Skip to main content
×
Home
    • Aa
    • Aa
  • Get access
    Check if you have access via personal or institutional login
  • Cited by 29
  • Cited by
    This article has been cited by the following publications. This list is generated based on data provided by CrossRef.

    Myatt, David P. 2016. A Theory of Protest Voting. The Economic Journal,


    Apolte, Thomas 2016. Gordon Tullock’s theory of revolution and dictatorship. Constitutional Political Economy, Vol. 27, Issue. 2, p. 158.


    SAMBANIS, NICHOLAS and SHAYO, MOSES 2013. Social Identification and Ethnic Conflict. American Political Science Review, Vol. 107, Issue. 02, p. 294.


    Bueno de Mesquita, Ethan 2013. Rebel Tactics. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 121, Issue. 2, p. 323.


    Shadmehr, Mehdi and Haschke, Peter 2016. YOUTH, REVOLUTION, AND REPRESSION. Economic Inquiry, Vol. 54, Issue. 2, p. 778.


    Chen, Heng Lu, Yang K. and Suen, Wing 2016. THE POWER OF WHISPERS: A THEORY OF RUMOR, COMMUNICATION, AND REVOLUTION*. International Economic Review, Vol. 57, Issue. 1, p. 89.


    Shadmehr, Mehdi 2014. Mobilization, Repression, and Revolution: Grievances and Opportunities in Contentious Politics. The Journal of Politics, Vol. 76, Issue. 3, p. 621.


    Chen, Jidong and Xu, Yiqing 2015. Information Manipulation and Reform in Authoritarian Regimes. Political Science Research and Methods, p. 1.


    Mekouar, Merouan 2014. No Political Agents, No Diffusion: Evidence from North Africa. International Studies Review, Vol. 16, Issue. 2, p. 206.


    Shadmehr, Mehdi and Bernhardt, Dan 2015. State Censorship. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, Vol. 7, Issue. 2, p. 280.


    Casper, Brett Allen and Tyson, Scott A. 2014. Popular Protest and Elite Coordination in a Coup d’état. The Journal of Politics, Vol. 76, Issue. 2, p. 548.


    Dorsch, Michael T. Dunz, Karl and Maarek, Paul 2015. Macro shocks and costly political action in non-democracies. Public Choice, Vol. 162, Issue. 3-4, p. 381.


    Edmond, C. 2013. Information Manipulation, Coordination, and Regime Change. The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 80, Issue. 4, p. 1422.


    Arena, Philip and Hardt, Brian 2014. Incentives to Rebel, Bargaining, and Civil War. International Interactions, Vol. 40, Issue. 1, p. 127.


    Dorsch, Michael T. and Maarek, Paul 2015. Inefficient predation and political transitions. European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 37, p. 37.


    Rost, Nicolas 2011. Human Rights Violations, Weak States, and Civil War. Human Rights Review, Vol. 12, Issue. 4, p. 417.


    Meirowitz, Adam and Tucker, Joshua A. 2013. People Power or a One-Shot Deal? A Dynamic Model of Protest. American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 57, Issue. 2, p. 478.


    Gehlbach, Scott and Keefer, Philip 2011. Investment without democracy: Ruling-party institutionalization and credible commitment in autocracies. Journal of Comparative Economics, Vol. 39, Issue. 2, p. 123.


    Siqueira, Kevin and Sekeris, Petros G. 2012. Politics and Insurgencies. Economics & Politics, Vol. 24, Issue. 2, p. 157.


    Baliga, Sandeep and Sjöström, Tomas 2012. The Strategy of Manipulating Conflict. American Economic Review, Vol. 102, Issue. 6, p. 2897.


    ×

Regime Change and Revolutionary Entrepreneurs

  • ETHAN BUENO DE MESQUITA (a1)
  • DOI: http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055410000274
  • Published online: 09 September 2010
Abstract

I study how a revolutionary vanguard might use violence to mobilize a mass public. The mechanism is informational—the vanguard uses violence to manipulate population member's beliefs about the level of antigovernment sentiment in society. The model has multiple equilibria, one equilibrium in which there may be revolution and another in which there is certain not to be. In the former, structural factors influence expected mobilization, whereas in the latter they do not. Hence, the model is consistent with structural factors influencing the likelihood of revolution in some societies but not others, offering a partial defense of structural accounts from common critiques. The model also challenges standard arguments about the role of revolutionary vanguards. The model is consistent with vanguard violence facilitating mobilization and even sparking spontaneous uprisings. However, it also predicts selection effects—an active vanguard emerges only in societies that are already coordinated on a participatory equilibrium. Hence, a correlation between vanguard activity and mass mobilization may not constitute evidence for the causal efficacy of vanguards—be it through creating focal points, providing selective incentives, or communicating information.

Copyright
Corresponding author
Ethan Bueno de Mesquita is Associate Professor, Harris School of Public Policy Studies, University of Chicago, 1155 East 60th Street, Suite 108, Chicago, IL 60637 (bdm@uchicago.edu).
Linked references
Hide All

This list contains references from the content that can be linked to their source. For a full set of references and notes please see the PDF or HTML where available.

George-Marios Angeletos , Christian Hellwig , and Alessandro Pavan . 2006. “Signaling in a Global Game: Coordination and Policy Traps.” Journal of Political Economy 114 (3): 452–84.

George-Marios Angeletos , Christian Hellwig , and Alessandro Pavan . 2007. “Dynamic Global Games of Regime Change: Learning, Multiplicity, and the Timing of Attacks.” Econometrica 75 (3): 711–56.

Sandeep Baliga and Tomas Sjöström . 2004. “Arms Races and Negotiations.” Review of Economic Studies 71: 351–69.

Eli Berman , and David D. Laitin . 2008. “Religion, Terrorism and Public Goods: Testing the Club Model.” Journal of Public Economics 92 (10–11): 1942–67.

Ethan Bueno de Mesquita . 2005. “The Quality of Terror.” American Journal of Political Science 49 (3): 515–30.

Ethan Bueno de Mesquita , and Eric Dickson . 2007. “The Propaganda of the Deed: Terrorism, Counterterrorism, and Moblization.” American Journal of Political Science 51 (2): 364–81.

Hans Carlsson , and Eric van Damme . 1993. “Global Games and Equilibrium Selection.” Econometrica 61 (5): 9891018.

Michael Chwe . 1998. “Culture, Circles, and Commercials: Publicity, Common Knowledge, and Social Coordination.” Rationality and Society 10: 4775.

Michael Chwe . 1999. “Structure and Strategy in Collective Action.” American Journal of Sociology 105: 128–56.

Michael Chwe . 2000. “Communication and Coordination in Social Networks.” Review of Economic Studies 67: 116.

Torun Dewan , and David P. Myatt . 2007. “Leading the Party: Coordination, Direction and Communication.” American Political Science Review 101 (4): 825–43.


Federico Echenique , and Aaron Edlin . 2004. “Mixed Equilibria Are Unstable in Games of Strategic Complements.” Journal of Economic Theory 118 (1): 6179.


Barbara Geddes . 1990. “How the Cases You Choose Affect the Answers You Get: Selection Bias in Comparative Politics.” Political Analysis 2 (1): 131–50.

John Ginkel , and Alastair Smith . 1999. “So You Say You Want a Revolution: A Game Theoretic Explanation of Revolution in Repressive Regimes.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 43 (3): 291316.

Jack A. Goldstone 2001. “Toward a Fourth Generation of Revolutionary Theory.” Annual Review of Political Science 4 (June): 139–87.

Bengt Holmström . 1999. “Managerial Incentive Problems: A Dynamic Perspective.” Review of Economic Studies 66 (1): 169–82.

Stathis N. Kalyvas 1999. “Wanton and Senseless? The Logic of Massacres in Algeria.” Rationality and Society 11 (3): 243–85.

Timor Kuran . 1989. “Sparks and Prairie Fires: A Theory of Unanticipates Political Revolution.” Public Choice 61 (1): 4174.


Mark Irving Lichbach . 1987. “Deterrence of Escalation?: The Puzzle of Aggregate Studies of Repression and Dissent.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 31: 266–97.


Stephen Morris , and Hyun Song Shin . 2000. “Rethinking Multiple Equilibria in Macroeconomic Modeling.” NBER Macroeconomics Annual 15: 139–61.

Stephen Morris , and Hyun Song Shin . 2003. “Global Games: Theory and Applications.” In Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, 8th World Congress of the Econometric Society, eds. Mathias Dewatripont , Lars Peter Hansen , and Stephen J. Turnovsky . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Stephen Morris , and Hyun Song Shin . 2004. “Coordination Risk and the Price of Debt.” European Economic Review 48: 133–53.

Peter Rosendorff and Todd Sandler . 2004. “Too Much of a Good Thing? The Proactive Response Dilemma.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 48 (4): 657–71.

Kevin Siqueira , and Todd Sandler . 2007. “Terrorist Backlash, Terrorism Mitigation, and Policy Delegation.” Journal of Public Economics 91 (9): 1800–15.


Gordon Tullock . 1971. “The Paradox of Revolution.” Public Choice 11 (Fall): 89100.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

American Political Science Review
  • ISSN: 0003-0554
  • EISSN: 1537-5943
  • URL: /core/journals/american-political-science-review
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×