Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-pjpqr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-17T10:20:19.246Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - A Unified Model of Issue Voting: Proximity, Direction, and Intensity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 December 2009

Samuel Merrill, III
Affiliation:
Wilkes University, Pennsylvania
Bernard Grofman
Affiliation:
University of California, Irvine
Get access

Summary

… spatial [i.e., proximity] and directional theories may not be incompatible but instead may complement one another in explaining patterns of voting behavior.

Torben Iversen, “Political Leadership and Representation in West European Democracies” (1994: 49)

Limitations of Pure Models

In Chapter 2, we introduced two pure models of voting behavior: the Downsian proximity model and the Matthews directional model. We saw that the former could be modified by discounting (Grofman), the latter by taking overall voter or candidate intensity into account (Rabinowitz and Macdonald). Even with these emendations, each of these models singles out one (or in some cases two) aspects of voter decision making. We expect each to be of limited usefulness by itself in explaining voter behavior, and empirical studies bear out this expectation (see Chapters 4–7). In this chapter, we specify a unified model intended to incorporate the features of all the various pure models.

In order that utility not increase without bound as candidates recede from the neutral point, Rabinowitz and Macdonald (1989) incorporate into their model a penalty for extremism, on the grounds that voters will tend to find unacceptable a candidate or party whose stands are too “far-out.” To this end, they define a circle or region of acceptability, centered at the neutral point, beyond which a candidate suffers a loss of utility for all voters. Although Rabinowitz and Macdonald consider the “region of acceptability” to be part of the definition of their directional model, they provide no decision rule for specifying which parties fall into the region.

Type
Chapter
Information
A Unified Theory of Voting
Directional and Proximity Spatial Models
, pp. 38 - 51
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1999

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×