chen, Zhijun and Rey, Patrick (2007), ‘On the Design of Leniency Programs’, IDEI Working Paper, No. 452
Choi, Jay Pil (2001), ‘A Theory of Mixed Bundling Applied to the GE/Honeywell Merger’, Antitrust, 16: 32–33Google Scholar
Choi, Jay Pil (2004), ‘Tying and Innovation: A Dynamic Analysis of Tying Arrangements’, Economic Journal, 114: 83–101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Choi, Jay Pil (2007), ‘Antitrust Analysis of Tying Arrangements’, in Pil Choi, Jay (ed.), Recent Developments in Antitrust: Theory and Evidence, CESifo seminar series, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Choi, Jay Pil and Stefanidis, Chrisodoulos (2001), ‘Tying, Investment, and the Dynamic Leverage Theory’, RAND Journal of Economics, 32(1): 52–71CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christensen, Laurits Rolf and Caves, Richard E. (1997), ‘Cheap Talk and Investment Rivalry in the Pulp and Paper Industry’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 45(1): 47–53CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Church, Jeffrey R. and Ware, Roger (2000), Industrial Organization: A Strategic Approach, Boston: Irwin McGraw-HillGoogle Scholar
Clarke, Roger, Davies, Steve, Dobson, Paul and Waterson, Michael (2002), Buyer Power and Competition in European Food Retailing, Cheltenham: Edward ElgarGoogle Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1960), ‘The Problem of Social Cost’, Journal of Law and Economics, 3(1): 1–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Competition Commission (2000a), ‘New Cars: A Report on the Supply of New Motor Cars within the UK’, London: HMSO
,Competition Commission (2000b), ‘Supermarkets: A Report on the Supply of Groceries from Multiple Stores in the United Kingdom’, Cm. 4842, London: TSO
,Competition Commission (2003a), ‘Safeway plc and Asda Group Limited (owned by Wal-Mart Stores Inc); Wm Morrison Supermarkets plc; J. Sainsbury plc; and Tesco plc: A Report on the Mergers in Contemplation’, Cm 5950, London: TSO
,Competition Commission (2003b), ‘Vodafone, O2, Orange and T-Mobile: Reports on References Under Section 13 of Telecommunications Act 1984 on Charges Made by Vodafone, Orange, O2 and T-Mobile for Terminating Calls Made by Fixed and Mobile Networks’, London: HMSO
Compte, Oliver (1998), ‘Communication in Repeated Games with Imperfect Private Monitoring’, Econometrica, 66: 597–626CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Compte, Olivier, Jenny, Frédéric and Rey, Patrick (2002), ‘Capacity Constraints, Mergers and Collusion’, European Economic Review, 46(1): 1–29CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Connor, John M. (1997), ‘The Global Lysine Price-Fixing Conspiracy of 1992–1995’, Review of Agricultural Economics, 19(2): 412–427CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Connor, John M. (2001), ‘“Our Customers are Our Enemies”: The Lysine Cartel of 1992–1995’, Review of Industrial Organization, 18(1): 5–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Connor, John M. (2004a), ‘Global Cartels Redux: The Amino Acid Lysine Antitrust Litigation (1996)’ in Kwoka, Jr John E. and White, Lawrence (eds.), The Antitrust Revolution: Economics, Competition, and Policy, 4th edition, Oxford University Press: 252–276.Google Scholar
Connor, John M. (2004b), ‘Price-Fixing Overcharges: Legal and Economic Evidence’, American Antitrust Institute Working Paper 04–05
Connor, John M. (2005), ‘Optimal Deterrence and Private International Cartels’, Draft Paper, Purdue University, Ind., May
Connor, John M. and Bolotova, Yulija (2006), ‘Cartel Overcharges: Survey and Meta-analysis’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24: 1109–1137CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corts, Kenneth S. (1998), ‘Third-Degree Price Discrimination in Oligopoly: All-Out Competition and Strategic Commitment’, RAND Journal of Economics, 29(2): 306–323CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cournot, Antoine (1838), Recherches sur les principes mathématiques de la théorie des richesses, Paris: HachetteGoogle Scholar
Court of First Instance (CFI) Decisions see European Court Decisions
Danzon, Patricia M. (1998), ‘The Economics of Parallel Trade’, Pharmaeconomics, 13(3): 293–304CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Davidson, Carl and Deneckere, Raymond (1990), ‘Excess Capacity and Collusion’, International Economic Review, 31(3): 521–541CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, Stephen, Coles, Heather, Olczak, Matt, Pike, Chris and Wilson, Chris (2004), ‘The Benefits of Competition: Some Illustrative UK Case Studies’, DTI Economics Paper No. 9, available at: www.berr.gov.uk/files/file13299.pdf
Davies, Stephen and Lyons, Bruce (1989), ‘Introduction’ in Stephen, Davies, Bruce, Lyons, Huw, Dixon and Paul, Geroski (eds.), Economics of Industrial Organisation, London: LongmanGoogle Scholar
Davies, Stephen and Lyons, Bruce (2007), Mergers and Merger Remedies in the EU: Assessing the Consequences for Competition, London: Edward ElgarCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, Stephen and Majumdar, Adrian (2002), The Development of Targets for Consumer Savings Arising from Competition Policy, Chapter 4, Office of Fair Trading Economic Discussion Paper 4
Dechenaux, Emmanuel and Kovenock, Dan (2003), ‘Endogenous Rationing, Price Dispersion and Collusion in Capacity Constrained Supergames’, Krannert Working Paper No. 1164, Ind.: Purdue UniversityGoogle Scholar
Deloitte, (2006), ‘Economic Impact Review of British Racing’, commissioned by BHB and available at: www.britishhorseracing.com/inside_horseracing/
Deloitte, (2007), ‘The Deterrent Effect of Competition Enforcement by the OFT’, OFT962, London: Office of Fair Trading
Demsetz, Harold (1973), ‘Industry Structure, Market Rivalry and Public Policy’, Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1): 1–10CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dick, Andrew R. (2002), ‘Coordinated Interaction: Pre-Merger Constraints and Post-Merger Effects’, mimeo, US Department of Justice, available at: www.crai.com/Agenda/Dick.pdf
,Director General of Fair Trading (DGFT) (1995), Memo to the Secretary of State for Trade and Industry
Dixit, Avinash (1980), ‘The Role of Investment in Entry-deterrence’, Economic Journal, 90: 95–106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash (1991), ‘Analytical Approximations in Models of Hysteresis’, Review of Economic Studies, 58: 141–151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Consulting, Dobson (1999), Buyer Power and its Impact on Competition in the Food Retail Distribution Sector of the European Union, Brussels: European Commission DG Competition, available at: www.europa.eu.int/comm/competition/publications/studies/bpifrs/Google Scholar
Dobson, Paul W. (2002), The Economic Effects of Constant Below-Cost Selling Practices by Grocery Retailers, London: UK Federation of BakersGoogle Scholar
Dobson, Paul W. (2005), ‘Exploiting Buyer Power: Lessons from the British Grocery Trade’, Antitrust Law Journal, 72(2): 529–562Google Scholar
Dobson, Paul W. (2007), Micro-marketing and Discriminatory Practices in UK Grocery Retailing, report submitted to the Competition Commission, available at: www.competition-commission.org.uk
Dobson, Paul W., Waterson, Michael and Chu, Alex (1998), ‘The Welfare Consequences of the Exercise of Buyer Power’, Research Paper No. 16, London: Office of Fair Trading
Dobson, Paul W., Clarke, Roger, Davies, Steve and Waterson, Michael (2001), ‘Buyer Power and its Impact on Competition in the Food Distribution Sector of the European Union’, Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade, 1(3): 247–281CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobson, Paul W. and Inderst, Roman (2007), ‘Differential Buyer Power and the Waterbed Effect: Do Strong Buyers Benefit or Harm Consumers?’, European Competition Law Review, 28(7): 393–400Google Scholar
Dobson, Paul W., Starkey, Ken and Richards, John (2004), Strategic Management: Issues and Cases, Oxford: Blackwell PublishingGoogle Scholar
Dobson, Paul W. and Waterson, Michael (1996), ‘Vertical Restraints and Competition Policy’, Research Paper No. 12, London: Office of Fair Trading
Dobson, Paul W. and Waterson, Michael (2005), ‘Chain-Store Pricing across Local Markets’, Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 14(1): 93–119CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobson, Paul W. and Waterson, Michael (2006), ‘Micro-marketing and Chain-Store Competition: Customized vs. Uniform Store-Level Pricing’, University of Loughborough, mimeo
Doyle, Maura P. and Snyder, Christopher M. (1999), ‘Information Sharing and Competition in the Motor Vehicle Industry’, Journal of Political Economy, 107(6): 1326–1364CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,EAGCP (2005), ‘An Economic Approach to Article 82’, Report for the European Commission (DG Competition), available at: http://llec.europa.eu/dgs/competition/economist/eagcp.html
Ellickson, Paul B. and Misra, Sanjog (2006), ‘Supermarket Pricing Strategies’, Working Paper 06–02, Department of Economics, Durham, N.C.: Duke University
Elliott, David (2007), ‘What is an Excessive Price? The View of the UK Courts’, Competition Law Insight, 31 July
Emch, Eric R. (2003), ‘GECAS and the GE/Honeywell Merger: A Response to Reynolds and Ordover’, Department of Justice Economic Analysis Group Discussion Paper, EAG 03–13
Epstein, Roy J. and Rubinfeld, Daniel L. (2002), ‘Merger Simulation: A Simplified Approach with New Applications’, Antitrust Law Journal, 69: 883–906Google Scholar
,European Commission (2000), ‘Report on the Evaluation of Regulation (EC) No 1475/95 on the Application of Article 85(3) of the Treaty to Certain Categories of Motor Vehicle Distribution and Servicing Agreements’,
,European Commission Decisions
,Commission Decision ofAirtours v First Choice 22 September 1999, Case No. IV/M.1524
,Commission Decision ofAseprofar and Fedifar Case IV/36.997/F3
,Commission Decision ofBAI Case IV/37.138/F3
,European Commission DecisionBass OJ L 186/1 Case IV/36.081/F3,European Commission Decision in General Electric/ Honeywell, 2001 – Case No. COMP/M.2220, downloadable at: ec.europa.eu/comm/competition/mergers/cases/decisions/m2220_en.pdf
,European Commission DecisionGlaxoWellcome Case IV/36.957/F3
,European Commission DecisionMicrosoft Decision 23.04.04 Case COMP/C-3/37.792
,European Commission DecisionNeste/IVO (1998), Case No. IV/M.931 (Luxembourg)
,European Commission DecisionRoberts v Greene King 1998, Case No. IV/36.511
,Commission Decision Case ofScottish and Newcastle, OJ L186/28 1999, Case No. IV/35.992/F3
,European Commission DecisionSpain Pharma Case IV/37.121/F3
,Commission Decision Case ofWhitbread, OJ L88/26 1999, Case No. IV/35.079/F3
Evans, David, Nichols, Albert, Reddy, Bernard and Schmalensee, Richard (2001), ‘A Monopolist Would Still Charge More for Windows: A Comment on Werden’, Review of Industrial Organization, 18: 263–268Google Scholar
Evans, David S. and Schmalensee, Richard (2005), Paying with Plastic, 2nd edition, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Farrell, Joseph (1987), ‘Cheap Talk, Coordination and Entry’, RAND Journal of Economics, 18: 34–39CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farrell, Joseph and Katz, Michael L. (2006), ‘The Economics of Welfare Standards in Antitrust’, Competition Policy International, 2(2): 3–28Google Scholar
Fershtman, Chaim and Gandal, Neil (1993), ‘Disadvantageous Semicollusion’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 12: 141–154CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fershtman, Chaim and Muller, Eitan (1986), ‘Capital Investments and Price Agreements in Semi-collusive Markets’, RAND Journal of Economics, 17: 214–226CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fershtman, Chaim and Pakes, Ariel (2000), ‘A Dynamic Oligopoly with Collusion and Price Wars’, RAND Journal of Economics, 31: 207–236CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finkelstein, Michael O. and Levenbach, Hans (1983), ‘Regression Estimates of Damages in Price-Fixing Cases’, Law and Contemporary Problems, 46(4): 145–169CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frankel, Alan S. (1998), ‘Monopoly and Competition in the Supply and Exchange of Money’, Antitrust Law Journal, 66(2): 313–361Google Scholar
Friberg, Richard (2001), ‘Two Monies, Two Markets? Variability and the Option to Segment’, Journal of International Economics, 55: 317–327CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, James (1971a), ‘A Non-cooperative Equilibrium for Supergames’, Review of Economic Studies, 38(113): 1–12CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, James (1971b), ‘A Non-cooperative View of Oligopoly’, International Economic Review, 12(1): 106–122CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, James (1983), ‘Advertising and Oligopolistic Equilibrium’, Bell Journal of Economics, 14: 464–473CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, James and Thisse, Jacques-François (1994), ‘Sustainable Collusion in Oligopoly with Free Entry’, European Economic Review, 38: 271–283CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fudenberg, Drew, Levine, David and Maskin, Eric (1994), ‘The Folk Theorem with Imperfect Public Information’, Econometrica, 62: 997–1039CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fumagalli, Chiara and Motta, Massimo (2006), ‘Exclusive Dealing and Entry: When Buyers Compete’, American Economic Review, 96(3): 785–795CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furse, Mark (2006), Competition Law of the EC and UK, 5th edition, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Gans, Joshua S. and King, Stephen P. (2000), ‘Mobile Network Competition, Customer Ignorance and Fixed-to-Mobile Call Prices’, Information Economics and Policy, 12(4): 301–328CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gans, Joshua S. and King, Stephen P. (2001), ‘Using “Bill and Keep” Interconnect Agreements to Soften Network Competition’, Economics Letters, 71(3): 413–420CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gans, Joshua S., King, Stephen P. and Wright, Julian (2005), ‘Wireless Communications’ in Majumdar, Sumit Kumar, Vogelsang, Ingo and Cave, Martin E. (eds.), Handbook of Telecommunications, Volume 2, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Genakos, Christos, Kühn, Kai-Uwe and Reenen, John (2006), ‘The Incentives of a Monopolist to Degrade Interoperability: Theory and Evidence from the PC and Server Market’, mimeo
Genakos, Christos and Valletti, Tommaso (2007), ‘Testing the “Waterbed” Effect in Mobile Telephony’, mimeo
Gerber, David J. (1998), Law and Competition in Twentieth Century Europe: Protecting Prometheus, Oxford: Clarendon PressGoogle Scholar
Geroski, Paul (2004), ‘Is Competition Policy Worth It?’, speech on the opening of the Centre for Competition Policy at the University of East Anglia, available at: www.competition-commission.org.uk/our_role/speeches/index.htm
Gilbert, Richard and Lieberman, Martin (1987), ‘Investment and Coordination in Oligopolistic Industries’, RAND Journal of Economics, 18: 17–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giotakos, Dimitri, Petit, Laurent, Garnier, Gaelle and Luyck, Peter (2001), ‘General Electric/Honeywell – An Insight into the Commission Investigation and Decision’, EC Competition Policy Newsletter, 3: 5–13
Goldberg, Pinelopi K. and Verboven, Frank (2001), ‘The Evolution of Price Dispersion in the European Car Market’, Review of Economic Studies, 68(4): 811–848CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberg, Pinelopi K. and Verboven, Frank (2005), ‘Market Integration and Convergence to the Law of One Price: Evidence from the European Car Market’, Journal of International Economics, 65(1): 49–73CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gollier, Christian and Schlesinger, Harris (1995), ‘Second-Best Insurance Contract Design in an Incomplete Market’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 97(1): 123–135CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grant, Jeremy and Neven, Damien (2005), ‘The Attempted Merger between General Electric and Honeywell: A Case of Transatlantic Conflict’, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 1: 595–633CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Green, Edward and Porter, Robert (1984), ‘Non Cooperative Collusion Under Imperfect Price Information’, Econometrica, 52: 87–100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griffin, Joseph P. (1998), ‘Foreign Governmental Reaction to US Assertion of Extraterritorial Jurisdiction’, European Competition Law Review, 19: 64–73Google Scholar
Gual, Jordi, Hellwig, Martin, Perrot, Anne, Polo, Michele, Rey, Patrick, Schmidt, Klaus and Stenbacka, Rune (2006), ‘An Economic Approach to Article 82’, Competition Policy International, 2(1): 111–154Google Scholar
Haltiwanger, John and Harrington, Joseph (1991), ‘The Impact of Cyclical Demand Movements in Collusive Behavior’, RAND Journal of Economics, 22: 89–106CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrington, Joseph E. (2004), ‘Post-cartel Pricing during Litigation’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 52(4): 517–533CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hart, Oliver (1983), ‘The Market Mechanism as an Incentive Scheme’, Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2): 366–382CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hatton, Catriona, Wagner, Christoph and Armengod, Hector (2007), ‘Fair Play: How Competition Authorities Have Regulated the Sale of Football Media Rights in Europe’, European Competition Law Review, 28(6): 346–354Google Scholar
Hausman, Jerry, Leonard, Gregory and Zona, J. Douglas (1994), ‘Competitive Analysis with Differentiated Products’, Annales d'Economie et de Statistique, 34: 159–180CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, Jerry and Leonard, Gregory (2005), ‘Using Merger Simulation Models: Testing the Underlying Assumptions’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23: 693–698CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, Jerry and Mackie-Mason, Jeffrey (1988), ‘Price Discrimination and Patent Policy’, RAND Journal of Economics, 19: 253–265CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1949), ‘The Meaning of Competition’ in Hayek, Friedrich A. (ed.), Individualism and Economic Order, London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Hayek, Friedrich A. (1960), The Constitution of Liberty, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Hendricks, Ken and Porter, Rob (2007), ‘An Empirical Perspective on Auctions’, in Armstrong, and Porter, (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Hicks, John R. (1935), ‘Annual Survey of Economic Theory: The Theory of Monopoly’, Econometrica, 3(1): 1–20CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoernig, Steffen (2007), ‘On-net and Off-net Pricing on Asymmetric Telecommunications Networks’, Information Economics and Policy, 19(2): 171–188CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holt, Charles A. (1995), ‘Industrial Organization: A Survey of Laboratory Research’ in Kagel, John Henry and Roth, Alvin E. (eds.), The Handbook of Experimental Economics, Princeton University Press, 349–443Google Scholar
,House of Lords (UK) (2006), Inntrepreneur v Crehan, UKHL 38; key earlier stages of this case can be found at (2003) EWHC 1510 (Ch) (Park J's High Court judgment), (2003) EuLR 663, (2004) EWCA Civ 637 (the Court of Appeal's judgment) and EuLR 693, also Courage Ltd v Crehan (Case C-453/99), (2002) QB 507
Ivaldi, Marc, Jullien, Bruno, Rey, Patrick, Seabright, Paul and Tirole, Jean (2003), ‘The Economics of Tacit Collusion’, Report for DG Competition, European Commission, available at: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/mergers/studies_reports/studies_reports.html
Ivaldi, Marc and Lorinscz, Szabeles (2004), ‘A Full Equilibrium Relevant Market Test: Application to Computer Servers’, mimeo, University of Toulouse
Ivaldi, Marc and Verboven, Frank (2005), ‘Quantifying the Effects from Horizontal Mergers: The European Heavy Trucks Market’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 23: 669–692CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iyer, Ganesh (1998), ‘Coordinating Channels under Price and Nonprice Competition’, Marketing Science, 17(4): 338–355CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jayaratne, Jith and Shapiro, Carl (2000), ‘Simulating Partial Asset Divestitures to “Fix” Mergers’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 7(2): 179–200CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenny, Frédéric (2002), ‘Pharmaceuticals, Competition and Free Movement of Goods’, EU Competition Law & Policy, Developments & Priorities, Helenic Competition Commission, Athens Conference, 19 April: 77–87
Jones, Alison and Sufrin, Brenda (2007), EC Competition Law: Text, Cases and Materials, 3rd edition, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Kandori, Michihiro and Matsushima, Hitoshi (1998), ‘Private Observation, Communication and Collusion’, Econometrica, 66: 627–652CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karlinger, Liliane and Motta, Massimo (2006), ‘Exclusionary Pricing and Rebates in a Network Industry’, mimeo, EUI
Kirzner, Israel M. (1978), Entrepreneurship and Competition, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
Klein, Benjamin and Lerner, Andres (eds.) (2008), Economics of Antitrust Law, Cheltenham: Edward ElgarCrossRef
Klein, Benjamin and Murphy, Kevin (1988), ‘Vertical Restraints as Contract Enforcement Mechanisms’, Journal of Law and Economics, 31(2): 265–297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klemperer, Paul (2007), ‘Bidding Markets’, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 3: 1–47CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klemperer, Paul D. and Meyer, Margaret A. (1989), ‘Supply Function Equilibrium in Oligopoly’, Econometrica, 57(6): 1243–1277CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kobayashi, Bruce H. (2001), ‘Antitrust, Agency and Amnesty: An Economic Analysis of the Criminal Enforcement of the Antitrust Laws against Corporations’, George Washington Law Review, 69(5–6): 715–744Google Scholar
Kobayashi, Bruce H. (2005), ‘The Economics of Loyalty Discounts and Antitrust Law in the United States’, Competition Policy International, 1(2): 115–148Google Scholar
Kolasky, William J. (2001), ‘Conglomerate Mergers and Range Effects: It's a Long Way From Chicago to Brussels’, speech made before the George Mason Symposium, Washington DC, 9 NovemberGoogle Scholar
Kolasky, William J. (2006), ‘GE/Honeywell: Narrowing, but Not Closing, the Gap’, Antitrust, 20(Spring): 69–76Google Scholar
Kovacic, William and Shapiro, Carl (2000), ‘Antitrust Policy: A Century of Economic and Legal Thinking’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1): 43–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,KPMG (2003), ‘Aalborg, Århus, Odense og Københavns Kommuner: (in Danish) Report on Calculation of Damages in Connection with the Trade Between [ABB] and the Municipalities During the Period 1991–1998’, Copenhagen
Kreps, David M. and Scheinkman, José A. (1983), ‘Quantity Precommitment and Bertrand Competition Yield Cournot Outcomes’, Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2): 326–337CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kroes, Neelie (2005), ‘The First Hundred Days’, 40th Anniversary of the Studienvereinigung Kartellrecht 1965–2005, International Forum on European Competition Law, Brussels, 7 April
Kühn, Kai-Uwe (2000), ‘An Economist's Guide through the Joint Dominance Jungle’, mimeo
Kühn, Kai-Uwe(2001a), ‘Fighting Collusion by Regulating Communication between Firms’, Economic Policy, 32: 169–204Google Scholar
Kühn, Kai-Uwe (2001b), ‘A Model of Collusion and Irreversible Investment’, mimeo, University of Michigan
Kühn, Kai-Uwe (2004), ‘The Coordinated Effects of Mergers in Differentiated Goods Markets’, CEPR Discussion Paper
Kuhn, Kai-Uwe(2005), ‘The Coordinated Effects of Mergers in Differentiated Products Markets’, CEPR Discussion Paper
Kühn, Kai-Uwe(2008), ‘The Coordinated Effects of Mergers’ in Buccirossi, Paolo (ed.), Handbook of Antitrust Economics, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Kühn, Kai-Uwe, Stillman, Robert and Caffara, Cristina (2005), ‘Economic Theories of Bundling and their Policy Implications in Abuse Cases: An Assessment in Light of the Microsoft Case’, European Competition Journal, 1: 85–122CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kühn, Kai-Uwe and Vives, Xavier (1995), ‘Information Exchanges among Firms and their Impact on Competition’, Office for Official Publications of the European Community, Luxembourg
Kwoka, John and White, Larry (1989), The Antitrust Revolution: Economics, Competition and Policy, 1st Edition (now in its 5th Edition), New York: Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Lademann, Rainer P. (2001), ‘Customer Preferences for Existing and Potential Sales and Servicing Alternatives in Automotive Distribution’, study prepared for the European Commission
Laffont, Jean-Jacques, Rey, Patrick and Tirole, Jean (1998), ‘Network Competition: II. Price Discrimination’, RAND Journal of Economics, 29(1): 38–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lafontaine, Francine and Slade, Margaret E. (2008), ‘Exclusive Contracts and Vertical Restraints: Empirical Evidence and Public Policy’, in Paolo Bucciross (ed.) Handbook of Antitrust Economics, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 391–414
Lafontaine, Francine and Slade, Margaret E.(2007), ‘Vertical Integration and Firm Boundaries: The Evidence’, Journal of Economic Literature, 45: 631–687CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lal, Rajiv and Rao, Ram (1997), ‘Supermarket Competition: The Case of Every Day Low Pricing’, Marketing Science, 16(1): 60–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lambson, Val E. (1994), ‘Some Results on Optimal Penal Codes in Asymmetric Bertrand Supergames’, Journal of Economic Theory, 62(2): 444–468CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Landes, William M. (1983), ‘Optimal Sanctions for Antitrust Violations’, University of Chicago Law Review, 50(2): 652–678CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leibenstein, Harvey (1966), ‘Allocative Efficiency vs. “X-Efficiency”’, American Economic Review, 56(3): 392–415Google Scholar
Leibenstein, Harvey (1973), ‘Competition and X-Efficiency: Reply’, Journal of Political Economy, 81(3): 765–777CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levenstein, Margaret and Suslow, Valerie Y. (2003), ‘Contemporary International Cartels and Developing Countries: Economic Effects and Implications for Competition Policy’, Antitrust Law Journal, 71(3): 801–852Google Scholar
,Lexecon (1985), The Economics of Gray-Markets Imports, ChicagoGoogle Scholar
,Lexicon Ltd(1999), ‘Joint Dominance’, Competition memo, London
,London Economics (1997), ‘Competition in Retailing’, Research Paper No. 13, London: Office of Fair Trading
Lowe, Philip (2006), ‘The Evolution and Regulation of the Payments System’, address to the Payments System Conference at Melbourne Business School, March
Lyons, Bruce (2007), ‘The Paradox of the Exclusion of Exploitative Abuse’, Chapter 3 in The Pros and Cons of High Prices, Swedish Competition Authority, 32–46CrossRef
Lyons, Bruce (2009), ‘An Economic Assessment of EC Merger Control: 1958–2007’, CCP Working Paper 08–17, in Vives, Xavier (ed.) (2009), Competition Policy in the EU: Fifty Years on from the Treaty of Rome, Oxford University Press, Ch. 6, 135–175Google Scholar
Macieira, João (2006), ‘Extending the Frontier: A Structural Model of Investment and Technological Competition in the Supercomputer Industry’, mimeo, Northwestern University
Malueg, David A. and Schwartz, Marius (1994), ‘Parallel Imports, Demand Dispersion and International Price Discrimination’, Journal of International Economics, 37(3–4): 167–195CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, Stephen (2001), Advanced Industrial Economics, 2nd edition, Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Mathewson, Frank and Winter, Ralph (1984), ‘An Economic Theory of Vertical Restraints’, RAND Journal of Economics, 15(1): 27–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matsushima, Hitoshi (1989), ‘Efficiency in Repeated Games with Imperfect Monitoring’, Journal of Economic Theory, 48: 428–442CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McAfee, R. Preston, McMillan, John and Whinston, Michael D. (1989), ‘Multiproduct Monopoly, Commodity Bundling, and Correlation of Values’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 104(2): 371–384CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McFadden, Daniel (1974), ‘Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behavior’ in Zarembka, Paul (ed.), Frontiers in Econometrics, New York: Academic Press, 105–142Google Scholar
McGuire, Timothy W. and Staelin, Richard (1983), ‘An Industry Equilibrium Analysis of Downstream Vertical Integration’, Marketing Science, 2(2): 161–192CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Megginson, William L. and Netter, Jeffrey M. (2001), ‘From State to Market: A Survey of Empirical Studies on Privatization’, Journal of Economic Literature, 39(2): 321–389CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melnik, Arie, Shy, Oz and Stenbacka, Rune (2008), ‘Assessing Market Dominance’, Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 68(1): 63–72CrossRef
Mittal, Vittas, Kumar, Pankaj and Tsiros, Michael (1999), ‘Attribute-Level Performance, Satisfaction and Behavioural Intentions over Time: a Consumption-System Decision Approach’, Journal of Marketing, 63: 88–101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Monopolies and Mergers Commission (1981), ‘Discounts to Retailers’, HC 311, London: HMSO
,Monopolies and Mergers Commission(1989), ‘The Supply of Beer’, London: HMSO
,Monopolies and Mergers Commission(1997), ‘Bass PLC, Carlsberg A/S, and Carlsberg–Tetley PLC: A Report on the Merger Situation’, London: HMSO
,Monopolies and Mergers Commission(1999a), ‘British Telecommunications plc: A Report on a Reference Under Section 13 of Telecommunications Act 1984 for Calls Made from its Subscribers to Phones Connected to the Networks of Cellnet and Vodafone’, London: HMSO
,Monopolies and Mergers Commission(1999b), ‘Cellnet and Vodafone: A Report on a Reference Under Section 13 of Telecommunications Act 1984 on the Charges Made by Cellnet and Vodafone for Terminating Calls from Fixed-Line Networks’, London: HMSO
Mossin, Jan (1968), ‘Aspects of Rational Insurance Purchasing’, Journal of Political Economy, 76: 533–568CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Motta, Massimo (2004), Competition Policy: Theory and Practice, Cambridge University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Motta, Massimo and Rønde, Thomas (2006), ‘Exclusive Contracts: Between Foreclosure and Protection of Investments’, mimeo, EUI
Nalebuff, Barry J. (2000), ‘Competing Against Bundles’ in Hammond, Peter and Myles, Gareth D. (eds.), Incentives, Organisation, Public Economics, London: Oxford University Press, 323–336Google Scholar
Nalebuff, Barry J. (2003), ‘Bundling, Tying and Portfolio Effects: Part 2 – Case Studies’, DTI Economic Paper 1, London
Nalebuff, Barry J. and Lu, Shihua (2001), ‘A Bundle of Trouble’, Yale School of Management Working Paper
Nazzini, Renato (2003), ‘Parallel Trade in the Pharmaceutical Market, Current Trends and Future Solutions’, World Competition, 26(1): 53–74Google Scholar
Neven, Damien J. (2006), ‘Competition Economics and Antitrust in Europe’, Economic Policy, 21(48): 741–791CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nevo, Aviv (2000), ‘Mergers with Differentiated Products: The Case of the Ready-to-Eat Cereal Industry’, RAND Journal of Economics, 31(3): 395–421CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nickell, Stephen (1996), ‘Competition and Corporate Performance’, Journal of Political Economy, 104: 724–746CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nickell, Stephen, Nicolitsas, Daphne and Dryden, Neil (1997), ‘What Makes Firms Perform Well?’, European Economic Review, 41: 783–796CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. (1991), ‘Institutions’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1): 97–112CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Ofcom (2006), ‘Mobile Call Termination: Market Review’, London: Office of Communications
,Office of Fair Trading (1989), ‘Supply of Beer (Tied Estate) Order’, SI 1989 No. 2390
,Office of Fair Trading(2003), ‘The British Horseracing Board and the Jockey Club: A Summary of the OFT's Case’, OFT654, April
,Office of Fair Trading(2006), ‘The Grocery Market: The OFT's Reasons for Making a Reference to the Competition Commission’, OFT845, May
Olley, Stephen and Pakes, Ariel (1996), ‘The Dynamics of Productivity in the Telecommunications Equipment Industry’, Econometrica, 64(6): 1263–1297CrossRefGoogle Scholar
,Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (1997), ‘Market Access Issues in the Automobile Sector’, OECD proceedings
,Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development(2000), Review of Regulatory Reform in Italy, Chapter 1: ‘The Role of Competition Policy’
,Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development(2003), Review of Regulatory Reform in France, Chapter 3: ‘The Role of Competition Policy’
,Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development(2004), Review of Regulatory Reform in Germany, Chapter 3: ‘The Role of Competition Policy’
,Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development(2005), Competition Law and Policy in the EU
Osborne, Martin J. and Pitchik, Carolyn (1987), ‘Cartels, Profits and Excess Capacity’, International Economic Review, 28(2): 413–428CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Patterson, Donna and Shapiro, Carl (2001), ‘Transatlantic Divergence in GE/Honeywell: Causes and Lessons’, Antitrust, 16(Fall): 32–33Google Scholar
Pepall, Lynne, Richards, Dan and Norman, George (2008), Industrial Organization: Contemporary Theory and Empirical Applications, 4th edition, Oxford: BlackwellGoogle Scholar
Perry, Martin K. and Besanko, David (1991), ‘Resale Price Maintenance and Manufacturer Competition for Exclusive Dealerships’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 39(5): 517–544CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phlips, Louis (1983), The Economics of Price Discrimination, Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Pinkse, Joris and Slade, Margaret E. (2004), ‘Mergers, Brand Competition, and the Price of a Pint’, European Economic Review, 48: 617–643CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pinkse, Joris, Slade, Margaret E. and Brett, Craig (2002), ‘Spatial Price Competition: A Semiparametric Approach’, Econometrica, 70(3): 1111–1155CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Majoras, Platt, Deborah (2001), ‘GE-Honeywell: The US Decision’, speech made before the Anti-Trust Section of the State Bar of Georgia, 29 November
Plott, Charles R. and Smith, Vernon L. (2008), Handbook of Results in Experimental Economics, Volume 1, place: ElsevierGoogle Scholar
Polinsky, A. Mitchell and Shavell, Steven (1994), ‘Should Liability Be Based on the Harm to the Victim or the Gain to the Injurer?’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 10(2): 427–437Google Scholar
Porter, Robert H. (1983a), ‘Optimal Cartel Trigger Price Strategies’, Journal of Economic Theory, 29: 313–338CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, Robert H. (1983b), ‘A Study of Cartel Stability: The Joint Executive Committee, 1880–1886’, Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2): 301–314CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porter, Robert H. (2005), ‘Detecting Collusion’, Review of Industrial Organization, 26(2): 147–167CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard (1976), Antitrust Law, University of Chicago PressGoogle Scholar
,PricewaterhouseCoopers (2002), ALSTOM PowerFlowSystems A/S (in Danish): ‘Report A: Theoretical and Analytical Framework for Determination of Economic Effects of an Alleged Cartel Formation’; ‘Report B: Description of Plaintiffs’ Models for Calculating Damages'; ‘Report C: Comments on the Plaintiffs’ Models for Calculating Damages'; ‘Report D: Alternative Calculation of Damages based on ALSTOM's Actual Transactions’; ‘Report E: Alternative Calculation of Damages based on ALSTOM's Economic Profit’, Hellerup, Copenhagen
Punj, Girish and Brookes, Richard (2002), ‘The Influence of Pre-Decisional Constraints on Information Search and Consideration Set Formation in New Automobile Purchases’, International Journal of Research in Marketing, 19(4): 383–400CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raskovich, Alexander (2003), ‘Pivotal Buyers and Bargaining Position’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 51(4): 405–426CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rasmusen, Eric, Ramseyer, J. Mark and Wiley, John S. (1991), ‘Naked Exclusion’, American Economic Review, 81(5): 1137–1145Google Scholar
Rey, Patrick (2003), ‘The Impact of Parallel Imports on Prescription Medicines’, mimeo, University of Toulouse
Rey, Patrick and Stiglitz, Joseph (1995), ‘The Role of Exclusive Territories in Producers’ Competition', RAND Journal of Economics, 26(3): 431–451CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rey, Patrick and Tirole, Jean (2007), ‘A Primer on Foreclosure’, in Armstrong, and Porter, (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, Amsterdam: North HollandGoogle Scholar
Reynolds, Robert J. and Ordover, Janusz (2002), ‘Archimedean Leveraging and the GE/Honeywell Transaction’, Antitrust Law Journal, 70: 171–198Google Scholar
Richardson, Russell (1999), ‘Guidance without Guidance – A European Revolution in Fining Policy? The Commission's New Guidelines on Fines’, European Competition Law Review, 20(7): 360–371Google Scholar
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Tirole, Jean (2002), ‘Cooperation among Competitors: Some Economics of Payment Card Associations’, RAND Journal of Economics, 33(4): 549–570CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Tirole, Jean (2003a), ‘An Economic Analysis of the Determination of Interchange Fees in Payment Card Systems’, Review of Network Economics, 2(2): 69–79CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Tirole, Jean (2003b), ‘Platform Competition in Two-Sided Markets’, Journal of the European Economics Association, 1(4): 990–1209CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Tirole, Jean (2006a), ‘Tying in Two-Sided Markets and the Honour-All-Cards Rule’, mimeo, IDEI, Toulouse University
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Tirole, Jean (2006b), ‘Must-Take Cards and the Tourist Test’, mimeo, IDEI, Toulouse University
Rochet, Jean-Charles and Tirole, Jean (2006c), ‘Two-Sided Markets: A Progress Report’, RAND Journal of Economics, Special Issue on Two-Sided Markets, 37(3): 645–663CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Thomas (1992), ‘Cartel Stability and Product Differentiation’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 10: 1–13CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, Julio and Saloner, Gapth (1986), ‘A Supergame Theoretic Model of Price Wars during Booms’, American Economic Review, 76: 390–407Google Scholar
Rubinfeld, D. (2004), 'Maintenance of Monopoly: U.S. vs. Microsoft (2001)', Case 19 in Kwoka, John E. and White, Lawrence J. (eds.), The Anti-Trust Revolution, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Sachs, Jeffrey (1993), Poland's Jump to the Market Economy, Lionel Robbins Lectures, Cambridge, Mass. and London: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Scherer, Mike and Ross, David (1990), Industrial Market Structure and Economic Performance, Boston, Mass.: Houghton Mifflin CompanyGoogle Scholar
Schmalensee, Richard (1987), ‘Competitive Advantage and Collusive Optima’, International Journal of Industrial Economics, 5: 351–367Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1943), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Segal, Ilya R. and Whinston, Michael D. (2000a), ‘Naked Exclusion: Comment’, American Economic Review, 90: 296–309CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Segal, Ilya R. and Whinston, Michael D. (2000b), ‘Exclusive Contracts and Protection of Investment’, RAND Journal of Economics, 31: 603–633CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, Amartya K. (1993), ‘Markets and Freedoms: the Achievements and Limitations of the Market Mechanisms in Promoting Individual Freedoms’, Oxford Economic Papers, 45(4): 519–541CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Carl (1989), ‘Theories of Oligopoly Behavior’ in Schmalensee, Richard and Willig, Robert D. (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 1, Amsterdam: North Holland/Elsevier Science Publishers, 329–414Google Scholar
Sibley, David S. and Heyer, Ken (2003), ‘Selected Economic Analysis at the Antitrust Division: The Year in Review’, Review of Industrial Organization, 23(2): 95–119CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slade, Margaret E. (1998), ‘Beer and the Tie: Did Divestiture of Brewer-owned Public Houses Lead to Higher Beer Prices?’, Economic Journal, 108: 565–602CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slade, Margaret E. (2000), ‘Regulating Manufacturers and Their Exclusive Retailers’ in Berg, Morten and Hope, Einar (eds.), Foundations of Competition Policy, London: RoutledgeGoogle Scholar
Slade, Margaret E. (2004a), ‘Market Power and Joint Dominance in the UK Brewing Industry’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 52: 133–163CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Slade, Margaret E. (2004b), ‘Models of Firm Profitability’, International Journal of Industrial Organization, 22: 289–308CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Adam (1776), An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Smith, Howard (2004), ‘Supermarket Choice and Supermarket Competition in Market Equilibrium’, Review of Economic Studies, 71(1): 235–263CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spector, David (2005), ‘Loyalty Rebates: An Assessment of Competition Concerns and a Proposed Structured Rule of Reason’, Competition Policy International, 1(2): 89–114Google Scholar
Spengler, Joseph J. (1950), ‘Vertical Integration and Anti-Trust Policy’, Journal of Political Economy, 58(4): 347–352CrossRefGoogle Scholar
München, Staatsanwaltschaft (2005), Anklageschrift, Beglaubigte Abschrift, Munich, 18 March
Staiger, Robert W. and Wolak, Frank A. (1992), ‘Collusive Pricing with Capacity Constraints in the Presence of Demand Uncertainty’, RAND Journal of Economics, 23(2): 203–220CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Steen, Frode and Sorgard, Lars (1999), ‘Semicollusion in the Norwegian Cement Market’, European Economic Review, 43(9): 1775–1796CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stein, Jeremy C. (1997), ‘Internal Capital Markets and the Competition for Corporate Resources’, Journal of Finance, 52(1): 111–133CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stephan, Andreas (2006), ‘The Bankruptcy Wildcard in Cartel Cases’, Journal of Business Law, August: 511–534Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. (1964), ‘A Theory of Oligopoly’, The Journal of Political Economy, 72(1): 44–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George (1976), ‘The Xistence of X-Efficiency’, American Economic Review, 66(1): 213–216Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. (1987), ‘Competition’ in Durlauf, S. N. and Blume, L. E. (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, reprinted in 2008 edition, Palgrave MacmillanGoogle Scholar
Sutton, John (2007), ‘Market Structure: Theory and Evidence’, in Armstrong, and Porter, (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Volume 3, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Telser, Lester G. (1960), ‘Why Should Manufacturers Want Fair Trade?’, Journal of Law and Economics, 3: 86–105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thisse, Jacques-François and Vives, Xavier (1988), ‘On the Strategic Choice of Spatial Price Policy’, American Economic Review, 78(1): 122–137Google Scholar
Tirole, Jean (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
,US Department of Justice (2001), ‘Range Effects: The United States Perspective’, Antitrust Division Submission for OECD Roundtable on Portfolio Effects in Conglomerate Mergers, downloadable at http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/international/9550.htm
Reenen, John (2004), ‘Is There a Market for Workgroup Servers?’, Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper No. 650
Reenen, John (2006), ‘The Growth of Network Computing: Quality Adjusted Prices for Network Servers’, Economic Journal, 116: 29–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, Hal (1985), ‘Price Discrimination and Social Welfare’, American Economic Review, 75: 870–875Google Scholar
Varian, Hal (1989), ‘Price Discrimination’ in Schmalensee, Richard and Willig, Robert D. (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Amsterdam: North-HollandGoogle Scholar
Veljanovski, Cento (2007), ‘Cartel Fines in Europe – Law, Practice and Deterrence’, World Competition, 30: 65–86Google Scholar
Verboven, Frank (1996), ‘International Price Discrimination in the European Car Market’, RAND Journal of Economics, 27(2): 240–268CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Verhoef, Peter and Langerak, Fred (2003), ‘On the Role of Dealers in Brand Loyalty Decisions in the Automotive Industry’, mimeo, Erasmus University, Rotterdam
Verouden, Vincent (2004), ‘Vertical Agreements and Article 81(1) EC: The Evolving Role of Economic Analysis’, Antitrust Law Journal, 71: 525–575Google Scholar
Vickers, John (1995), ‘Concepts of Competition’, Oxford Economic Papers, 47(1): 1–23CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickers, John (2005), ‘Public Policy and the Invisible Price: Competition Law, Regulation, and the Interchange Fee’, presented at the International Payments Policy Conference: ‘Interchange Fees in Credit and Debit Card Industries: What Role for Public Authorities?’ at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
Vickers, John (2006), ‘Discussion of Neven (2006)’, Economic Policy, 21(48): 781–786Google Scholar
Vives, Xavier (1999), Oligopoly Pricing: Old Ideas and New Tools, Boston: MIT PressGoogle Scholar
Vives, Xavier (2008), ‘Innovation and Competitive Pressure’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 56(3): 419–469CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vives, Xavier (ed.) (2009), Competition Policy in the EU: Fifty Years on from the Treaty of Rome, forthcoming, Oxford University PressCrossRef
Waelbroeck, Denis (2005), ‘Michelin II: A per se Rule Against Rebates by Dominant Companies?’, Journal of Competition Law and Economics, 1(1): 149–171CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Werden, Gregory (2001), ‘Microsoft's Pricing of Windows and the Economics of Derived Demand Monopoly’, Review of Industrial Organization, 18: 357–362Google Scholar
Werden, Gregory J. and Froeb, Luke M. (1994), ‘The Effects of Mergers in Differentiated Products Industries: Logit Demand and Merger Policy’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 10: 407–426Google Scholar
Werden, Gregory J. and Froeb, Luke M.(2002), ‘The Antitrust Logit Model for Predicting Unilateral Competitive Effects’, Antitrust Law Journal, 70: 257Google Scholar
Werden, Gregory J., Froeb, Luke M. and Tardiff, Timothy J. (1996), ‘The Use of the Logit Model in Applied Industrial Organization’, International Journal of the Economics of Business, 3(1), 83–105CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whinston, Michael D. (1990), ‘Tying, Foreclosure, and Exclusion’, American Economic Review, 80(4): 837–859Google Scholar
Whinston, Michael D.(2001), ‘Exclusivity and Tying in US v. Microsoft: What We Know, and Don't Know’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15(2): 63–80CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whish, Richard (2003), Competition Law, 3rd edition, London: ButterworthsGoogle Scholar
Whish, Richard (2008), Competition Law, 6th edition, London: LexisNexis UKCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wijckmans, Frank, Tuytschaever, Filip and Vanderelst, Alain (2006), ‘The Motor Vehicle Distribution Block Exemption’ in Wijckmans, Frank, Tuytschaever, Filip and Vanderelst, Alain (eds.), Vertical Agreements in EC Competition Law, Oxford University PressGoogle Scholar
Wilks, Stephen (1999), In the Public Interest: Competition Policy and the Monopolies and Mergers Commission, Manchester University PressGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1976), ‘Franchise Bidding for Natural Monopolies: In General and with Respect to CATV’, Bell Journal of Economics, 7(1): 73–104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: Macmillan Free PressGoogle Scholar
Wils, Wouter P. J. (1998), ‘The Commission's New Method for Calculating Fines in Antitrust Cases’, European Law Review, 23(3): 252–263Google Scholar
Wils, Wouter P. J. (2006), ‘Optimal Antitrust Fines: Theory and Practice’, World Competition, 29(2): 183–208Google Scholar
Wright, Julian (2002), ‘Access Pricing under Competition: An Application to Cellular Networks’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 50(3): 289–316CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wright, Julian (2003), ‘Optimal Card Payment Systems’, European Economic Review, 47(4): 587–612CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Edited by Bruce Lyons, University of East Anglia
  • Book: Cases in European Competition Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511803130.025
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Edited by Bruce Lyons, University of East Anglia
  • Book: Cases in European Competition Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511803130.025
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Edited by Bruce Lyons, University of East Anglia
  • Book: Cases in European Competition Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511803130.025
Available formats
×