Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-m9kch Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-21T18:40:26.427Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

On the Genesis of the Canonical Labor Supply Model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 June 2009

Laurent Derobert
Affiliation:
Université d'Aix-Marseille, Faculté d'Economie Appliquée; and GREQAM, 15–19 allée Claude Forbin, 13627 Aix-en-Provence, France.

Extract

The individual's labor supply model, usually called leisure-income, is very well known in labor economics. It determines the time a person spends on the labor market by studying it as the outcome of a trade-off between leisure and income. The model is developed in almost every book on microeconomics. But strangely enough, although all economists know the model, no one seems to know precisely its origins.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2001

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Ashenfelter, Orley and Layard, Richard, eds. 1986. Handbook of Labor Economics. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Bachelard, Gaston. 1938. La formation de l'esprit scientifique. Paris: Vrin.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary. 1965. “A Theory of the Allocation of Time.” Economic Journal 75: 493517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1939. The Incidence of Income Taxes. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1968. Economic Theory in Retrospect. London: Richard D Irwin, 1973.Google Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth. 1941. Economic Analysis. New York: Harper & Row, 1964.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James. 1971. “The Backbending Supply Curve of Labor: An Example of Doctrinal Retrogression?History of Political Economy 3: 383–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cahuc, Pierre and Zylberberg, André. 1996. Economie du travail. Paris: De Boeck.Google Scholar
Chapman, Sidney. 1909. “Hours of Labour.” Economic Journal 19: 355–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, Gershon. 1952a. “Taxation and Incentive in Mobilization.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 66: 4366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cooper, Gershon. 1952b. “Taxation and Incentive in Mobilization: A Reply.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 66: 609–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deaton, Augustus and Muellbauer, John. 1980. Economics and Consumer Behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demaria, Giovanni. 1933. “L'offerta individuate di lavoro e le sue limitazione.” Giornale degli Economisti 38: 549–70.Google Scholar
Derobert, Laurent. 2000. “Etude sur la genèse edu modèle canonique d'offre individuelle de travail.” Working Paper, Marseille: GREQAM.Google Scholar
Dobb, Maurice. 1927. Wages. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1948.Google Scholar
Douglas, Paul. 1934. Theory of Wages. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1957.Google Scholar
Ehrenbeg, Ronald and Smith, Robert. 1982. Modem Labor Economies. Glenview, IL: Scott, Foresman & Co.Google Scholar
Finegan, Thomas. 1960. Hours of Work in the United States. Ph.D. Dissertation. Chicago: University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Fleisher, Belton. 1970. Labor Economics: Theory and Evidence. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1953. “The Methodology of Positive Economics.” In Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Frisch, Ragnar. 1932. New Methods of Measuring Marginal Utility. Tübingen: Verlag von J. C. B. Mohr.Google Scholar
Gazier, Bernard. 1992. Economie du travail et de l'emploi. Paris: Dalloz.Google Scholar
Gilbert, Franklee and Pfouts, Ralph. 1958. “A Theory of the Responsiveness of Hours of Work to Changes in Wage Rate.” Review of Economics and Statistics 40: 116–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goode, Richard. 1949. “The Income Tax and the Supply of Labor.” Journal of Political Economy 57: 428–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gossen, Hermann Heinrich. 1854. Exposition des lois de l'échange et des règles de l'industrie qui s'en déduisent. Paris: Economica, 1995.Google Scholar
Henderson, A. 1948. “The Case for Direct Taxation.” Economic Journal 58: 538553.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, John. 1932. The Theory of Wages. London: Macmillan, 1964.Google Scholar
Hicks, John. 1939. Value and Capital. Oxford: The Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Jevons, William Stanley. 1871. The Theory of Political Economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1965.Google Scholar
Kaufman, Bruce. 1986. The Economics of Labor Markets. Orlando: Dryden Press, 1994.Google Scholar
Keynes, John M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Cambridge: Macmillan, 1973.Google Scholar
Killingsworth, Mark. 1983. Labor Supply. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
King, J. L. 1972. Labour Economics. London: Macmillan, 1990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knight, Frank. 1921. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. London: London School of Economics and Political Science, 1940.Google Scholar
Launhardt, Wilhelm. 1885. Mathematical Principles of Economics. Hants: Edward Elgar, 1993.Google Scholar
Lewis, H. G. 1957. “Hours of Work and Hours of Leisure.” In Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Meeting, Madison: Industrial Relations Research Association, pp. 195206.Google Scholar
Linder, Staffan. 1970. The Harried Leisure Class. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred. 1890. Principles of Economics. London: Macmillan, 1961.Google Scholar
Menger, Carl. 1871. Principles of Economics. New York: New York University Press, 1981.Google Scholar
Mering, Otto von. 1942. The Shifting and Incidence of Taxation. Philadelphia: Blakiston.Google Scholar
Mering, Otto von. 1952. “Taxation and Incentive in Mobilization: Further Comment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 66: 605609.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mincer, Jacob. 1993. Studies in Labor Supply. Collected Essays of Jacob Mincer, Vol 2. Hants, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Owen, John. 1964. The Supply of Labor and the Demand for Recreation in the United States, 1900–1961. Ph.D. Dissertation, Columbia University.Google Scholar
Paish, F. W. 1941. “Economic Incentive in War Time.” Economica 8: 239–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pencavel, John. 1986. “Labor Supply of Men: A Survey.” In Ashenfelter, O. and Layard, R., eds., Handbook of Labor Economics, Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Perlman, Richard. 1969. Labor Theory. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1920. The Economics of Welfare. London: Macmillan, 1960.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1928. A Study in Public Finance. London: Macmillan, 1949.Google Scholar
Rebeyrol, Antoine 1999. La pensée économique de Walras. Paris: Dunod.Google Scholar
Reynolds, Lloyd. 1949. Labor Economies and Labor Relations. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1974.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. 1930. “On the Elasticity of the Demand for Income in Terms of Effort.” Economica 10: 123–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sapsford, David and Tzannatos, Zafiris. 1993. The Economics of the Labour Market. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor. 1951. Welfare and Competition. Chicago: Richard D. Irwin.Google Scholar
Sourdain, Robert. 1966. “La courbe d'offre individuelle de travail.” Revue économique 17: 603–35.Google Scholar
Stackelberg, Heinrich von. 1948. The Theory of the Market Economy. London: William Hodge, 1952.Google Scholar
Stigler, George. 1941. Production and Distribution Theories. New York: Macmillan, 1949.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein. 1899. The Theory of the Leisure Class. New York: New American Library, 1953.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein. 1909. “The Limitations of Marginal Utility.” Journal of Political Economy 17: 620–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wald, Haskeil. 1945. “The Classical Indictment of Indirect Taxation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 59: 577–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walras, Léon. 1874. Eléments d'économie politique pure. Paris: Economica, 1988.Google Scholar
Whorf, B. Lee. 1956. Language, Thought and Reality. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Wicksell, Knut. 1901. Lectures on Political Economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley, 1967.Google Scholar
Wicksteed, Philip 1910. The Common Sense of Political Economy. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Wisman, Jon. 1989. “Straightening out the Backward-bending Supply Curve of Labour.” Review of Political Economy 1: 94112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar