Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T17:58:15.767Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Institutional selection in international relations: state anarchy as order

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

Hendrik Spruyt
Affiliation:
Member of the Institute of War and Peace Studies and an Assistant Professor in the Department of Political Science at Columbia University, New York.
Get access

Abstract

By the end of the medieval era, three new competing institutions attempted to capture gains from trade and reduce feudal particularism: sovereign territorial states, cityleagues, and city-states. By the middle of the seventeenth century, city-leagues and city-states had declined markedly. Territorial states survived as the dominant form because they were able to reduce free riding, lower transaction costs, and credibly commit their constituents. The selection process took place along three dimensions. First, sovereign territorial states proved competitively superior in the economic realm. Second, states increasingly recognized only other sovereign territorial states as legitimate actors in the international system. Third, other actors defected to or copied the institutional makeup of sovereign territorial organization. The emergence of discrete territorial units in which only sovereign authorities represented their citizens as the predominant type of organization in international affairs created a new solution to the problem of markets and hierarchies.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1994

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1. In the following pages I sometimes denote “sovereign territorial state” with either the term “territorial state” or “sovereign state.” These terms all refer to a particular form of government wherein authority claims internal hierarchy and recognizes no higher authority beyond its borders. For this definition see Benn, Stanley, “Sovereignty,” in The Encyclopedia of Philosophy (New York: Macmillan, 1967), pp. 501–5Google Scholar.

2. The term “international” semantically prejudges the issue, since it is an anachronism for this period.

3. For an argument that these three institutional arrangements had run their course by 1300, see Tilly, Charles, ed., The Formation of National States in Western Europe (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1975), p. 26Google Scholar.

4. For a discussion of the various meanings of the term “state,” see Nettl, J. P., “The State as a Conceptual Variable,” World Politics 20 (Summer 1968), pp. 559–92CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

5. The literature on emergent capitalism ranges in perspective from a neo-Marxist one to a liberal economic one, focusing on property rights and individual incentives. For an example of the former perspective, see Anderson, Perry, Lineages of the Absolutist State (London: Verso, 1974)Google Scholar; and Wallerstein, Immanuel, The Modern World System, vol. 1 (New York: Academic Press, 1974)Google Scholar. For the public choice approach, see North, Douglass and Thomas, Robert, The Rise of the Western World (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1973)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; North, Douglass, Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: W. W. Norton, 1981)Google Scholar; and Levi, Margaret, Of Rule and Revenue (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1988)Google Scholar.

6. I define transaction costs as the costs of arranging a contract ex ante and monitoring and enforcing it ex post. See Eggertson, Thrain, Economic Behavior and Institutions (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), p. 14CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

7. This lies in contrast to Waltz's view of international systems. His argument is that such systems vary only by ordering principle and capabilities. See Waltz, Kenneth, Theory of International Politics (New York: Random House, 1979), pp. 82ffGoogle Scholar. While both ordering principle and capability remain critical elements in any understanding of international affairs, they alone do not determine structure. In other realist understandings, the most fundamental type of change in the international system is that of unit change. See Gilpin, Robert, War and Change in World Politics (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1981), pp. 3942CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8. See Thelen, Kathleen and Steinmo, Sven, “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics,” in Steinmo, Sven, Thelen, Kathleen, and Longstreth, Frank, eds., Structuring Politics (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1992), pp. 132Google Scholar; and Caporaso, James, “Microeconomics and International Political Economy: The Neoclassical Approach to Institutions,” in Czempiel, Ernst-Otto and Rosenau, James, eds., Global Changes and Theoretical Challenges (Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath, 1989), pp. 135–59Google Scholar.

9. For excellent overviews of the literature, see Moe, Terry, “New Economics of Organization,” American Journal of Political Science 28 (11 1984), pp. 739–77CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Yarborough, Beth and Yarborough, Robert, “International Institutions and the New Economics of Organization,” International Organization 44 (Spring 1990), pp. 235–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

10. See, for example, the discussion on reneging by Yarborough, Beth and Yarborough, Robert, Cooperation and Governance in International Trade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1992), pp. 14ffGoogle Scholar. For an example of how actors seek to devise institutions to limit ex post reneging in foreign investments, see Lipson, Charles, Standing Guard (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985)Google Scholar.

11. For one account that uses such “entrepreneurial logic” see Friedman, David, “A Theory of the Size and Shape of Nations,” Journal of Political Economy, vol. 85, no. 1, 1977, pp. 5977CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

12. See Williamson, Oliver, Markets and Hierarchies (New York: The Free Press, 1975)Google Scholar; and Williamson, Oliver, Economic Organization (New York: New York University Press, 1986)Google Scholar.

13. For an expansion of this logic to the integration of states, see Beth Yarborough and Robert Yarborough, “International Contracting and Territorial Control: The Boundary Question,” Journal of Theoretical and Institutional Economics, forthcoming.

14. The standard argument is by Olson, Mancur, The Logic of Collective Action (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1965)Google Scholar. See also Hardin, Russell, Collective Action (Washington, D.C.: Resources for the Future, 1982)Google Scholar.

15. For a brief discussion of some of the issues involved, see Williamson, , Markets and Hierarchies, pp. 20 and 48Google Scholar.

16. Moe, , “New Economics of Organization,” p. 761Google Scholar.

17. For example, Margaret Levi suggests that political associations are based on security motives; see Levi, Of Rule and Revenue. See also Bean, Richard, “War and the Birth of the Nation State,” Journal of Economic History 33 (03 1973), pp. 203–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Ames, Edward and Rapp, Richard, “The Birth and Death of Taxes: A Hypothesis,” Journal of Economic History 37 (03 1977), pp. 161–78CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

18. Williamson, Oliver, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism (New York: The Free Press, 1985), p. 4Google Scholar.

19. For brief and insightful critiques of functionalist explanations, see Keohane, Robert, After Hegemony (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1984), pp. 8083Google Scholar; Barry, Brian, Sociologists, Economists, and Democracy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1978), p. 169Google Scholar; and Yarborough, and Yarborough, , “International Institutions and the New Economics of Organization,” pp. 252–55Google Scholar.

20. Many of these points are also raised in Thelen and Steinmo, “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics.”

21. For a discussion of focal points in enhancing cooperation, see Schelling, Thomas, The Strategy of Conflict (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1980)Google Scholar. In my usage, however, I do not associate it with tacit communication.

22. See the discussion of how such actors can overtake the elements in an entire set in Axelrod, Robert, “The Emergence of Cooperation Among Egoists,” American Political Science Review 75 (06 1981), pp. 306–19CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a discussion of the prerequisites of iteration, see Oye, Kenneth, Cooperation Under Anarchy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986)Google Scholar, chap. 1.

23. Unger, Roberto, Plasticity into Power (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1987), p. 113Google Scholar. Unger places such modern empires as the twentieth-century German and Japanese programs in this category.

24. Giddens, Anthony, The Nation-State and Violence (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1987), p. 80Google Scholar.

25. Wallerstein, , The Modern World System, p. 15Google Scholar.

26. On this point, see Kratochwil, Friedrich, “Of Systems, Boundaries, and Territoriality: An Inquiry into the Formation of the State System,” World Politics 39 (10 1986), pp. 2752CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

27. For an overview of these dynamics, see Hall, John, Powers and Liberties (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1985)Google Scholar.

28. See Doyle, Michael, Empires (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1986)Google Scholar; and Snyder, Jack, Myths of Empire (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1991)Google Scholar.

29. As Abu-Lughod notes, many economic zones, and world systems, did not fall under political unification. She also notes, however, that unification can sometimes reduce uncertainty and protection costs. See Abu-Lughod, Janet, Before European Hegemony (New York: Oxford University Press, 1989), pp. 208–9Google Scholar.

30. Snyder, , Myths of Empire, p. 6Google Scholar.

31. See Curtin's discussion of trade diasporas in Curtin, Philip D., Cross-Cultural Trade in World History (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1984)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32. See Landa, Janet, “A Theory of the Ethnically Homogeneous Middleman Group: An Institutional Alternative to Contract Law,” Journal of Legal Studies 10 (06 1981), pp. 349–62CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Schmidt-Trenz, Hans-Jörg, “Private International Trade in the Shadow of the Territoriality of Law: Why Does It Work,” Southern Economic Journal 58 (10 1991), pp. 329–38CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Carr, Jack and Landa, Janet, “The Economics of Symbols, Clan Names, and Religion,” Journal of Legal Studies 12 (01 1983), pp. 135–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

33. One might object that this expansion should not be perceived as a contract between ruler and ruled. However, if one assumes that at least a minimum of quasi-compliance is necessary for a trading system to continue, then a purely extortionist government will destroy its own basis of revenue should it tax its merchants to the point that there are no incentives to continue to engage in commercial activity.

34. The characteristic features of feudalism are the subjects of long-standing disputes. Strayer's description is widely accepted, and that is the one I use here. See Strayer, Joseph, Feudalism (New York: Van Nostrand Reinhold, 1965), p. 13Google Scholar.

35. Saltman, Michael, “Feudal Relationships and the Law: A Comparative Inquiry,” Comparative Studies in Society and History 29 (07 1987), pp. 514–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar. See also Bloch, Marc, Feudal Society (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1961), pp. 115–16Google Scholar.

36. Thus, Polanyi defined feudalism as an in-kind economy. See Polanyi, Karl, “Primitive Feudalism and the Feudalism of Decay,” in Dalton, George, ed., Economic Development and Social Change (New York: Natural History Press, 1971), pp. 141–47 and p. 142Google Scholar in particular. An indicator of this local consumption was the itinerancy of kings. Kings traveled to locations to claim lodgings and food, to which they were entitled by the gîte, the claim to hospitality from their vassals.

37. Genicot, Leopold, “La Noblesse au Moyen Age Dans L'Ancienne ‘Francie’: Continuité, Rupture ou Evolution?” (Medieval nobility in ancient France: Continuity, break, or evolution?) Comparative Studies in Society and History, vol. 5, no. 1, 1962, pp. 5259CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

38. For a good account of the local diversity of law, see Reynolds, Susan, Kingdoms and Communities in Western Europe 900–1300 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984), chaps. 1 and 2Google Scholar. See also Berman, Harold, Law and Revolution (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1983)Google Scholar, particularly chap. 13.

39. For a discussion of these rights of local lords, see Duby, Georges, Rural Economy and Country Life in the Medieval West (Columbia: University of South Carolina Press, 1968), p. 181Google Scholar.

40. Dunbabin, Jean, France in the Making 843–1180 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1985), p. 277Google Scholar.

41. Zupko, Ronald, “Weights and Measures, Western European,” in Strayer, Joseph, ed., Dictionary of the Middle Ages, vol. 12 (New York: Charles Scribner, 1989), p. 582Google Scholar; Kula, Witold, Measures and Men (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1986)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, provides a fascinating account of the variety of weights and measures and of their regulation as an issue of contention. For a classic discussion of the variation in weights and measures and coinage throughout the Mediterranean, see Lopez, Robert and Raymond, Irving, Medieval Trade in the Mediterranean World (New York: W. W. Norton, 1967), pp. llffGoogle Scholar.

42. Heaton, Herbert, Economic History of Europe (New York: Harper and Row, 1948), p. 175Google Scholar.

43. Bloch describes this period as the second feudal period. See Bloch, , Feudal Society, p. 69Google Scholar. The economic growth is well-documented in Cipolla, Carlo, Before the Industrial Revolution (New York: W. W. Norton, 1980)Google Scholar; Duby, Georges, The Early Growth of the European Economy (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1974)Google Scholar; and Le Goff, Jacques, Medieval Civilization (New York: Basil Blackwell, 1988)Google Scholar.

44. See Braudel, Fernand, The Perspective of the World (New York: Harper and Row, 1984)Google Scholar; Pirenne, Henri, Medieval Cities (1925Google Scholar, reprint; Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1952). For a reaffirmation of Pirenne, see Le Goff, Medieval Civilization; Rörig, Fritz, The Medieval Town (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1969), p. 20Google Scholar; Barraclough, Geoffrey, Origins of Modern Germany (New York: W. W. Norton, 1984), pp. 4 and 76Google Scholar; and Verhulst, Adriaan, “The Origins of Towns in the Low Countries and the Pirenne Thesis,” Past and Present 122 (1989), pp. 335CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

45. See Hohenberg, Paul and Lees, Lynn, The Making of Urban Europe (Boston: Harvard University Press, 1985)Google Scholar; and Ennen, Edith, The Medieval Town (Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing, 1979)Google Scholar.

46. For a discussion of the significant implications of that transition, see Becker, Marvin, Medieval Italy (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1981)Google Scholar.

47. Duby, , The Early Growth of the European Economy, p. 252Google Scholar. For a similar view, see Morrall, John, Political Thought in Medieval Times (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1980), p. 42Google Scholar.

48. For an assessment that these three institutional arrangements indeed had come to the end of their primacy by 1300, see Tilly, , The Formation of National States in Western Europe, p. 26Google Scholar; and Morrall, Political Thought in Medieval Times.

49. Merchant law is discussed by Berman, Law and Revolution, chap. 11. For a new institutionalist view of merchant law, see Milgrom, Paul, North, Douglass, and Weingast, Barry, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 2 (03 1990), pp. 123CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Greif, Avner, “Institutions and International Trade: Lessons from the Commercial Revolution,” American Economic Review 82 (05 1992), pp. 128–33Google Scholar; and Benson, Bruce, “The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law,” Southern Economic Journal 55 (01 1989), pp. 644–61CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50. The quotation is drawn from p. 139 of Sawyer, P. H., “Kings and Merchants,” in Sawyer, P. H. and Wood, I., eds., Early Medieval Kingship (Leeds: University of Leeds, 1977), pp. 139–58Google Scholar.

51. Duby, , The Early Growth of the European Economy, p. 249Google Scholar.

52. For French royal efforts in this regard, see Fawtier, Robert, The Capetian Kings of France (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1960), pp. 188–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar. In general, all royal authorities tried to standardize and rationalize the legal process and bring more certitude to economic transactions. See Berman, , Law and Revolution, pp. 466–77Google Scholar; Spufford, Peter, “Coinage and Currency,” The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, vol. 2 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), p. 812Google Scholar; and Myers, Henry, Medieval Kingship (Chicago: Nelson-Hall, 1982), p. 319Google Scholar.

53. See Heaton, , Economic History of Europe, pp. 174–75Google Scholar; and Jordan, William, Louis IX and the Challenge of the Crusade (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1979), p. 209Google Scholar.

54. Cipolla, Carlo, “Currency Depreciation in Medieval Europe,” Economic History Review, vol. 15, no. 3, 1963, pp. 413–22CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For the stability of English coinage, see Duby, , The Early Growth of the European Economy, p. 251Google Scholar.

55. See particularly Kula, Measures and Men, chap. 22. Also see Hallam, Elizabeth, Capetian France 987–1328 (New York: Longman, 1980), p. 284Google Scholar; and Myers, , Medieval Kingship, p. 319Google Scholar.

56. Zupko, Ronald, British Weights and Measures (Madison: University of Wisconsin Press, 1977), p. 74Google Scholar. For another discussion of English success at centralization, see Rörig, , Medieval Town, pp. 65ffGoogle Scholar.

57. See Fawtier, , The Capetian Kings of France, p. 188Google Scholar; and Berman, , Law and Revolution, p. 467Google Scholar.

58. Berman, , Law and Revolution, p. 445Google Scholar.

59. Van Caenegem, R. C., The Birth of the English Common Law (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1988), 2d ed., pp. 44 and 91CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

60. For an argument that the Capetian kings had formed the basis for sovereign authority by 1300, see Hallam, , Capetian France 987–1328, pp. 262, 266, and 308Google Scholar; and Fawtier, , The Capetian Kings of France, pp. 47 and 189Google Scholar.

61. Vallee, Aline, “Etat et Securité Publique au XlVe Siecle: Une Nouvelle Lecture des Archives Royales Francaises” (State and public security in the fourteenth century: A new reading of French royal archives), Histoire, Economie et Societe 1 (Spring 1987), pp. 315Google Scholar. Similarly the king claimed jurisdiction in translocal affairs such as piracy. See Cheyette, Frederic, “The Sovereign and the Pirates,” Speculum, vol. 45, no. 1, 1970, pp. 4068CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

62. Bernard, Jacques, “Trade and Finance in the Middle Ages 900–1500,” in Cipolla, Carlo, ed., The Fontana Economic History of Europe, vol. 1 (Glasgow: Collins, 1972), p. 314Google Scholar.

63. Benson, , “The Spontaneous Evolution of Commercial Law,” p. 651Google Scholar.

64. Nettl, , “The State as a Conceptual Variable,” p. 564Google Scholar.

65. On the affinity between king and burghers, see Poggi, Gianfranco, The Development of the Modern State (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1978), p. 63Google Scholar; Miller, Edward, “Government Economic Policies and Public Finance 1000–1500,” in Cipolla, , The Fontana Economic History of Europe, vol. 1, pp. 356 and 369Google Scholar; and Rörig, , The Medieval Town, pp. 5864Google Scholar.

66. The seminal work on the Hansa is by Dollinger, Philippe, The German Hansa (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1970)Google Scholar. Wernicke gives a good description of the Hansa's formative period and its regional and local subassemblies. See Wernicke, Horst, Die Städtehanse 1280–1418 (The Hanseatic cities 1280–1418) (Weimar: Hermann Böhlaus Nachfolger, 1983)Google Scholar. A good introduction to the history of the Hansa can be found in Scammel, G. V., The World Encompassed: The First European Maritime Empires Circa 800–1650 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1981), chap. 2Google Scholar.

67. On the lack of success in standardizing measures and weights, see Held, Otto, “Hansische Einheitsbestrebungen im Mass und Gewichtswesen bis zum Jahre 1500” (Hanseatic attempts at unity in measures and weights until the year 1500), Hansische Geschichtsblätter 45 (1918), pp. 127–67Google Scholar.

68. Lensen, Leo and Heitling, Willy, De Geschiedenis van de Hanze (The history of the Hansa), (Deventer, Holland: Arko, 1990), pp. 24 and 36Google Scholar.

69. Dollinger, , The German Hansa, p. 207Google Scholar. Jesse, Wilhelm, “Die Münzpolitik der Hansestädte” (The coinage policy of the Hanseatic cities), Hansische Geschichtsblätter 53 (1928), pp. 7896Google Scholar, contrasts the lack of success in standardizing coinage and minting in the Hansa with the relative success of France. See also Rörig, , The Medieval Town, p. 65Google Scholar. Holborn comments on the lack of centralization and the chaotic currency conditions in Germany as compared with England. See Holborn, Hajo, A History of Modem Germany: The Reformation (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1959), p. 68Google Scholar.

70. Berman, , Law and Revolution, p. 376Google Scholar.

71. Lensen, and Heitling, , De Geschiedenis van de Hanze, p. 41Google Scholar.

72. Puhle, Matthias, “Der Sächsische Städtebund und die Hanse im Späten Mittelalter” (The Saxon city-league and the Hansa in the late Middle Ages), Hansische Geschichtsblätter 104 (1986), pp. 2134Google Scholar.

73. Lensen, and Heitling, , Geschiedenis van de Hanze, p. 155Google Scholar.

74. Schäfer, Dietrich, “Zur Frage nach der Einführung des Sundzolls” (On the question of the introduction of customs duties in the sound), Hansische Geschichtsblätter 5 (1875), pp. 3343Google Scholar.

75. Lloyd, T. H., England and the German Hanse 1157–1611 (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991), p. 370CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

76. Fink, Georg, “Die Rechtliche Stellung der Deutschen Hanse in der Zeit ihres Niedergangs” (The juridical position of the German Hansa in the time of its decline), Hansische Geschichtsblätter (1936), pp. 122–37Google Scholar. See also Lloyd, , England and the German Hanse, pp. 294304, 319, and 378Google Scholar.

77. On English expansion into the Baltic, see Davis, Ralph, English Overseas Trade 1500–1700 (London: Macmillan, 1973), pp. 1619CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

78. Conybeare, John, Trade Wars (New York: Columbia University Press, 1987)Google Scholar.

79. See Link, Werner, “Reflections on Paradigmatic Complementarity in the Study of International Relations,” in Czempiel, Ernst and Rosenau, James, eds., Global Changes and Theoretical Challenges (Lexington, Mass.: D. C. Heath, 1989), p. 101Google Scholar.

80. Lloyd, , England and the German Hanse, p. 375Google Scholar.

81. Krasner is right in pointing out that Westphalia is not a dramatic break with the past. I see it as a codification of practices already under way centuries before that. Nevertheless, it does serve a useful purpose as a benchmark signifying that the formation of a state system was coming to fruition. See Krasner, Stephen, “Westphalia and All That,” in Goldstein, Judith and Keohane, Robert, eds., Ideas and Foreign Policy (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1993), pp. 235–64Google Scholar.

82. Spies, Hans-Bernd, “Lübeck, die Hanse und der Westfälische Frieden” (Lübeck, the Hansa, and the Peace of Wesphalia), Hansische Geschichtsblätter 100 (1932), pp. 110–24Google Scholar.

83. Structuration theorists might frame this in terms of the system empowering only like actors. See, for example, Giddens, , The Nation State and Violence, p. 282Google Scholar. Rephrased this implies that actors recognize other units only on their terms—they admit only other states as legitimate actors in international relations.

84. In other words, they exercised exit rather than loyalty. See Hirschman, Albert, Exit, Voice, and Loyalty (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1970)Google Scholar.

85. For this institutional mimicry, see Barraclough, , Origins of Modern Germany, pp. 279 and 342–52Google Scholar; and Holborn, . A History of Modern Germany, pp. 3436 and 57Google Scholar.

86. Tilly, Charles, Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990–1990 (Cambridge: Basil Blackwell, 1990), p. 21Google Scholar.

87. For the early history of these communes, see Waley, Daniel, The Italian City-Republics (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1969)Google Scholar.

88. The quotation is drawn from p. 699 of Chittolini, Giorgio, “Cities, City-States, and Regional States in North-Central Italy,” Theory and Society 18 (09 1989), pp. 689706CrossRefGoogle Scholar. Also see Anderson, , Lineages of the Absolutist State, p. 152Google Scholar; Pullan, Brian, ed., Crisis and Change in the Venetian Economy in the Sixteenth and Seventeenth Centuries (London: Methuen, 1968), p. 15Google Scholar; and Hocquet, Jean-Claude, “Venise, Les Villes et les Campagnes de la Terreferme XVe-XVIe siecles” (Venice, and the towns and countryside of the mainland in the fifteenth and sixteenth centuries in Bulst, Neithard and Genet, Jean-Philippe, eds., La Ville, La Bourgeoisie et la Genèse de L'État Moderne (The city, the bourgeoisie, and the creation of the modern state) (Paris: CNRS, 1988), pp. 211–28Google Scholar.

89. For an exposition of this internal fragmentation, see Cochrane, Eric, Florence in the Forgotten Centuries 1527–1800 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1973), p. 651Google Scholar; Cochrane, Eric, Italy 1530–1630 (London: Longman, 1988), pp. 4647Google Scholar; Woolf, Stuart, A History of Italy 1700–1860 (London: Methuen, 1979), pp. 57 and 63Google Scholar; and Lane, Frederic, Venice: A Maritime Republic (Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1973), p. 424Google Scholar.

90. Hay, Denys and Law, John, Italy in the Age of the Renaissance (London: Longman, 1989), p. 261Google Scholar.

91. See Braudel, , The Perspective of the World, p. 289Google Scholar; Cochrane, , Italy 1530–1630, p. 183Google Scholar; and Woolf, , History of Italy 1700–1860, p. 208Google Scholar.

92. Rapp, Richard, Industry and Economic Decline in Seventeenth-Century Venice (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1976), p. 160Google Scholar.

93. Lane, , Venice: A Maritime Republic, p. 427Google Scholar.

94. See Hocquet, , “Venise, Les Villes et les Campagnes de la Terreferme,” p. 210Google Scholar; and Woolf, , A History of Italy 1700–1860, p. 64Google Scholar.

95. Knapton, Michael, “City Wealth and State Wealth in Northeast Italy, Fourteenth through Seventeenth Centuries,” in Bulst, and Genet, , La Ville, La Bourgeoisie et la Genèse de L'État Moderne, p. 189Google Scholar. For a similar evaluation of Florentine efforts, see Cochrane, , Italy 1530–1630, p. 9Google Scholar.

96. Woolf, , A History of Italy 1700–1860, pp. 52 and 59Google Scholar. See also Cochrane, , Italy 1530–1630, p. 183Google Scholar.

97. Woolf, , A History of Italy 1700–1860, p. 51Google Scholar.

98. Cochrane, , Italy 1530–1630, p. 14Google Scholar. For similar assessments of the return of feudalism, see Woolf, , A History of Italy 1700–1860, pp. 1718Google Scholar; Knapton, , “City Wealth and State Wealth,” p. 195Google Scholar; and Romano, Ruggiero, “Italy in the Crisis of the Seventeenth Century,” in Earle, Peter, ed., Essays in European Economic History 1500–1800 (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984), p. 193Google Scholar.

99. See the discussion in Mattingly, Garrett, Renaissance Diplomacy (New York: Dover, 1988)Google Scholar, first published in 1955.

100. Rice, Eugene, The Foundation of Early Modern Europe 1460–1559 (New York: W. W. Norton, 1970), p. 115Google Scholar.

101. For the long-run diplomatic successes of some of the Italian city-states, see Hinsley, F. H., Sovereignty, 2d ed. (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1986)Google Scholar; and McNeill, William, Venice: The Hinge of Europe 1081–1797 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1974)Google Scholar.

102. Woolf, , A History of Italy 1700–1860, p. 85Google Scholar.

103. On the notion of institutional mimicry, see DiMaggio, Paul and Powell, Walter, “The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organizational Fields,” American Sociological Review 48 (04 1983), pp. 147–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar. My thanks to Guy Peters and Stephen Krasner for bringing this argument to my attention.

104. See, for example, Rasler, Karen and Thomson, William, “War Making and State Making: Governmental Expenditures, Tax Revenue, and Global War,” American Political Science Review 79 (06 1985), pp. 491507CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Brewer, John, The Sinews of Power (New York: Alfred Knopf, 1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Mann, Michael, States, War, and Capitalism (Cambridge: Blackwell, 1988)Google Scholar; McNeill, William, The Pursuit of Power (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982)Google Scholar; Tilly, , Coercion, Capital, and European States; and Downing, Brian, The Military Revolution and Political Change (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1992)Google Scholar.

105. Often these arguments allude to military and economic efficiencies of scale. See Dudley, Leonard, “Structural Change in Interdependent Bureaucracies: Was Rome's Failure Economic or Military?Explorations in Economic History 27 (04 1990), pp. 232–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Bean, “War and the Birth of the Nation State”; and Ames and Rapp, “The Birth and Death of Taxes.”

106. See North, Douglass and Weingast, Barry, “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England,” Journal of Economic History 49 (12 1989), pp. 803–32CrossRefGoogle Scholar; North and Thomas, Rise of the Western World; and North, Structure and Change in Economic History.

107. For example, the Della Scala signoria, comprising Parma, Lucca, and Modena, had a yearly revenue of about 700,000 florins in the beginning of the fourteenth century. This was double that of England at the time. See Schumann, Reinhold, Italy in the Last Fifteen Hundred Years (Lanham, Md.: University Press of America, 1986), p. 116Google Scholar. The revenue of Venice and its Terra Ferma around the middle of the fifteenth century was 60 percent higher than that of France—more than double that of England or Spain. See Braudel, , The Perspective of the World, p. 120Google Scholar. See also the estimates in Knapton, “City Wealth and State Wealth.”

108. On the number of Genovese troops, see Scammel, , The World Encompassed, p. 161Google Scholar. Florence fielded about twenty-four thousand men in 1550; see Cochrane, , Florence in the Forgotten Centuries, p. 91Google Scholar. On the Rhenish-Swabian league, see Rotz, Rhiman, “German Towns,” in Strayer, Joseph, ed., Dictionary of the Middle Ages, vol. 5 (New York: Charles Scribner, 1985), p. 464Google Scholar. By contrast, the French standing army after the end of the Hundred Years War in the middle of the fifteenth century numbered about fourteen thousand.

109. Braudel, , The Perspective of the World, p. 91Google Scholar.

110. This notion of international empowerment also explains why African states have persisted despite tribal and irredentist movements. For that argument, see Jackson, Robert, “Quasi-States, Dual Regimes, and Neo-classical Theory: International Jurisprudence and the Third World,” International Organization 41 (Autumn 1987), pp. 519–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

111. North argues that the flaw of suggesting optimality in outcomes existed particularly in his earlier work. See North, Douglass, Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1990), p. 7CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For a discussion of this problem, also see Moe, “New Economics of Organization.”

112. For the latter use of transaction costs, see Dudley, “Structural Change in Interdependent Bureaucracies”; and Levi, Of Rule and Revenue.

113. For a comparison between the competitive state system and non-European autarkic empires, see Hall, , Powers and Liberties; and Hall, John, ed., States in History (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1986)Google Scholar.

114. See Parker, David, The Making of French Absolutism (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1983)Google Scholar, for the argument that French absolutism was paradoxically quite weak vis-à-vis the multitude of social actors. Robin Briggs notes how monarchs were constrained in the level of debasement, as this would weaken their “international position.” See Briggs, Robin, Early Modern France 1560–1715 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1977), p. 44Google Scholar.

115. As John Hall points out, that argument already had been made by Hall, Gibbon, Powers and Liberties, p. 14Google Scholar.

116. For a discussion of the Dutch case, see Boxer, C. R., The Dutch Seaborne Empire 1600–1800 (London: Penguin, 1965), pp. 119 and 328Google Scholar; and Holton, R. J., Cities, Capitalism, and Civilization (London: Allen and Unwin, 1986), p. 108Google Scholar.

117. For the difference, see Held, David, Political Theory and the Modern State (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1989)Google Scholar, chap. 8.

118. For different views about the compatibility of Islam and statehood, see Piscatori, James, Islam in a World of Nation-States (New York: Cambridge University Press, 1986)Google Scholar.

119. The early independence literature in emphasizing transnational relations below the state level can be read as describing the tension between sovereign territorial rule and the nonspatial character of the global economy. See Keohane, Robert and Nye, Joseph, Power and Interdependence (Boston: Little Brown and Company, 1977)Google Scholar. See also Reich, Robert, The Work of Nations (New York: Alfred Knopf, 1991)Google Scholar. Porter argues that the state is still relevant, but only in terms of an aggregation of sectors. See Porter, Michael, The Competitive Advantage of Nations (New York: Free Press, 1990)CrossRefGoogle Scholar. For the development toward truly transnational organization, see Bartlett, Christopher and Ghoshal, Sumantra, Managing Across Borders (Boston: Harvard University Press, 1989)Google Scholar.

120. This issue is raised explicitly in Ruggie, John, “Territoriality and Beyond: Problematizing Modernity in International Relations,” International Organization 47 (Winter 1993), pp. 139–74CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

121. This issue has been well-described by Kratochwil, “Of Systems, Boundaries, and Territoriality”; Holzgrefe, J. L., “The Origins of Modern International Relations Theory,” Review of International Studies 15 (01 1989), pp. 1126CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Ruggie, John, “Continuity and Transformation in the World Polity,” in Keohane, Robert, ed., Neorealism and Its Critics (New York: Columbia University Press, 1986), pp. 131157Google Scholar.

122. For example, Wright cites Arnold Brecht's view that the anarchy of the state system is the primary cause of armed conflict: “There is a cause of wars between sovereign states that stands above all others—the fact that there are sovereign states, and a very great many of them.” See Wright, Quincy, A Study of War, vol. 2 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1942), p. 896Google Scholar.

123. Bull, Hedley, The Anarchical Society (New York: Columbia University Press, 1977)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

124. Realists such as Robert Gilpin have suggested that the most fundamental type of system change is change in the type of units, but there has been little research on what the effects of such change are. See Gilpin, , War and Change in World Politics, pp. 4142Google Scholar; and Katzenstein, Peter, “International Relations Theory and the Analysis of Change,” in Czempiel, and Rosenau, , Global Changes and Theoretical Challenges, pp. 291304Google Scholar.

125. This corresponds with what Ruggie describes as the mode of individuation between units. See Ruggie, “Territoriality and Beyond.”

126. Wendt, Alexander E., “The Agent-Structure Problem in International Relations Theory,” International Organization 41 (Summer 1987), pp. 335–70 and p. 342 in particularCrossRefGoogle Scholar. Ashley makes a similar point from a poststructural perspective. See Ashley, Richard, “The Poverty of Neorealism,” in Keohane, , Neorealism and Its Critics, pp. 255300Google Scholar.

127. See Thomson, Janice, “Sovereignty in Historical Perspective: The Evolution of State Control over Extraterritorial Violence,” in Caporaso, James, ed., The Elusive State (Newbury Park, Calif.: Sage, 1989), pp. 227–54Google Scholar. See also Ritchie's account of Kidd, Captain in Ritchie, Robert, Captain Kidd and the War Against the Pirates (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1986)Google Scholar.

128. Thomson, Janice, “State Practices, International Norms, and the Decline of Mercenarism,” International Studies Quarterly 34 (03 1990), pp. 2348CrossRefGoogle Scholar.