Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-m8qmq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T07:58:23.958Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

8 - Property Rights and Environmental Markets

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2014

Terry L. Anderson
Affiliation:
Property and Environment Research Center
Gary D. Libecap
Affiliation:
University of California, Santa Barbara
Get access

Summary

In a nutshell, this book has made the case for environmental markets based on well-defined, enforced, and transferable property rights. If all three exist, owners have an incentive to consider the full effects of their actions as they engage in Coasean bargaining to mitigate the losses of open access. Property rights – informal or formal, individual or group – help reduce the tragedy of the commons by assigning the costs and benefits of decisions, making the opportunity costs clear, limiting the race to capture rents, and allowing owners to reallocate resources across uses and across time. Property rights identify the relevant people who have a stake in the resource and who can engage in negotiation and contracting. Without them, there is little basis for bargaining. Absent exclusivity, any party can enter and compete for resource rents regardless of any agreement made by an initial group of users. Because everyone knows this potential, bargaining for environmental quality cannot gain much traction.

Property rights define expectations regarding entitlements from resource use, investment, coordination, and cooperation, relative to nonowners. They provide incentives for considering long-time horizons and for long-lasting collaboration. This certainly is necessary because most environmental and natural resource challenges involve the long term, require exclusion, and necessitate teamwork for solution. Secure property rights economize on the transaction costs of decision making, allowing market exchange, investment, and experimentation to take place quickly in response to new information regarding the environmental and natural resource asset. Given the limited scientific knowledge that often accompanies many open-access problems, the information generation and flexibility of markets are particularly critical.

Type
Chapter
Information
Environmental Markets
A Property Rights Approach
, pp. 204 - 216
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2014

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Merrill, Thomas W. and Smith, Henry E. (2010), Property, New York: Oxford University Press, 1–13Google Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. (1991), “What are Transaction Costs?Research in Law and Economics 14: 1–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Douglas W. (2000), “Transaction Costs,” in Bouckaert, Boudewijn and De Geest, Gerrit, eds., The Encyclopedia of Law and Economics, Vol. 1, Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 893–926Google Scholar
Eagle, Steven J. (2008), “The Common Law and the Environment,” Case Western Law Review 53(3): 583–620Google Scholar
Stavins, Robert N. (2007), “Market-Based Environmental Policies: What Can We Learn from U.S. Experience (and Related Research)?” in Freeman, Jody and Kolstad, Charles D., eds., Moving to Markets in Environmental Regulation, New York: Oxford University Press, 25Google Scholar
Keohane, Nathaniel O., Revesz, Richard L., and Stavins, Robert N. (1998), “The Choice of Regulatory Instruments in Environmental Policy,” The Harvard Environmental Law Review 22: 313–345Google Scholar
Joskow, Paul L. and Schmalensee, Richard (1998), “The Political Economy of Market-Based Environmental Policy: The U.S. Acid Rain Program,” Journal of Law and Economics 41 (April): 37–83CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, Robert W. (1990), “The Politics and Religion of Clean Air,” Regulation (Winter): 21–30
Ackerman, Bruce and Hassler, William T. (1981), Clean Coal/Dirty Air: or How the Clean Air Act Became a Multibillion-Dollar Bail-Out for High-Sulfur Coal Producers, New Haven: Yale University PressGoogle Scholar
Olson, Mancur (1965), The Logic of Collective ActionCambridge, MA: Harvard University PressGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, James M. and Tullock, Gordon (1962), The Calculus of Consent, Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stigler, George J. (1971), “The Theory of Economic Regulation,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management 2: 3–21CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lasswell, Harold D. (1936), Politics: Who Gets What, When, How?New York: McGraw HillGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry and Marshall, William (1988), “The Industrial Organization of Congress; or, Why Legislatures, Like Firms, are not Organized as Markets,” Journal of Political Economy 96 (February): 132–168CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth and Weingast, Barry (1982), “Institutionalizing Majority Rule,” American Economic Review 72: 367–371Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth and Weingast, Barry (1987), “The Institutional Foundations of Committee Power,” American Political Science Review 81: 85–104CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weingast, Barry (2007), “The Political Economy of Law,” in Polinsky, A. Mitchell and Shavell, Steven, eds., Handbook of Law and Economics, Vol. 2, Elsevier, 1652–1738Google Scholar
Homans, Frances R. and Wilen, James E. (1997), “A Model of Regulated Open Access Resource Use,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 32: 1–27CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Revesz, Richard L. (1996), “The Control of Interstate Environmental Externalities in a Federal System,” University of Arizona Law Review 38: 883–900Google Scholar
Weingast, Barry (1995), “The Economic Role of Political Institutions: Market-Preserving Federalism and Economic Development,” Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization 20(1): 1–31Google Scholar
Johnson, Ronald N. and Libecap, Gary D. (2001), “Information Distortion and Competitive Remedies in Government Transfer Policies: The Case of Ethanol,” Economics of Governance 2(2): 101–134CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrett, Scott (2007), Why Cooperate: The Incentive to Supply Global Public GoodsNew York: Oxford University PressCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helm, Dieter (2008), “Climate-Change Policy: Why Has so Little Been Achieved?Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 24(2): 211–238CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pashigian, Peter B. (1985), “Environmental Regulation: Whose Self-Interests are Being Protected?Economic Inquiry 23(4): 551–584CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ackerman, Bruce A. and Stewart, Richard B. (1985), “Reforming Environmental Law,” Stanford Law Review 37: 1333–1365CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meridian Institute (2010), Catch Shares in New England, February, Washington D.C.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James (2012), The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty: Why Nations Fail, New York: Crown and Douglass C. NorthGoogle Scholar
Joseph Wallis, John, and Weingast, Barry R. (2009), Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, New York: Cambridge University PressGoogle Scholar
Libecap, Gary D. (2008), “Open Access Losses and Delay in the Assignment of Property Rights,” Arizona Law Review 50(2), 379–408Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×