Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T13:04:37.956Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

7 - Optimal Tontine: Hedging (Some) Longevity Risk

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 May 2015

Moshe A. Milevsky
Affiliation:
York University, Toronto
Get access

Summary

A RATIONAL PROBLEM WITH TONTINE'S UTILITY

Up to this point in the narrative I haven't really opined about or addressed the issue of optimal tontine design versus suboptimal design from the perspective of economic theory. Sure, I have introduced the idea of “tontine thinking” and the sharing principle, including examples of many different tontine schemes. I have discussed their historical features, focused on their payout rates, and examined whether their yield was fair, relative to prevailing interest rates and competing products. I even touched on good tontines and bad tontines from a moral or ethical viewpoint. But thus far I have stayed clear of economic theory. In this chapter I will go one level deeper – which gets a bit more technical, as well – and address the economic properties of the scheme itself and some of the rational aspects of their design. I will introduce and discuss something called Jared's retirement tontine, which has some similarities to the historical design but differs in some important ways.

To put this all in perspective and set the context for this chapter, think about the following questions: How would the rational and logical Mr. Spock design a tontine scheme? And, how might it differ from the 300-year-old design of King William's tontine?

For starters, the single biggest problem with most historical tontine schemes – whether they are equity or debt or whether they are of Type 1, Type 2, or Type 3 – can be seen in the “winner take all” picture displayed in Figure 7.1. The graph displays the range of possible payouts to the tontine annuitant/nominee – assuming they are still alive – at ages ranging from 65 to 100. This example or picture assumes that a tontine scheme with 400 members is initiated at the age of sixty-five and the (constant) payout to the entire pool is a constant 4% per year.

Type
Chapter
Information
King William's Tontine
Why the Retirement Annuity of the Future Should Resemble its Past
, pp. 140 - 169
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×