Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T11:02:23.685Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Unbounded Intervention

The State and the Blocked Deal

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 March 2018

Ashley Thomas Lenihan
Affiliation:
London School of Economics and Political Science

Summary

Type
Chapter
Information
Balancing Power without Weapons
State Intervention into Cross-Border Mergers and Acquisitions
, pp. 93 - 157
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2018
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NC
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

Introduction

States may employ a variety of balancing strategies in response to a perceived threat to their relative position of power within the international system. This book argues that when the perceived threat to power is caused by the potential foreign takeover of a company in one of its national security industries, a state is likely to react using one of three non-military internal balancing strategies: unbounded, bounded, or internal intervention. The next four chapters provide a deeper explanation and examination of each of these forms of balancing, and qualitatively assess the theory through a series of cases studies.

The purpose of this chapter is to further specify the conditions under which a state might choose to engage in unbounded intervention. Toward this end, four critical cases are examined: (1) the rumored attempt of the US company PepsiCo to acquire the French food company Danone, (2) the attempted takeover of the US oil company Unocal by the Chinese company CNOOC, (3) the attempted takeover of the US software company Sourcefire by the Israeli company Check Point, and (4) the attempted takeover of the Chinese telecommunications company PCCW by Australia's Macquarie Group (Figure 26).

Case 1Case 2Case 3Case 4Case 5
Acquirer NamePepsiCoCNOOCCheck Point SoftwareMacquarieDubai Ports World*
Acquirer CountryUSAChina**IsraelAustraliaUAE
Target NameGroupe DanoneUnocal CorporationSourcefire Inc.PCCWP&O
Target CountryFranceUSAUSAChina**UK
Target IndustryFood & BeverageOil & Gas ProducersSoftwareFixed Line TelecomMarine Infrastructure
Deal TypeAcquisitionAcquisitionAcquisitionAcquisitionAcquisition
Deal Value (in $US thousands)N/A18,209,400225,0007,300,0005,701,062 (Bid 1)
6,780,131 (Bid 2)
Deal StatusRumor/Informally WithdrawnWithdrawnWithdrawnRumor/Informally WithdrawnBid 1 – Withdrawn
Bid 2 – Completed
First Deal DateFebruary 12, 2004March 3, 2005October 7, 2005June 20, 2006October 31, 2005

* The acquisition vehicle used for this deal was named Thunder FZE.

** The company is headquartered in Hong Kong.

Figure 26 Unbounded intervention: critical cases examined in Chapters 3 and 4

As with other forms of balancing, states face costs for both over- and underreactions to these potential changes in relative power,1 even though they may not be fully cognizant that their proactive use of these tools could be categorized as “balancing.” The next chapter will therefore focus on an instance of unbounded balancing by the US, which could also be considered an instance of “overbalancing,” and thus an “outlier” case: namely, the US intervention into the takeover of P&O in Britain by DPW of the UAE (Figure 26).

Defining Unbounded Intervention

Definition

The term “unbounded intervention” is used here to represent the most aggressive form of government interference into a cross-border merger or acquisition. Such intervention is defined by the intention of government actors who, on the whole, seek to prevent a potential foreign takeover bid from reaching a successful conclusion. Yet, government actors do not always act coherently, and on rare occasions the government itself may even be divided as to the best course of action. When trying to identify cases of unbounded intervention, therefore, it will be necessary to demonstrate that either a critical mass of government actors2 seek to block the bid, or that crucial government players – i.e., those with veto power, or particular sway in the decision making process – wish to do so. In such cases, the opposition is often unable to prevent the unbounded intervention strategy from being carried out. In fact, the results from the secondary hypothesis indicate that intervention type and deal outcome are closely linked, and unbounded intervention strategies will usually result in the successful prevention of a foreign takeover.

Purpose and Motivation

The stated purpose of unbounded intervention will almost always be the protection of national security. Indeed, the right of states to intervene is based on the protection of companies whose loss or foreign control would pose an immediate threat to national security. It is important to note, though, that actors involved in this type of intervention may stretch the notion of “national security” beyond its traditionally defined bounds (see Introduction and Chapter 1). This is because government actors concerned with the relative power position of their state may have longer time horizons with respect to what they consider to be a “threat.” They may also have more elastic definitions as to which companies should be placed under the rubric of the national security umbrella, especially if those companies are national champions considered vital to the state's economic power.

The first hypothesis tested here claims that government intervention into foreign takeovers is primarily motivated by either geopolitical concerns or economic nationalism. As the findings in Chapter 2 indicate, it should be expected that the respective prominence of each of these factors will vary in accordance with the systemic relationship between states A and B. In other words, the case studies should support the general idea that when states A and B are members of the same security community, economic nationalism will usually be the primary motivation behind unbounded intervention. Similarly, when states A and B are not members of the same security community, the case studies should show that geopolitical concerns play a greater role in unbounded intervention. In either situation, however, it is expected that state A is concerned with its power position relative to state B, and thus seeks to balance the potential increase in state B's relative power that could result from a particular foreign takeover by preventing that transaction from occurring in the first place.

It is also important to recognize two other possible reasons that state A might employ a strategy of unbounded intervention, reasons that will be controlled for in the case studies. These are: the presence of interest groups who desire a negative deal outcome, and the presence of competition concerns on the part of a relevant economic authority. It is necessary to note, however, that while interest groups may raise alarms about a deal that could affect national security, it is expected that they will rarely affect the outcome of that deal, or the strategy with which state A chooses to handle it. It is also important to realize that in some cases a state may raise economic competition concerns at the same time that it flags national security issues, or that a relevant government agency may seek to veto a deal solely on competition grounds.

Means and Manner

Unbounded intervention involves the efforts of government actors to block a foreign takeover through formal, or “effective,” means. A “formal block” is when a government, or a representative government agency, officially vetoes the deal on national security grounds. An “effective block” is when the acquiring company is convinced or pressured to withdraw/rescind its proposed bid for the target company through one of the following means:

  1. 1. The government and/or its agencies voice such significant concerns or reservations regarding the deal before the formal review process begins in the relevant regulatory agencies of state A that the acquiring company feels compelled to withdraw the bid in the face of overwhelming opposition, which it deems too costly to overcome.

  2. 2. The government forces the divestiture of facilities or subsidiaries involved in the transaction that reside in its country. This particular strategy may also be used by a third-party state involved in the transaction to block the sale of assets within its territory.

  3. 3. The government of state A institutes a lengthy review process in a relevant regulatory body from which the acquiring company does not believe its bid will successfully emerge. The company's cause for concern will likely be either that the review process has extended in time to a point where it is proving too costly for the company to proceed3 or that the government of state A has indicated to the company that it is unlikely to emerge from the review process without triggering a formal veto.4

While it is possible that efforts to “effectively” block a specified transaction may not initially succeed, this is rare (for reasons outlined earlier and later), and a state can still decide to formally veto the deal in order to prevent it from being completed. In cases where the companies involved fail to notify the relevant national authorities before a transaction is completed, many countries also maintain the right to review a takeover after completion and to unwind it, in whole or in part, if it is deemed to pose a threat to national security.

Outcomes and Results

Unbounded intervention will usually lead the acquiring company to withdraw its bid, whether or not it has been formally announced. There are a couple of reasons behind this. First, even if there is a chance that state A's position on the bid might be reversed, a company facing extreme government opposition will usually not have the time, money, or patience to surmount it. Second, a company is unlikely to desire any further negative publicity of the type that can result from such government opposition. Third, a company whose bid has been formally vetoed on national security grounds is often then branded as a “security risk” in future deals. Companies faced with severe government opposition will thus often withdraw from the bidding process before a formal veto can occur. Finally, if state A's unbounded intervention strategy does result in a formal veto, it may not be possible for the company to reverse that decision through any means.5

Of even greater interest than the immediate deal outcome, however, is the impact that unbounded intervention is likely to have on the relationship between states A and B. At best, such intervention is viewed as a legitimate action by a state to protect a company from foreign control because of an immediate national security concern: an action considered a right of states, and which many states view as “fair play” even in the context of a free-market environment. Indeed, the relationship between the states involved usually remains largely unchanged, because such intervention is usually soon forgotten by states for the simple reason that M&A is associated with the private, rather than the public, realm. At worst, intervention may irritate another state into tit-for-tat behavior, causing it to respond similarly in the future.

State intervention into foreign takeovers may thus be considered a form of non-military internal balancing because, in addition to using non-military means, it rarely causes a complete disruption in the relationship between states A and B. Of all the forms of intervention discussed here, however, unbounded intervention is undoubtedly the most complete. Thus, if it is used improperly, i.e., if it becomes an instance of unnecessary balancing or overbalancing, it is the type of intervention most likely to produce a temporary antagonism between states A and B. Yet, even in such a case, as the DPW study in Chapter 4 shows, the internal and non-military nature of this strategy makes it unlikely to lead to a permanent disruption in the relationship between the states involved, such as the cutting of military or diplomatic ties.

Case Selection

The ten cases examined in this and the next three chapters are critical to understanding government intervention into cross-border M&A, as they have informed the way market analysts understand domestic barriers to foreign takeovers. These cases also represent a diverse population of states associated with both the target and the acquiring companies,6 and each had a significant impact on the international merger market. A brief overview of why each of the cases included in this chapter is considered critical to our understanding of unbounded intervention as a form of non-military internal balancing is provided below.

The PepsiCo/Danone case is key to our knowledge of unbounded intervention, for two reasons. First, it is one of the rare instances in which unbounded intervention has occurred within the security community context, and can thus help us to understand how and why this might occur. As discussed in Chapter 5, bounded intervention tends to be viewed as a more satisfactory and useful tool of non-military internal balancing between closely allied states. It should be remembered that the database exhibited only eleven cases of unbounded intervention out of 158 cases of intervention within security communities as a whole. In almost every case, economic nationalism was the primary, and geopolitical competition the secondary, motivation for unbounded intervention.7

Second, though PepsiCo/Danone is clearly a case of unbounded intervention in terms of motivation and form, it has one unique feature that prevented its inclusion in the statistical database, and which makes it critical to examine qualitatively if we are to further our understanding of such balancing. For, though it is one of the more often cited examples of government intervention into foreign takeovers, the target company (Danone) hails from an industry that many states would not normally associate with “national security:” the yogurt industry. Food and agriculture were not included in the sectors covered in the statistical database, because there is little consensus over whether or not it should be considered a national security sector. Some countries do consider the agriculture and food sector to be critical infrastructure, and since the Danone case there have been several reviews of foreign investments into the takeovers of large agribusinesses for possible national security risks, though thus far no notable vetoes have been recorded in this sector on such grounds.8 It was important to examine this case, however, because the French government adamantly argued that Danone's safety from foreign acquisition was a matter of national security, and promptly changed French FDI law to reflect its concerns. This case thus provides an excellent opportunity to examine the dynamics that result when such an unusual categorization is made.

Conversely, CNOOC/Unocal is a critically important instance of unbounded intervention outside of the security community context. This case provides a detailed example of a company, owned by the government of a rising power that has a stated policy of using M&A to gain control of vital resources, finding its attempted acquisition blocked primarily because the target company's state feared the geopolitical and national security implications of such a deal. It is also of interest because of its historical context, as unbounded intervention occurred with relative infrequency in the US before this case. The US had not previously sought to block British Petroleum's (BP's) purchase of Amoco in 1988 or Petróleos de Venezuela's (PDVSA's) purchase of CITGO in 1990, both of which were arguably of much greater economic importance. Thus, it is vital to understand why unbounded intervention was considered warranted in this particular instance.

The Check Point/Sourcefire case was included because it is a rare example of unbounded intervention within a security community that was primarily motivated by national security and geopolitical concerns, rather than by economic nationalism. Despite the extremely close relationship of the US and Israel (the countries involved), tensions existed over Israel's ability and willingness to adhere to US export control laws for technology in the sector in question.9

Finally, the Macquarie/PCCW case has been included as an example of unbounded intervention outside of the security community context, and is considered critical because it widens the geographical test of the hypotheses. In this case, the target company is Chinese, and the acquirer Australian. Certainly, it is the only example within the database of unbounded intervention being undertaken by either Russia or China within the time frame examined. This is primarily because these are what might be termed “capitalist autocracies,” where the foreign acquisition of 100% of a company within the industries examined here is highly regulated and, if it is allowed at all, must often be undertaken with the cooperation of the government. Such strict regulations regarding this type of foreign investment mean that unbounded interventions are rarely necessary in these countries, because if the government doesn't indicate in advance that it wants a deal to happen in some form, companies are usually unwilling to risk the capital to pursue it. Indeed, the high degree of regulation within many industries in China and Russia already indicates a tendency toward internal balancing used to strengthen their strategic sectors relative to those of other states. The number of foreign acquisitions in these countries is also generally lower than in the EU or US, due to the uncertainties of their investment climate. It is still possible, however, for a foreign company to attempt a takeover in these “strategic industries,” and it is important to understand how these governments will react, and what will motivate them.

Case 1: PepsiCo/Danone

The Story

On July 6, 2005, a rumor surfaced in the international equities market that the US beverage company PepsiCo was in the process of formulating a bid to acquire 100% of the French yogurt and water company Groupe Danone.10 Talk of the rumor persisted throughout the summer despite Danone's insistence that they had not been approached regarding a possible takeover (Perri & Deen Reference Perri and Deen2005), largely because of Pepsi's refusal to comment on the rumor either positively or negatively (Matthews Reference Matthews2005; Mercer Reference Mercer2005). International newspapers and wires kept the story going, naming inside sources who believed that the bid was real, or who claimed to know which banks were helping Pepsi to prepare its offer (see e.g., Brothers & Robbins Reference Brothers and Robbins2005; Gay Reference Gay2005; Schuman Reference Schuman2005). Meanwhile, “the French media reported rumors that [the takeover] was imminent – and even, wrongly, that the American group had already bought a 3% stake” (Gow Reference Gow2005).

What followed was an almost immediate reaction on the part of the French government, which sought (with gusto) to prevent the takeover entirely. By July 19, a lower-level government official made the “concern” of the French government over such a “culturally awkward” deal known to the press (Zephyr 2005a). In the next two days, the French Prime Minister Dominique de Villepin publicly proclaimed Danone's status as a national champion, naming it one of the “jewels of [French] industry” (de Beaupuy & Vandore Reference de Beaupuy2005) and claiming that the French government would protect its independent French status in order to “defend France's interests” (Vandore Reference Vandore2005a). At the same time, French President Jacques Chirac announced his concern over the possible deal, stating that the French government was “particularly vigilant and mobilized” to intervene if necessary, and stressing the role of the government in maintaining “the industrial competitiveness and…strength of its companies” (de Beaupuy & Vandore Reference de Beaupuy2005).

It was not until July 25 that PepsiCo reported to the French market regulatory body (the Autorité des Marchés Financiers, or AMF) that it was not preparing a takeover bid for Danone “right now” (Perri & Deen Reference Perri and Deen2005). This “denial” of the rumor, however, still clearly left open the possibility that Pepsi might make such a bid in the future. The result was that less than twenty days after the initial rumor surfaced, and without any formal bid having been announced by Pepsi, the French government signaled its intent to prevent a hostile foreign takeover of Danone through a series of actions that formed a coherent strategy of unbounded intervention.

First, the AMF became involved toward the end of the month by announcing that it would begin an investigation into the trading of Groupe Danone's shares (Vandore Reference Vandore2005b). This was because Danone's share prices had been fluctuating greatly, rising on reports of a takeover, and then falling sharply on July 25, when Pepsi denied an imminent bid (Gow Reference Gow2005). The investigation was made at the behest of “the minority shareholders’ defense group, ADAM,” which “demanded a full-scale investigation to determine whether the rumors about Danone were the result of market manipulation and insider trading” (Gow Reference Gow2005). The AMF echoed the widespread frustration that Pepsi's failure to clearly refute the rumor had a great effect on share price (AMF 2005). This investigation eventually had a great impact on FDI in France, as it prompted the so-called “Danone Amendment” to be passed into law in March 2006 (see Merger Market 2006). The new law “ultimately…aims to deter takeover bids that are either hostile or motivated by speculation, by [allowing the target company to] increase[e it]s capital through the issuing of stock purchase warrants” (EIRO 2006). Ironically, this amendment was attached to a law meant to provide for the domestic implementation of the European Takeover Directive, one of the goals of which was to reduce barriers to cross-border M&A within the EU (see European Parliament 2004).

Second, and more importantly, Chirac and Villepin announced in a government meeting on July 27, 2005 that France “must strengthen the measures to protect [its] key companies,” and suggested that French law would need to be changed in order to protect its companies from such “hostile”11 foreign takeovers (Vandore Reference Vandore2005b). Less than a year earlier, on December 9, 2004, the French National Assembly had already passed a “Reform Law” intended “to ensure that all foreign investments involving public order, public security, or interests of national defense were subject to official review” by the French government (Cafritz Reference Cafritz2014, 1).12 By August 31, 2005, amidst the PepsiCo/Danone rumors, French Finance Minister Thierry Breton announced that eleven “sensitive” sectors would be considered strategic and, therefore, that the government would be changing the law to protect companies in these industries from unwanted foreign takeovers in the future (de Beaupuy Reference de Beaupuy2005). On December 31, 2005, the French government put this plan into action, passing an anti-takeover decree that gives it “the right to veto or impose conditions on foreign takeovers of domestic companies operating in as many as 11 sensitive industries” (Buck et al. Reference Buck, Hollinger and Braithwaite2006b). These include the industries dealing with:

private security, if used, for example in nuclear or other secure installations; research or production of products that can be used in terrorist or chemical attacks; bugging equipment; information security; companies providing information technology security to government; dual-use technology for civilian or military applications; cryptology; companies entrusted with defense secrets; arms; certain sub-contractors to the defense ministry; and casinos, where the government is concerned about money laundering.

The French government notably broadened the scope of its strategic sectors list again in 2014, to help ensure government approval would be needed before the US company General Electric could acquire the French conglomerate Alstom,13 adding industries related to the “security and continuity of supplies that are essential to public order or safety and national defence,” such as water, energy, transport, and health (Hepher Reference Hepher2014).14

Both the French President and Prime Minister were strongly in favor of the 2005 anti-takeover decree as a result of their opposition to a possible bid for Danone by Pepsi, and, consequently, they used every opportunity to show their support for it during the furor caused by the rumor. They went out of their way to publicize their intent to “defend French interests” in a potential bid for Danone, and Villepin openly contended that France “must ensure that [its] companies have the same means to act and defend themselves as their foreign counterparts” (Vandore Reference Vandore2005b).

Thus, it is clear that even though the acquisition of Danone by Pepsi had not yet passed the rumor stage, the French government reacted to the potential bid with a virulent campaign to prevent its success. Furthermore, the French government sought, successfully, to carry out a strategy of unbounded intervention to block this potential cross-border takeover bid on the basis that it threatened the national interest and security. The question, therefore, is not only why did the French pursue this type of intervention, but also why did they pursue it in the context of the yogurt industry, which is not one that would normally be associated with “national security” in the traditional sense. The variables proposed in the primary hypothesis are explored in relation to the PepsiCo/Danone case in the sections that follow, together with an analysis of which variables provided the primary motivation behind the French government's actions.

Geopolitical Competition

Resource Dependency

While France is a resource-dependent nation, the US is not one of its primary sources of energy (see Encyclopedia of Earth 2007). France's resource dependency ratio, or the ratio of all its imported energy sources to its total energy supply, was 63% in 2005.15 This is very close to the mean resource dependency ratio for the 209 cases in the dataset, which was 62%.

Relative Power Differential

Despite the fact that both the US and France are major powers, the relative power differential between them is vast. The US completely overshadows France in terms of relative military power. In 2005, US military expenditure was $504,638 million, which was over nine and a half times France's expenditure of $52,917 million.16 Furthermore, this differential was increasing because the average growth rate of the US’ military expenditure between 2001 and 2005 was 8%, while that of France was only 1%.17 The differences are also stark in terms of relative economic power. US GDP in 2005 (at price purchasing parity, or PPP) was almost seven times that of France.18 The relative economic power of the US was also increasing slightly vis-à-vis France at this time, with the average economic growth rate for the years 2001–05 being 5% for the US and 4% for France.19 It is clear, however, that France was closer to the US in terms of relative economic power than it was in terms of relative military power. It would thus make sense at the time for the French government to seek to balance the US through means that would help enhance France's relative economic power position.

Overall Character of the Geopolitical Relationship

The US and France are formal military allies and members of a deeply integrated security community, a relationship formalized through their membership in NATO. At the heart of this alliance is Article 5 of the Treaty, which provides for the mutual self-defense of its members, who commit to treat “an armed attack against one or more of them” as “an attack against them all” (NATO 1949). Despite the end of the Cold War that originally gave it purpose, NATO's members have maintained the alliance and committed to strengthen it, and to redefine its mission. NATO remains the “essential alliance” for the US (Burns Reference Burns2004), and France recognizes it as “a priceless asset that must be maintained in order to cope with current and future challenges and threats” (French Ministry 2008).

This being said, the relationship between the US and France within NATO is far from uncomplicated. France left the military arm of NATO in 1966 in order to pursue its own independent nuclear and military defense plans, largely because of disagreements with US policy and concerns that the US would not provide fully for the defense of France in case of a nuclear war (La Fondation Charles de Gaulle 2008). Since that time, France has contributed troops to Alliance operations such as Kosovo and Afghanistan, even when it was not officially part of NATO's military command. Chirac initiated a discussion to rejoin the NATO command early in his presidency, but his demands for rejoining were not met, and the discussion was dropped almost ten years before the 2005 PepsiCo/Danone case. In 2007, French President Nicolas Sarkozy made overtures to rejoin the military command of NATO, but France did not officially do so until April 2009, well after this case concluded.20

Strain within the US–French alliance arguably reached a height, however, following the invasion of Iraq in 2003. French opposition to the Iraq war was vociferous and unflagging, with threats of a French veto in the UN preventing the US from gaining full Security Council authorization for the invasion, and the acrimony of the discussion causing many to question the future of the alliance. This strain had not faded by the time of the PepsiCo/Danone case, and it was only with the later election of President Sarkozy that tensions began to ease.

As a result, there was a prevailing perception within France at the time that the US was a threat to international stability, not only because of its unilateral foreign policies, but, more fundamentally, because of its position as the world's only superpower. Though French public opinion of the US has been relatively low for some time, the Pew Global Attitudes Project (PGAP) found that it lowered dramatically after the Iraq War, falling from 63% in the summer of 2002 to 43% in June 2003 (Pew Global Attitudes Project 2003). Moreover, the French government has not been shy over its concerns with US hyperpuissance, a concept first put forward by then French Foreign Minister Hubert Vedrine in 1999 (Lieber Reference Lieber2005). The French strongly believe in “the need to counterbalance [US] power,” and have “expressed under Chirac's presidency” the belief that “multipolarism is a better way to guarantee world security than unipolarism” (Tardy Reference Tardy2003). They feel that unipolar power is dangerous because of its ability to act beyond the constraint of international norms and agreements. The French have thus tried to establish themselves as the leaders of a self-styled effort to balance US hyperpuissance and return the world to multipolarity.

Within the confines of the NATO relationship, then, the potential exists for a certain level of strategic competition between the US and France. This competition largely focuses on the use of diplomatic and economic tools to balance US power. Within this context, it is not surprising that the French government might use a tool of unbounded intervention to prevent the takeover of one of its national champions by a US company. The use of such a non-military internal balancing strategy makes perfect sense within the context of France's desire to enhance its own power vis-à-vis the US, while at the same time maintaining an alliance with the US, which it believes provides more strategic benefits than costs.

Thus, while French and American security are formally intertwined, their relationship remains antagonistic because of the vast power differentials and historical differences between the two countries, which are resented by the French, and which were exacerbated by the US’ unilateralist approach to Iraq. The French have a stated policy of seeking to balance US power, and, not surprisingly, chose to do so through unbounded intervention in the PepsiCo/Danone case. This can be interpreted as the French government protecting its relative economic power position vis-à-vis the US by defending one of its national champions (Danone) from a US “predator” (Pepsi).

The timing of the anti-takeover decree, and the acknowledgment that this case was the impetus behind the law, helped frame the protection of Danone as a matter of French national security. Chirac and other members of the French government painted Danone as a “key” company, “national treasure,” and “jewel” of French industry, whose protection was of paramount importance not only to French “industrial competitiveness,” but also to its “interests” (see Brothers & Robbins Reference Brothers and Robbins2005; Corcoran Reference Corcoran2005; de Beaupuy & Vandore Reference de Beaupuy2005; Vandore Reference Vandore2005b). While the food industry was not protected in the final version of the law, there was speculation that it would be included as one of the eleven strategic sectors made “off limits” to foreign takeovers. The government also did nothing to dispel the belief that Danone would be protected until after the takeover rumors died down, when a French Finance Ministry official would only say that “Yogurt does not feature on our list” (Bennhold Reference Bennhold2006a). However, under the provisions of the law, Danone itself was protected from a foreign takeover, because it also owned a casino – an industry that was protected at the time of this case, on the grounds that the government needed to monitor casinos and gambling to protect the country from money-laundering used for organized crime and terrorism (see PINR 2005). Casinos were later removed from the list of strategic sectors in a 2012 update of the 2005 Decree, reportedly under pressure from the EU Commission, though the wider gambling sector (excluding casinos) was retained on the list of strategic sectors for which the investments of non-EU foreign investors would be subject to review (Cafritz Reference Cafritz2014, 3, 9).21 France's government thus went to extraordinary lengths to ensure that a food and drinks company was associated with national security in order to effectively veto the potential transaction at the time, and to reinforce its “right” to veto such a deal in the future.22 With all of this in mind, it remains true that the US and France are closer allies than many states in the world, and the underlying elements of geopolitical competition between them could not have been enough to cause this kind of virulent reaction on its own.

Economic Nationalism

As the birthplace of nationalism, and as one of the few true “nation-states,” France retains high levels of national pride. In the last wave of the World Values Survey before this case, 37% of respondents in France claimed to be “very proud” of their nationality, and another 47% were “quite proud,” making 84% proud of their national identity to at least some degree (WVS 2001–04).

Not surprisingly, the French are also well known for their economic nationalism. This is partially rooted in pride – 32% of French citizens claim to be proud of their nation's economic achievements (ISSP 2003). The virulence of their economic nationalism, however, is also rooted in a strong belief that globalization threatens not only French “culture and…identity,” but also the health and vitality of the French economy (Gordon Reference Gordon2005). This belief is strengthened by the fact “that globalization directly challenges the statist economic and political traditions of the country” (Gordon Reference Gordon2005). For example, a 2005 World Public Opinion (WPO) survey of every G8 country but Japan asked respondents whether “the free enterprise system and free market economy [was] the best system on which to base the future of the world” (WPO 2006). France was the only country where more respondents disagreed with that statement (50%) than agreed that the free-market economy was a positive influence (36%) (WPO 2006). In a survey of fifty-four countries, French businessmen ranked second to last among those who believed that “attitudes toward globalization are generally positive in [their] economy,” followed only by Venezuela (IMD 2007a, 2007b).23 Such intense anti-globalization sentiment infuses every aspect of business in France, and was one of the primary reasons behind the French rejection of the EU constitution in 2005. Furthermore, the French associate the evils of globalization with “Americanization” (Gordon Reference Gordon2005; WPO 2006), explaining in part their virulent reaction to a perceived national champion being taken over by a US company.

The French government thus blatantly refused to allow one of its recognized national champions to become a victim of globalization in the form of a takeover by an American company. One observer even went so far as to proclaim “L’état, c'est Danone” (Corcoran Reference Corcoran2005). France has had a history of subsidizing and protecting its companies from foreign control since the Cold War, but this case sent the government “into protectionist overdrive” (WSJ 2005a).

Villepin's stated policy of “economic patriotism”24 throws the role that economic nationalism played in French opposition to the potential Danone takeover into stark relief. Simply put, this doctrine is an “industrial Maginot line” – a policy “designed to defend ‘France and that which is French’…by declaring entire sectors of French industry off-limits to [foreign takeovers]” (Theil Reference Theil2005; Economist 2006b). The French government even argued that this was not “protectionism,” but a policy designed to counter similar policies “in the US and elsewhere” (Thornhill & Jones Reference Thornhill and Jones2005). Most importantly, however, this policy of economic patriotism is considered by many to be a reaction to the rumors surrounding the possible takeover of Danone by Pepsi (see e.g., Franks Reference Franks2006). Its formulation clearly demonstrates France's desire to balance the relative economic position of the US through unbounded intervention in this case, and to balance that of other countries in future like cases.

All of these facts combine to show that economic nationalism was indeed one of the primary motivations behind France's strategy of unbounded intervention in this case, and that this was exacerbated by tensions in the geopolitical relationship between the US and France. It is in the context of such virulent economic nationalism that the Pepsi rumor was able to trigger both legislation and the formalization of a new economic policy designed specifically to block a foreign takeover of Danone. Furthermore, these policies enjoy such strong support across government and public lines that it is unlikely they will change in the future.

Presence of Interest Groups

There were interest groups present in France that either opposed the PepsiCo/Danone deal or were likely to oppose it if given the opportunity to do so. Danone itself preferred “to remain independent,” but was also reportedly looking for a domestic white knight to provide an alternative if Pepsi did make a formal offer for its company (Perri & Deen Reference Perri and Deen2005; Schuman Reference Schuman2005). Danone Chairmen Franck Ribaud later suggested, however, that he did not actually want to see the government “sanctuarise” his company, because “sanctuaries are for relics, whereas Danone thrives on the competition it faces in all its markets” (Dairy Reporter 2006). Thus, the actual role played by Danone in the government's actions is somewhat opaque. Furthermore, the fact that the government reacted to the rumor almost immediately meant that shareholders (who would be the main stakeholders in such a transaction) didn't really have time to respond either positively or negatively to the deal.

It was also fairly clear that the interest groups normally associated with anti-globalization movements would protest against the deal due to fears that it would lead to job losses for French workers, and because of the company's iconic role in French economic identity. It was, for example, claimed that “France's Unions would…strongly oppose a PepsiCo deal,” as would French farmers (Brothers & Robbins Reference Brothers and Robbins2005; Corcoran Reference Corcoran2005). This did, of course, play a role in the government's attitude toward the deal, and contributed to the unlikelihood that it would become more than a rumor. These interest groups, however, were largely motivated by economic nationalism themselves, and it seems clear that it was the general economic nationalist mood of the nation at that time, rather than the persuasive powers of any one interest group, that contributed to the rapidity of the French government's intervention. In the end, it was not the opposition of a particular interest group, but the staunch opposition of the French leadership combined with widespread opposition that prevented the rumor from ever becoming a reality.25

More importantly, the immediate groundswell of opposition to the deal did not come from the market, but from French government officials appalled at the notion that such a French icon would be bought by a foreign – and, equally important, an American – firm. As the preceding discussion of the general French tendency toward economic nationalism and the specific French policy of economic patriotism demonstrates, it is not surprising that the government in this case did not need the lobbying of a specific irate interest group or stakeholder to bring its attention to, or convince it of, the dangers of such a deal.

Competition Concerns

The issue of whether or not such a combination of companies would be monopolistic, or whether competition within the food industry would be affected negatively by such a takeover, was not a concern that was flagged by the government or the market in this case. This was largely because government efforts to block the deal on other grounds were so quick that the deal was scuttled long before it could move beyond the rumor stage.

Conclusions on PepsiCo/Danone

There is a distinct pattern of French government-led efforts to balance the relative economic power position of the US through a strategy of unbounded intervention in this case. This makes sense in the context of French efforts to balance American hyperpuissance as a whole. This strategy seems to be both purposefully and consciously implemented. Not surprisingly, the stock of French FDI abroad far exceeded that of FDI into France, in terms of both book and market value, in 2005 and 2006 (US DOS 2009). For, at the same time that the French have sought to protect their national champions from foreign takeovers, they have supported their “own companies [who] are active acquisitors” abroad (Parker & Thornhill Reference Parker and Thornhill2005).

Case 2: CNOOC/Unocal

The Story

In 2005, the potential acquisition of the American Unocal Corporation by the Chinese government-owned CNOOC Ltd. caused an almost unprecedented reaction in Washington, where a widespread movement among members of the US government sought to block the foreign takeover through a strategy of unbounded intervention, allowing the American company Chevron to win the “war” for Unocal. All three companies involved were in the oil and gas industry, and Unocal was a recognized takeover target that, though relatively small as “the 9th largest oil company in the world” (Powell Reference Powell2005), provided others with a unique opportunity to buy an independent company with wholly owned assets in Asia. Indeed, Unocal had relatively few assets in North America (mainly in the Gulf of Mexico) and Europe, but a number of prime assets in Asia (in Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Indonesia, Myanmar, the Philippines, and Thailand), in addition to a number of joint venture (JV) projects in Asia (Unocal 2005; Greenwire 2005c). Meanwhile, CNOOC Ltd., an American listed company based in Hong Kong, was seeking to expand its asset base in Asia. The fit initially seemed obvious to the market,26 though there were questions over whether CNOOC could afford Unocal. Yet, controversy ensued when it was realized by public policymakers that CNOOC Ltd. was 71% owned by the Chinese government-owned and controlled China National Offshore Oil Corporation.

The race for Unocal began early in 2005. CNOOC announced it was considering a bid for the company on January 7, and by March 3, Chevron had stated it too was contemplating mounting a takeover attempt. In early April, CNOOC withdrew itself from the bidding process amid the concerns of its non-executive board members, who were “troubled by the amount of debt” CNOOC would have to take on in order to complete such a deal (Timmons Reference Timmons2005). With the path seemingly clear, Chevron announced on April 4 its intention to buy Unocal for $18 billion in a debt/cash deal worth “an overall value of US $62.00 per share” (Zephyr 2005b, 2005c), for which it received approval from the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) of the US by June 10, and from the US Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) by July 29. The race, however, was far from over, and on June 7, CNOOC once again “confirmed” its intention to make an offer for Unocal in the near future (AFP 2005a), a promise that it fulfilled on June 22 when it topped Chevron's bid with a cash offer of $67 per share of Unocal stock (Zephyr 2005b, 2005c).

Before continuing with this story, it is necessary to remember that in the US there are three major hurdles any foreign takeover must clear in order to be successful (Grundman & Roncka Reference Grundman and Roncka2006). The first is a Foreign Ownership, Control or Influence (FOCI) review, in which the DOD Defense Security Service (DSS) investigates a transaction to ensure that it will not “result in unauthorized access to classified information or…adversely affect the performance of classified contracts” (DSS 2016b). This process was established in 1993 as part of the National Industrial Security Program (NISP) created by Executive Order 12829.27 Like the CFIUS process, the FOCI review is classified, and it is unclear whether Unocal had classified contracts that would have triggered a FOCI review if it had accepted CNOOC's bid.

The second hurdle is a competition review provided for under the 1976 Hart–Scott–Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act, which occurs before a transaction is concluded. This review process, carried out by the FTC and Department of Justice (DOJ), with support from the DOD as needed, is “intended to protect competition and prevent transaction-specific adverse impacts on prices and innovation” (Grundman & Roncka Reference Grundman and Roncka2006, 2).28 As discussed later, the US government did not really display concern over a proposed CNOOC/Unocal deal on such competition grounds.

The third hurdle for foreign investors is the CFIUS process. As discussed in the Introduction, this national security review process for foreign takeovers was initially established by the Exon–Florio Provision of the 1988 Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act, which:

amended Section 721 of the Defense Production Act of 1950 to provide authority to the President to suspend or prohibit any foreign acquisition, merger or takeover of a US corporation that is determined to threaten the national security of the United States. The President can exercise this authority under section 721…to block a foreign acquisition of a US corporation only if he finds: (1) there is credible evidence that the foreign entity exercising control might take action that threatens national security, and (2) the provisions of law, other than the International Emergency Economic Powers Act do not provide adequate and appropriate authority to protect the national security.

(US DOT 2007)

President Reagan also signed Executive Order 12661 in 1988, amending the Executive Order that originally established CFIUS (11858), and thus delegating his new presidential authority to investigate and review foreign takeovers to CFIUS. The Committee is headed by the Secretary of the Treasury, who at the time of this case was John Snow. In 1992, the “Byrd Amendment” to the 1950 DPA further stipulated that CFIUS be mandated to investigate proposed takeovers in which the acquirer was “controlled by or acting on behalf of a foreign government.”29 The national security review for foreign takeovers was thus referred to for a long time as the “Exon–Florio Process,” and these provisions served as the backbone of foreign takeover law in the US until being updated by the Foreign Investment and National Security Act of 2007 (FINSA).30

FINSA was passed in response to Congressional concerns over the strength, transparency, and oversight of the CFIUS process following the CNOOC/Unocal and DPW/P&O cases examined in this book. FINSA and Executive Order 13456, respectively, once again amend section 721 of the DPA and Executive Order 11858. FINSA primarily clarifies the Exon–Florio process and makes it more transparent.31 FINSA also notably increases the membership of CFIUS from the twelve reporting agencies it had reached by the time of the CNOOC/Unocal case32 (adding the Secretary of Energy), and formally recognizes critical infrastructure as a national security concern in transactions covered by the review process. For the most part, however, FINSA simply provides for a “codification of [the] many existing informal practices” (Plotkin et al. Reference Plotkin, Fagan and Chambers2009) already in play during this case and the DPW/P&O deal. Concern over critical infrastructure, for example, was already informally recognized in the DPW transaction, and the inclusion of the Energy Secretary was presaged by the CNOOC case. Thus, though FINSA came after many of the cases examined here, it does not affect the theory, or the conclusions drawn from these case studies.

Crucial to understanding the CNOOC/Unocal case is the CFIUS filing procedure and timeline for reviews, which has not changed since 1988. Filings with CFIUS are usually voluntary, with companies notifying the Committee once a preliminary or formal agreement has been reached for the transaction in question (US DOT 2007). When this notification is received, the review process begins; for most companies, this involves a simple thirty-day review of the transaction, but in cases where a national security issue is flagged, the Committee can conduct an “extended 45-day review,” which must be followed by “a report…to the President, who must [then] announce the final decision [on the deal] within 15 days” (US DOT 2007). This means that ninety days is the maximum time allowed for a review (US DOT 2007). This time limitation is important because it gives foreign investors a time frame within which they can plan to have contingent funding and resources available for their transaction. One industry source has also pointed out that unexpected delays in the review process, especially those that might unofficially extend the ninety-day limit, can cause some foreign companies to lose short-term financing opportunities or force them to pay higher prices because of interest accrued on loans that may have already been in place for a deal. More importantly, however, and as the CNOOC/Unocal case will demonstrate, attempts to cause a delay in a foreign takeover transaction beyond the ninety-day process cause uncertainty and, therefore, a degree of risk that investors, shareholders, and board members of the companies involved are usually unwilling to accept. Understanding the details of this review process is thus integral to understanding what happened in the CNOOC/Unocal case.

The possibility of a Chinese government-owned company taking over a US oil company during a period of tense Sino-American relations and rising energy prices began to worry members of the US government, who quickly sought to deal with the issue both inside and outside the context of this highly institutionalized process for reviewing foreign takeovers under US law. By June 17, US Congressmen Duncan Hunter (R-CA) and Richard Pombo (R-CA) sent a letter to President Bush requesting that CFIUS investigate the potential ramifications of a CNOOC/Unocal deal because they were concerned that such a deal would threaten “US jobs, energy production, and energy security” (Timmons Reference Timmons2005). The latter issue was of significant concern to the congressmen, who “encourag[ed] Bush to consider the national security implications regarding the transfer of technology to China in the event of Unocal's acceptance of CNOOC's offer” (Bullock & Xiao Reference Bullock and Xiao2005b). On June 22, only five days after the Hunter/Pombo letter, “Energy Secretary Samuel Bodman [confirmed] that a bid would be reviewed by [CFIUS]” (Gold et al. Reference Gold, Pottinger and Berman2005). On June 23 – the same day that there was a hearing in “the Senate Finance Committee…on the evolving US–Chinese economic relationship”33 – Senator Chuck Grassley (R-IA) announced that US “legislators [would] watch [the] CNOOC-Unocal” deal (Gold et al. Reference Gold, Pottinger and Berman2005; Dow Jones 2005b). By the end of June, “41 members of Congress sent a letter to Treasury Secretary John Snow…asking that the potential transaction ‘be reviewed immediately to investigate the implications of the acquisition’” (Graham & Marchick Reference Graham and Marchick2006, 131). On June 27, Congressmen Joe Barton (R-TX) and Ralph Hall (R-TX) wrote a letter to President Bush urging him to block a CNOOC takeover of Unocal because it “poses a clear threat to the energy and national security of the United States” (Orol Reference Orol2005d; Barton & Hall Reference Barton and Hall2005). Congress was thus beginning to lean toward a clear strategy of unbounded intervention, with the intent to block the deal one way or another.

This strategy was solidified on June 30 in two separate formal actions taken by the US House of Representatives. The first was the passage of House Resolution 344, sponsored by Congressman Pombo, which formally recognized congressional concern that a CNOOC/Unocal deal “threatens to impair the national security” (US House 2005c). This concern mostly emanated from a belief that, in an environment where the US and China were competing for energy resources and Sino-American relations were strained, the Chinese government might through its ownership of CNOOC use a Unocal purchase to gain control over much-needed energy assets, as well as over dual-use technologies that could have military applications. H. Res. 344, therefore, demanded that if Unocal and CNOOC did agree to a transaction, “the President…[would] initiate immediately a thorough review of the proposed acquisition, merger, or takeover” (US House 2005c). This resolution passed by a vote of 398–15.

The second action taken by the US Congress was the addition of Amendment 431 to H.R. 3058.34 The purpose of this amendment, sponsored by Congresswoman Carolyn Kilpatrick (D-MI) and passed by a vote of 333–92, was to “prohibit the use of [Treasury] funds from being made available to recommend approval of the sale of Unocal Corporation to CNOOC Ltd. of China” (H. Amdt. 431 to H.R. 3058). This amendment was clearly a tactic to block a CNOOC/Unocal deal, because, had CNOOC and Unocal reached an acquisition agreement, a CFIUS review would have been triggered, and those funds required. H. Res. 344 mandated that such a review be “thorough,” which would indicate a full forty-five-day CFIUS investigation, resulting in a report to the President, who would then have to give his approval or disapproval regarding the transaction (see H. Res. 344). This amendment, therefore, would have made it impossible for the President to give his approval under such a scenario, because the report would be delivered through the Chair of CFIUS, who is the Secretary of the Treasury, and who by definition would be using funds from the Treasury.

The high-profile concern generated by the deal caused the CEO of CNOOC, Fu Chengyu, to take the highly unusual step in late June of “writing to members of Congress expressing his company's willingness to participate in a [CFIUS] review” (International Oil Daily 2005c) and on July 1 of requesting that CFIUS review the transaction before an acquisition agreement had actually been reached with Unocal (Amaewhule Reference Amaewhule2005).35 On June 30, Liu Jianchao, the spokesman for the Chinese Foreign Ministry, announced that “China wants to find a ‘win-win’ result,” because “this issue is a commercial transaction between two companies, and a normal exchange between China and the US. It should stay free of political interference” (Dow Jones 2005a). In the beginning, CNOOC really believed that the US would not block the transaction as long as it marketed the deal, and its intentions, correctly. Chengyu, for example, was truly “confident [the] deal [was] politically viable” (AFX 2005a), once he made it clear that CNOOC's “all-cash offer [was] clearly superior for Unocal shareholders” and was “good for America,” and that CNOOC would “protect Unocal's US jobs” (Gold et al. Reference Gold, Pottinger and Berman2005).

Frustration on the part of the Chinese government at what it viewed as US “protectionism” soon began to show, however. In what is widely viewed as a critical slip in the campaign to win the race for Unocal, the Chinese Foreign Ministry made another statement on July 5, declaring: “We demand that the US Congress correct its mistaken ways of politicizing economic and trade issues and stop interfering in the normal commercial exchanges between enterprises of…[China and the US]” (Dow Jones 2005d). This statement only served to increase the fears of certain members of the US government that the Chinese government was guiding the CNOOC bid, and that such an offer did not necessarily have friendly motivations (Dow Jones 2005d).36

On July 13, the same day that it was reported CNOOC was contemplating making a higher offer in order to win over Unocal shareholders (Canadian Press 2005), the difficulties for CNOOC's bid intensified. First, CFIUS reportedly denied CNOOC's request for “a preliminary opinion on its proposed acquisition” (AFX 2005c). Second, the House Armed Services Committee held a hearing to review the “national security implications” of a CNOOC takeover (Dow Jones 2005c). The majority of witnesses at the hearing, and most members of the committee, believed such a takeover would be a threat to US national security (AFX 2005c), and Committee Chairman Duncan Hunter argued the deal was fundamentally “at odds with US interests” (AFX 2005c). Finally, Senators Chuck Grassley and Max Baucus (D-MT) sent a letter to the President expressing their concern over the possible CNOOC takeover, supporting calls for a formal CFIUS review of the deal if an acquisition agreement was made with Unocal (Grassley 2005). On July 15, Senator Dorgan (D-ND) introduced S. 1412, a piece of legislation that would have “prohibit[ed] the merger, acquisition, or takeover of Unocal Corporation by CNOOC Ltd. of China” outright, if it had been passed (US Senate 2005).

Despite the hot political environment, Unocal was enticed by the possibility of a bidding war for its company, as well as the higher return for its shareholders that a courtship of CNOOC promised. Unocal's board and shareholders wanted the highest price at the lowest level of risk. Thus, on July 14, the board of Unocal “agreed that ‘assuming neither Chevron nor CNOOC improved the financial terms of [their] proposed transaction[s], the board's inclination would be to withdraw its recommendation for the Chevron transaction’” (Natural Gas Intelligence 2005). When Chevron then raised its bid on July 19 to “an overall value of US $63.01 per share,” Unocal's board not surprisingly recommended this new bid to its shareholders (Zephyr 2005d).

At this point, opposition to the deal remained strong within the US government and public. The hearing held by the House Energy & Commerce Committee reviewed the possible CNOOC/Unocal Deal on July 22. Senators Vitter (R-LA), Bayh (D-IN), Talent (R-MO), Coburn (R-OK), and Inhofe (R-OK) also sent a letter on this date,

urging Senate Energy and Natural Resources Committee Chairman Pete Domenici (R-NM) and Ranking Member Jeff Bingaman (D-NM) to include language in the Energy Bill Conference Report that would require the Secretary of Energy, along with the Secretaries of Defense and Homeland Security, to study the implications of such a transaction before a formal review could begin.

(States News Service 2005b)

By mid-June, 73% of Americans polled by the Wall Street Journal claimed to “‘dislike’ the potential [CNOOC] deal” (Voice of America 2005).

Throughout this period, the White House remained fairly neutral on the proposed foreign takeover, as is the norm in such cases. This was largely because it did not yet need to get involved, and likely because it probably was better to wait and see whether Unocal actually chose CNOOC over Chevron, rather than waste valuable political capital committing itself to a position at such an early stage in the process. The White House did make it clear, however, that a CFIUS review would be triggered if the CNOOC bid was chosen, and that it did not openly favor such a deal – indicating a desire for Congress and the Senate to do the dirty work of balancing in this case. Nevertheless, it was clear that the majority of the US legislative branch wanted to block a CNOOC/Unocal deal completely, and the muted response of the Executive branch would not fill CNOOC with confidence about the chances of obtaining approval for its proposed transaction.

Unocal, meanwhile, was still hoping for a bidding war, and continued to hold meetings with both Chevron and CNOOC during this time period, in the hopes of a higher offer. Though CNOOC's original bid was higher, the degree of political uncertainty surrounding it was much greater than Chevron's, which not only had FTC and SEC approval, but which (as a US company) would also not have to face the CFIUS process (see AFX 2005b; Reuters 2005b; Murray Reference Murray2005). It was thus reported by July 26 that “Unocal management argued that increased risks of government approval and delay outweigh the differential on CNOOC's $67/share bid” (Taylor Reference Taylor2005). At the same time, it was reported that CNOOC might raise its bid for the company above $67/share, if Unocal met two demands (Taylor Reference Taylor2005). These were that Unocal: (1) “pay the $500 million break-up fee for terminating the [original deal with] Chevron” and (2) “take ‘specific actions’ to help ‘influence the US congress’ towards a deal with CNOOC” (Taylor Reference Taylor2005). Neither of these conditions would be particularly easy for Unocal to achieve, and the market roundly believed at this point that, while CNOOC still had a chance if it made a higher bid, the political risk of such a deal would probably be too much for either CNOOC or Unocal to accept. As one analyst put it, “the market [was] split” on “how to price political risk” (Natural Gas Intelligence 2005). One of Oppenheimer's analysts claimed that CNOOC “would not want to offer more money without assurances of success” (Taylor Reference Taylor2005).

Despite all of this, many observers in the market and the press still believed that CNOOC would raise its bid. For example, on July 28 it was rumored that “CNOOC Ltd. has drafted plans to increase its $67/share cash bid to more than $70/share, valuing Unocal at about $19.3 [billion], about $2 [billion] above Chevron's proposal” (Platts 2005). It was also believed that “Unocal's board would need a 10% premium from CNOOC, over and above Chevron's $63.01/share offer to compensate for risk that US Legislators and regulators would delay or even stop a CNOOC-Unocal merger” (Platts 2005). Rumors even surfaced as late as August 1 that CNOOC was waiting for Congress to recess to announce both a higher bid and a white-knight buyer for Unocal's US assets (Natural Gas Intelligence 2005). Either way, CNOOC's pursuit was dealt a strong blow that same day when the proxy firm Institutional Shareholder Services, “which can at times sway US takeover battles with its recommendations, said it was supporting Chevron because of the significant premium associated with the $17.5 [billion] offer, as well as the regulatory risks associated with CNOOC's bid” (Guerrera & Polti Reference Guerrera and Polti2005).

In the following days and weeks, another crucial effort at unbounded intervention was made by the Legislative branch to block a possible CNOOC/Unocal deal. On August 8, a piece of legislation introduced by Representative Joe Barton, the Energy Policy Act of 2005 (H.R. 6), was signed into law. This law included within it a provision for an extraordinary delay in the conclusion of any deal between CNOOC and Unocal – a delay that effectively killed the deal. Section 1837 of H.R. 6 required that a report be made to Congress assessing the national security implications of the issues relating to China's quest for energy, the use of foreign investment to satisfy those energy needs, and “reciprocity” issues, such as whether or not a US company would be able to purchase an oil company in China (US House 2005a). This section was the result of an amendment made by Congressman Pombo, who “admitted to reporters that his amendment was meant to effectively kill a potential CNOOC/Unocal deal” (Oil Daily 2005a). According to Senator Dorgan, who also supported the amendment, the main motivation behind the request for this study was the delay that it would cause (O'Driscoll Reference O'Driscoll2005). H.R. 6 allowed 120 days for the completion of the report, and effectively mandated that CFIUS could not begin its review of a CNOOC/Unocal deal until twenty-one days after that, in order for its findings to be considered in the review process (US House 2005a; O'Driscoll Reference O'Driscoll2005). Thus, this law ensured that there would be an excessive and onerous delay of 186 days (about six months) before the companies would officially be told if the transaction could be concluded.

Not surprisingly, CNOOC withdrew its outstanding bid for Unocal on August 2, 2005. Its stated reason for pulling out was “the political environment in the US,” and the “unprecedented political opposition that followed the announcement of our proposed transaction” (CNOOC 2005). In fact, opposition to the deal was so intense that the Chinese government withdrew its support for the acquisition toward the end of the bidding process (Grimmer Reference Grimmer2005). Tensions with the US were already high at the time, as discussed later, and “it was just not worth using up a lot of political capital over, especially with President Hu Jintao heading to the United States in September for his first visit” (Grimmer Reference Grimmer2005). By August 10, Unocal held a shareholder meeting to assess the proposed merger agreement with Chevron, after which it announced the approval of Chevron's bid, and Chevron declared the deal complete.

The timeline of events in this case makes it clear that the Legislative branch's strategy of unbounded intervention forced CNOOC to decide that it was unlikely to be able to conclude the deal at all, much less do so in a timely and profitable manner. It was clear that many members of the US government felt the deal needed to be prevented, or blocked if necessary, on national security grounds. But what were their exact concerns, and what really motivated them, causing Congress to react the way it did to the possibility of a CNOOC/Unocal deal? Were geostrategic issues the main concern? It is clear that the context of the geopolitical relationship between the US and China at the time only intensified opposition to a deal that was never going to be easy in the first place because of the national security issues it raised. Indeed, “Washington attorneys familiar with the deal [said that]…CNOOC's biggest problem in Washington was that its attempt collided with US lawmaker's growing frustration with the US relationship with China on issues ranging from currency manipulation to trade reciprocity and intellectual property rights” (Kirchgaessner Reference Kirchgaessner2005). Or was the failure of the deal caused by “a variety of factors – economic nationalism, superpower rivalry, fears about declining US competitiveness, and worries about energy security – [which] blended into a potent mixture” to prevent CNOOC from taking over Unocal, as some (Molchanov Reference Molchanov2005) claimed? The following section will assess the variables hypothesized to be the primary reasons behind unbounded intervention. It should show that while there were many variables influencing government action in this case, the geopolitical issues it raised were clearly the strongest.

Geopolitical Competition

China and the US were, in 2005, as they are now, geopolitical rivals with a highly complex, but mainly amicable, relationship. These states are neither military allies, nor members of the same security community. China is a major, and a rapidly “rising,” power. The relationship between the two countries has long been complicated by each state's position on the status of Taiwan, which Beijing's seeks to reintegrate fully, while Washington seeks to defend the “status quo,” thus treading a fine line between its commitment to a military defense of the island and its commitment to a “one China” policy (see US House 2004).

In the summer of 2005, when the CNOOC bid took place, there was a prevailing perception in the US that China was more than just an emerging power. Many saw it as a strategic rival, which had the potential to develop into a military threat in the future.37 Thus, the DOD made clear in its Annual Report to Congress in 2005:

The United States welcomes the rise of a peaceful and prosperous China, one that becomes integrated as a constructive member of the international community. But, we see a China facing a strategic crossroads. Questions remain about the basic choices China's leaders will make as China's power and influence grow, particularly its military power.

(US DOD 2005, 4)

US unease over China's rapid growth and modernization was amplified by the fact that Chinese military spending is not very transparent (US DOD 2005). For, while the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute (SIPRI) reported its spending in 2005 as $40,300 million (SIPRI 2006), US DOD “estimates put it at two to three times the officially published figures” (US DOD 2005, 4). This means that China's average military growth over the five years leading up to this case may have been much higher than the already large estimates of 11.31%.38 Yet, though this is far greater than the US’ 8.19% average military growth rate over this same period, China's military spending still remained a far second to the US, which totaled $504,638 million in 2005 (SIPRI 2006).

The US continues to engage China economically, politically, and culturally, and trade between the two countries is highly interdependent. Yet, the relationship between them was strained in 2005 by China's growing economic power relative to the US. In relative terms, China's economy was far smaller at the time: China's GDP at PPP was about 50% of US GDP in 2005, or about 52% if you include Hong Kong and Macao.39 Still, the undervaluation of its currency, the yuan (or renminbi), which some analysts then measured as being undervalued by more than 50%, implies that China's economy is larger than suggested by calculations taken from the official exchange rates, and by 2006 China's economy was the second largest in the world (CIA 2007). As with the examination of military growth rates, China's average economic growth rate outstrips that of the US for the five years before 2005, with China's being 12.13% and the US’ remaining at 4.93%.40 Not surprisingly, such figures contribute to US fears that China's relative economic power is growing rapidly.

At the same time, a number of other economic issues contributed to heightened tensions between the two countries. In 2005, China was seen by many as a nation whose financial actions would prove threatening to the future of the US economy. The trade deficit with China had reached $201,544.8 million in 2005 (US Bureau of the Census 2008). There was mounting US pressure placed on China during the summer of 2005 to revalue the yuan, as many in the US believed its undervaluation to be part of an economic policy designed to give China an unfair trade advantage (Preeg Reference Preeg, Bergsten and Williamson2002).41 The Chinese government did revalue the yuan by “2.1% against the US dollar” in July of that summer (CIA 2005, 2007), largely as a palliative measure against deteriorating US–Chinese relations during the CNOOC/Unocal bidding process. Other issues straining Sino–US relations at the time included disputes over intellectual property rights and “an escalating trade row” over Chinese export tariffs on textiles (Financial Times 2005a).

The geopolitical relationship between China and the US in the summer of 2005 was thus characterized by heightened tensions over a series of issues, making CNOOC's bid for Unocal more unpalatable to the US government than it might otherwise have been. Indeed, there was “a widening sense among politicians in both parties that China [was] reaping the benefits of free trade without playing fully by the rules,” which observers rightly believed would make “steering [the] public debate away from politics…difficult” for CNOOC (Linebaugh et al. Reference Linebaugh, Pottinger and Hitt2005). At the time, it seemed that the deal was only “raising political tension between two countries with an already strained relationship” (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005). Dick D'Amato, Chairman of the US–China Economic and Security Review Commission (ESRC), even went so far as to ask: “what in [the] relationship [with China] is working?” (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005). Congressmen Barton and Hall made clear their opposition to the CNOOC bid on the grounds that “the Chinese are great economic and political rivals [of the US], not friendly competitors or allies in democracy” (Alden & Kirchgaessner Reference Kirchgaessner2005).

Geopolitical tensions between the US and China were further sharpened by the fact that both countries were increasingly competing for access to energy resources, over which there were new worries about scarcity of supply. The US resource dependency ratio in 2005 was 36%.42 Though the US was not dependent on China for oil,43 China had recently become highly dependent on oil imports, and the two countries were now actively vying for new sources of supply (CIA 2008). Moreover, an April 2005 IEA Report may have raised fears about the scarcity of oil supplies at the time of the CNOOC/Unocal bid (Greenwire 2005c). All of this, of course, should be understood within the context that, at the time, “most of the world's oil fields [were] already believed to have been discovered, and many of those [were] in oil-producing countries such as Saudi Arabia that [were] off limits to public companies” (Gentile Reference Gentile2005).

In order to appreciate fully the effect of such geopolitical concerns, it is necessary to understand not only the stated rationale behind CNOOC's bid (and the Chinese government's original support), but also what the US government believed to be the real motivation behind it. CNOOC claimed that its deal rationale hinged mainly on the large gains to be made to its Asian asset portfolio: a “nearly 80% increase in reserves and a doubling of production,” which had hitherto been deficient (FD 2005). According to CNOOC, the bid was one made by a commercial company for commercial reasons only. The company, furthermore, claimed that the Chinese government played no role in its decision to make an offer for Unocal.44

Yet, the deal did not necessarily make sense from a purely economic standpoint, for two reasons. First, CNOOC simply did not have the financial wherewithal to pull off its bid without the help of the Chinese government. It lacked the cash for such a high all-cash bid, and clearly needed its “state parent to foot the bill” (Lex 2005c). It was reported that “of the $16 billion in pledges the company has said it has received for its bid, $13 billion comes from state-owned Chinese entities, including $7 billion in long-term and short-term loans from CNOOC's parent China National Offshore Oil Corp” (Gold et al. Reference Gold, Pottinger and Berman2005; see also FD 2005). Second, CNOOC's offer would be a financial burden to the company, as the Fitch Ratings Agency (among others) argued that it would negatively affect their credit rating (see AFX 2005b; PR Newswire 2005; Reuters 2005a). CNOOC's bid was thus perceived as another example of a Chinese company hungry for brands, resources, and assets that could outbid more traditional buyers because of the “extraordinarily cheap financing” it received from its government (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005).

Furthermore, despite CNOOC's claims of independent action, it was clear that the bid had the backing of the Chinese government. First, the government subsidy indicated to many observers that the deal was to a great extent “backed by a [Chinese] state keen for global influence and resources” (Lex 2005a). Second, CNOOC must have had state backing for the bid because all major foreign acquisitions made by Chinese companies were first required to receive Chinese government approval under Chinese law at the time.45 Third, other observers verified that the Chinese government, whether tacitly or actively, was involved in the deal in some way. In fact, “all four of CNOOC's executive directors” were confirmed to be members of the Communist Party, and David Merjan of the mutual fund William Blair & Co. claimed that “it [was] clear that the Chinese Government [was] exerting…pressure on management” (Cheng & Ng Reference Cheng and Ng2005).

The geopolitical positioning of the two countries vis-à-vis world energy resources also forced US policymakers, for good or ill, to assume that CNOOC's bid for Unocal was part of a larger Chinese government policy of trying to gain access to oil resources abroad. A number of market and foreign policy analysts agreed that the Chinese government was using all means available, including the acquisition of foreign companies and the conclusion of JVs abroad through its state-owned national oil companies (NOCs), in order to meet energy demands at home, and to secure supply lines for the future.46 James Sweeney, an energy economist and Director of the Precourt Institute for Energy Efficiency at Stanford University, publicly argued that CNOOC's bid for Unocal was about “security of supply” because “China want[s] to control supply themselves,” and such a deal would arguably give them that control (Greenwire 2005b). The former Executive Director of the IEA, Robert J. Priddle, said at the time that China was “in a panic” because “they're relatively newly dependent on oil imports, and think they must do something to secure their own supply” (Blustein Reference Blustein2005). Similarly, an oil market analyst with Foresight Research Solutions claimed that the race for Unocal was “just round one in the fight for strategic energy resources” (AFX 2005b). McKinsey's Paul Gao maintained that the Chinese “government [was] pushing to create national champions to reduce dependence on foreign technology,” giving it “a mandate…to look overseas for deals” that would help it accomplish this goal (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005).

Indeed, it was quite clear that the Chinese NOCs were busy actively concluding deals with companies in Canada, Sudan, and Venezuela, among other countries (see Greenwire 2005a; Chen Reference Chen2005). The expansion of Chinese M&A activity during 2005 also included a number of big deals in the oil and gas industry (AFX 2005b). At the time of the CNOOC/Unocal case, for example, China Petroleum & Chemical Corp. was looking to buy the Canadian company Husky Energy Inc., and two separate Chinese companies (Synopec and CNOOC) bought stakes in Canadian oil sands development projects (Chen Reference Chen2005; Reguly Reference Reguly2005). Such activity, as discussed later, heightened the fears of some in the US government that the Chinese government was using its NOCs to gain access to foreign oil reserves. Congressman Hunter, for example, was clear that part of his concern emanated from the fact that “China [was] in the business of making strategic acquisitions” (Orol Reference Orol2005c) for the purpose of gaining access to both resources and technology.47

One of the fundamental issues for members of the US legislative branch, therefore, was energy security. A strategic competitor for natural resources was seeking to buy a US company with US assets when it was believed that there was a Chinese government strategy of systematically seeking resources through the use of the “free” market, and there was no guarantee that such a rival might not then take those freely acquired resources “off the market” in the future. For while market analysts generally assumed that CNOOC was only interested in the Asian assets of Unocal, there was no actual guarantee that CNOOC would sell off Unocal's American assets as promised. CNOOC had been vociferous about the fact that it was willing to give up Unocal's US assets in order to get through the CFIUS review process – a tactic that it fully expected to work.48 However, CNOOC's advisor from JP Morgan, Charles Li, made it quite clear to investors that CNOOC had no intention of selling the US assets unless forced to by the US regulatory process.49 Though the US assets involved were relatively small in size, they were of symbolic importance in the context of a greater debate over whether a Chinese state-owned company might divert supplies solely to China in an energy crisis, pulling those reserves off the market and making them unavailable for purchase at any price. Priddle, from the IEA, claimed that a CNOOC/Unocal deal would not “change the price of oil, or the availability of oil,” because these factors would be governed solely by the rules of supply and demand (Blustein Reference Blustein2005). Jerry Taylor of the CATO Institute made basically the same argument to a House Armed Services Committee hearing, claiming that even if China were to pull such supplies from the market, the US could replace them by paying for equivalent supplies from other sources (Kudlow 2005). The three other major witnesses at the hearing, however, completely disagreed with this assessment, instead arguing that the Communist regime was likely to divert those resources if necessary, that those resources would then be going to a rival, and that the market would not necessarily be able to fill the gap.50 One of those witnesses, Thomas Donnelly, a member of the US–China Economic & Security Review Commission, believed “there [was] a fairly strong argument” for blocking the deal “not simply because Unocal is a national asset,” but also because of “the strategic question of how China is approaching energy supplies” (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005). Indeed, the letter sent from Congressmen Barton and Hall to President Bush stated that “this transaction poses a clear threat to the energy and national security of the United States” (Barton & Hall Reference Barton and Hall2005). Their argument was that:

This sale would be a mistake under almost any circumstance, but it would be especially egregious at a time when energy markets are so tight and the US is becoming even more dependent on foreign sources of energy…US national energy security depends on sufficient energy supplies to support US and global economic growth. But those supplies are threatened by China's aggressive tactics to lock up energy supplies around the world that are largely dedicated for their own use. China has used its state-owned oil companies to advance this strategy, by buying up energy assets around the world without regard to human rights and environmental protection, in countries such as Sudan and Iran. And unlike other companies, these resources are not available to the global market.

Similarly, Congressman Hunter announced his “intention to oppose the sale” (International Oil Daily 2005b), which he saw as a security threat not only because China could try to block US access to Unocal's oil assets in Asia, but more fundamentally because it could shift the geopolitical balance of power in Asia. Referring to “investments by Unocal in pipelines running from Caspian sea oil fields through Azerbaijan, Georgia, and Turkey,” Hunter claimed that “China's purchase of Unocal would dramatically increase its leverage over these countries, and therefore its leverage over US interests in those regions” (Eckert Reference Eckert2005). Observers were also concerned that Unocal had terminals that were part of the US Strategic Petroleum Reserve (see e.g., Murray Reference Murray2005; LA Times Reference Laitner and Parker2005).

Energy security, however, was not the only concern sparked by the geopolitical tensions between the two countries. Congress was equally concerned by a number of national security issues that were raised by the perception that the Chinese government backed such foreign takeovers in order to gain access to technology that had dual-use applications, thus helping China to enhance its military (or other forms of) power. Again, the text of Congressmen Barton and Hall's letter gives us an insight into the concerns of the legislative branch on this issue. They stated that:

In addition to this obvious threat to our energy security, the acquisition of Unocal by a Chinese state-owned company poses other risks to our US national security. As a significant player in the US energy industry, Unocal uses a host of highly advanced technologies necessary for the exploration and production of oil and gas. Many of these technologies have dual-use applications. Given the potential military threat posed by China to our allies in Asia and our security interests, it is of the utmost importance that US export control laws be strictly applied to ensure that no sensitive technology falls into the hands of the Chinese government – or, through China, other, more dangerous regimes around the world – which can later be used to undermine our national security.

The SVP and CFO of CNOOC, Hua Yang, had likely confirmed some of these fears when he told investors during a conference call that the deal was desirable because it involved “technical advantages” such as “Unocal's leading deepwater drilling technology[, which] would extend CNOOC's exploration capability” (FD 2005). Yang also stated a desire “to retain substantially all Unocal employees” because they included “a highly skilled management and technical talent pool” that was “driving this technology” (FD 2005), confirming the general belief that CNOOC was as interested in Unocal's technology and expertise as it was in its physical assets.

In the end, there were five major technological and defense-related national security concerns raised during the bidding process. The first was Unocal's deepwater drilling technology. CNOOC was actually formed by the Chinese government “in the early 1980s to explore and develop undersea oil and gas fields” (Gold et al. Reference Gold, Pottinger and Berman2005), but did not have the advanced technology Unocal possessed. In fact, the Research Director of the NBR Energy Security Program, Mikkal Herberg, foresaw that the Chinese company's bid would “incite a ‘firestorm’ in Congress” because of Unocal's “very good deep-water exploration skills, developed in projects off of Indonesia and Mexico that could have military applications,” which “critics are likely to ‘question letting…fall into the hands of the Chinese government’” (Cincinnati Post 2005). Richard D'Amato, Chairman of the US–China Economic Security Review Commission, made similar comments during the House Armed Services Committee hearing on the CNOOC bid (Orol Reference Orol2005c). Second, the related underwater mapping capabilities Unocal possessed were also reportedly one of the causes of concern. “Trade and security analysts” at the time claimed that Unocal's “underwater terrain-mapping technology used for offshore oil exploration…might also be useful in navigation for the Chinese military's growing fleet of submarines” (Lohr Reference Lohr2005). The third concern was raised “in [an unpublished] letter to Energy Bill conference Committee Chairman Joe Barton” by Congressman Pombo, who “pointed out Unocal could have important technologies to access oil shale resources” (Oil Daily 2005a). The fourth issue was Unocal's alleged possession of a rare earth mineral mine that the US government would not want under foreign government control for strategic reasons, because the metals involved reportedly “have military functions for laser technology” (Orol Reference Orol2005c). Congressman Joe Schwartz (R-MI), for example, showed his concern by stating: “these kinds of metal technology are important to our defense posture” (Orol Reference Orol2005c). The final issue raised on pure national security grounds was related to US missile defense capabilities. This issue was, again, raised by D'Amato at the House Armed Services Committee hearing, when he “noted that Unocal has 14 offshore oil platforms in Alaska and the Gulf of Mexico that are near important US defense strategic facilities, an apparent reference to missile defense operations in those regions” (Orol Reference Orol2005c).

In sum, the Sino-US geopolitical relationship in 2005 was mostly characterized by rivalry. Congress clearly defined energy security as a “national security” issue in this case because of that geopolitical context. It is also not surprising that within the context of these geopolitical and deal-specific concerns, many in the US government saw the deal as a Chinese “power grab,”51 and therefore sought to intervene to block it outright. Despite this, both countries recognized their mutual economic dependence, and appreciated the need for constructive engagement, which led to mutual efforts and policies geared toward the maintenance of an overall amicable relationship. It was this recognition of mutual self-interest in a constructive relationship that eventually led the Chinese government to pull its support for CNOOC's bid for Unocal. This case, therefore, clearly shows that states can effectively use unbounded intervention, in line with the purpose of non-military internal balancing, to balance the power of another state without endangering the greater relationship between themselves and that state.

Economic Nationalism

The US is not usually associated with economic nationalism, yet as with many states there remain distinct pockets of such nationalism among members of the US government and its institutions. One source in the legal community that often deals with CFIUS cases pointed out that among all of the US government institutions, the only one that seems to continuously retain elements of economic nationalism is (perhaps not surprisingly) the Department of Commerce, which is one of the agencies involved in the CFIUS process. Thus, while national pride in the US is relatively high,52 instances of economic nationalism in the US are usually fairly targeted and rare. Notably, they have largely been caused in the past by massive influxes of FDI from a particular state, as witnessed by the reaction and response in the US to the huge increase in FDI from Japan in the 1980s.

Some observers made comparisons between the Japanese case and the CNOOC bid, indicating a belief that economic nationalism might be to blame for government intervention (see e.g., Reguly Reference Reguly2005). Part of this was rooted in the fact that the CNOOC bid, if accepted, would have been “China's largest overseas investment ever” (Timmons Reference Timmons2005). Part can be explained in the context of a general expansion of overseas Chinese M&A activity, which included not only the oil and gas deals already mentioned, but also two recent high-profile Chinese purchases in unrelated US industries: Lenovo bought IBM's personal computing (PC) business in 2004 for $1.25 billion and Haier was bidding over a billion dollars for Maytag at the time of the CNOOC bid (Reguly Reference Reguly2005).53 Thus, an element of economic nationalism may indeed have existed against Chinese investment generally, which was particularly aroused by this case, as it would have been the largest Chinese investment yet in a strategic industry in the US. In fact, it does seem true that this case marks the beginning of a period of somewhat increased economic nationalism in the US generally, at least relative to its previously low levels of that sentiment.54

There are some very important differences, though, between the US response to the CNOOC bid and its response to Japanese investment in the 1980s. First, unlike the Japanese in the 1980s, “Chinese companies seem more interested in industrial businesses than trophy assets” (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005). This was of more than symbolic importance, when many in the US government believed that the Chinese government had a policy of supporting/encouraging foreign takeovers through which it could gain technology and resources. This fact, and the geopolitical context between the US and China, made the influx of Chinese FDI much more worrying for the US government. Senator Schumer (D-NY), for example, pointed out that: “Japan was an ally, and Japan was fundamentally a smaller country than we are. [But] China is emerging as a dominant player, and at the same time, China isn't acting like one. It isn't playing by the rules” (Murray Reference Murray2005).

It was for this reason that those concerned with the economic consequences of a possible CNOOC deal believed the issue was (or simply framed it as being) a matter of economic security. Certainly, there was a big push throughout the whole debate over the deal to change the way CFIUS defines national security, and to get economic security issues, such as oil, included in the definition (see Graham & Marchick Reference Graham and Marchick2006, 75, 172; Jackson Reference Jackson2007; Lohr Reference Lohr2005). On June 22, for example, Congressman Pombo said he did “not believe it is in the best interest of the US to have Unocal owned by the Chinese national government,” as it could have “disastrous consequences for our economic and national security” (Greenwire 2005b).

It could be argued that this concern over economic security was an example of economic nationalism. “Some analysts,” indeed, claimed that CFIUS was “being used as a weapon of economic nationalism” by some of the congressman involved (International Oil Daily 2005c). Other scholars, like Graham and Marchick, feared the inclusion of economic security in the national security criteria used by CFIUS could prompt the review process to “become even more politicized,” and possibly allow “domestic companies to exploit the CFIUS process against foreign bidders” in the future (Graham & Marchick Reference Graham and Marchick2006, 143). Indeed, the July 1 House Resolution called on the deal to be blocked, given that “oil and natural gas resources are strategic assets critical to national security and the Nation's economic prosperity” (US House 2005c).

Despite this, it is important to understand that Unocal was never trumpeted as a national champion, and that the US does not really have a history of protecting national champions per se. As one observer poignantly noted: “Unocal is not an economic or cultural icon. For Americans it is holier than that; it's an oil producer” (Reguly Reference Reguly2005). Indeed, neither members of the US government, nor lobbyists, nor pundits, went so far as to call Unocal a national champion; it was a relatively small oil company that provided only a minor portion of the US oil supply. Moreover, the US did not block Chinese efforts to purchase Maytag or IBM, which could have been viewed as national champions in their industries. Within the oil and gas industry, furthermore, the US did not seek to block British Petroleum's (BP's) purchase of Amoco in 1988 or Petróleos de Venezuela's (PDVSA's) purchase of CITGO in 1990, which were arguably of much greater economic importance. In fact, unbounded intervention through CFIUS, or otherwise, was rare on the part of the US before the CNOOC case. For instance, at this time the only transaction to have been formally prohibited by the US President was, interestingly, when in 1989 the China National Aero-Technology Import and Export Corporation (CATIC) bought – and was ordered by the President in 1990 to wholly divest – the US company MAMCO Manufacturing (Bush Reference Bush1990). The intervention was made “to protect national security,” because MAMCO was the sole supplier of certain airplane parts in the US and CATIC was owned and operated by the Chinese government's Ministry of Aerospace Industry, which had clear ties to the Chinese military (Bush Reference Bush1990). After that, one of the largest efforts made to block a deal before the Unocal case was when a Chinese military-owned company (COSCO) tried to lease terminal space at the former US naval base in Long Beach, California.55 It would therefore be difficult to argue that the US has a history of supporting national champions against foreign takeovers, but clear evidence can be found of concern over Chinese state-owned corporations pursuing takeovers of US companies for national security reasons.

Thus, while there was an element of economic nationalism to the efforts of some members of Congress who sought to block the deal on the grounds of “economic security,” these concerns were largely present and intensified because of the larger geopolitical context of the case. Furthermore, these concerns were consistently accompanied, and overshadowed, by anxiety over the national security issues just discussed.

Presence of Interest Groups

The majority of the lobbying in Congress for or against CNOOC's bid for Unocal was backed by either CNOOC or Chevron themselves. Indeed, once it became clear that the two would be battling for control of Unocal, both companies “hired public-relations firms to press their respective agendas” (Gold et al. Reference Gold, Pottinger and Berman2005). As demonstrated in this section, Chevron's lobbying efforts played an undeniable role in making members of Congress aware of the national security issues posed by CNOOC's bid. Yet, it will also be argued that these lobbying efforts played on pre-existing national security concerns, and would not have resonated with Congress outside of the geopolitical context of this case.

Chevron was definitely the biggest and primary interest group actively lobbying against CNOOC's bid. The Vice-Chairman of Chevron, Peter Robertson, immediately declared that he felt Chevron was “competing with the Chinese government and…that is wrong,” because “clearly, this is not a commercial competition” (Mouwad & Barboza Reference Mouwad and Barboza2005). Chevron went much further than scathing commentary, however. In fact, it was “Chevron lobbyists [who] helped draft language for at least one letter [that was] circulated by lawmakers to Treasury Secretary John Snow, [which] warns that CNOOC's bid for Unocal…challenges American jobs, energy production and national security” (Pierce & Newmeyer Reference Pierce and Newmeyer2005). They also “provid[ed] Member offices with information to support th[ose] claims,” and even helped “to gather signatures for the letter to Snow” (Pierce & Newmeyer Reference Pierce and Newmeyer2005).

A history of campaign contributions to certain members of Congress by Chevron was also considered by many to have helped its cause. Californian representatives, where Chevron was based, obviously had a vested interest in looking out for the company (International Oil Daily 2005a). It is also important to note, however, that “both [Congressmen Hall and Barton] have received significant contributions from Chevron Corp. and Texaco” in the past (Orol Reference Orol2005d). The Center for Responsive Politics had released information that “Barton received $19,000…while Hall received $9,500” from these companies (Orol Reference Orol2005d). It was also reported that Congressman Pombo had received $13,500 from Chevron (Alden & Kirchgaessner Reference Kirchgaessner2005). It is unlikely, however, that these contributions (the exact timing of which are unspecified) would alone have swayed these congressmen into such active opposition to the CNOOC deal. Many domestic companies that later end up in bidding wars with foreign companies contribute to lawmaker's campaigns, and yet it is extremely rare for those lawmakers to come out so vociferously against a foreign takeover.

Thus, it is highly unlikely that Chevron's lobbying could have been effective without there first being genuine national security and geostrategic issues for it to play upon. To be sure, it was reported at the time that “Chevron Lobbyists are finding a warm reception to the patriotic message they have been pitching on Capitol Hill, especially among Members with oil and gas interests in their districts as well as those with long-standing national security concerns” (Pierce & Newmeyer Reference Pierce and Newmeyer2005). For example, Congressman Barton's spokesman Larry Neal responded to criticism over the congressman's position (raised because he had received donations from Chevron in the past) by saying: “Chairman Barton has consistently opposed advancing Chinese governmental interests” (Pierce & Newmeyer Reference Pierce and Newmeyer2005).56 Thus, the general consensus (not surprisingly) was that “while Chevron skillfully drummed up opposition to CNOOC's bid in Washington, it was merely tapping into already existing anti-China sentiment” (EIU 2005).

Outside of Chevron's lobbying efforts, there was one former policymaker in particular who lobbied vociferously against the deal, both as a witness at the House Armed Services Committee hearing and through press, TV, and radio interviews. This was Frank Gaffney, a former member of the Pentagon under President Ronald Reagan and, at the time, the head of the Center for Security Policy. Gaffney took a realist approach to the deal, arguing that China was not an ally and, as already mentioned, that he was worried it was using the deal to gain access to resources it would then make unavailable to the US in the future. While his arguments were well received at the hearing, they lost some support in the public when he lost his realist rational tone and went so far as to call those in favor of the deal “panda huggers” (Kudlow 2005).

CNOOC, however, had also hired a small army of lobbyists and advisors, which it used to counter the image Chevron painted of its intentions. CNOOC actually hired “three investment banks, a pair of media strategy groups, and four law firms” (Linebaugh et al. Reference Linebaugh, Pottinger and Hitt2005). The firms hired to “manage the media firestorm” were “Public Strategies Inc., a firm with close ties to the Bush White House, and Brunswick Group, which handled the corporate meltdown at the energy company Enron” (Pierce & Newmeyer Reference Pierce and Newmeyer2005). The law firms included Akin Gump Strauss Hauer & Feld, which also was reported to have close “connections to the White House” (Linebaugh et al. Reference Linebaugh, Pottinger and Hitt2005; Pierce & Newmeyer Reference Pierce and Newmeyer2005). Public Strategies diligently argued, as did CNOOC itself, that the transaction was meant to be a purely “commercial deal” (Gentile Reference Gentile2005). It was also reported that CNOOC's many lobbyists anticipated the arguments put forward by those against the deal,

and prepared an aggressive response. CNOOC's Chairman immediately sent letters to every member of Congress and to the media. He argued that a Unocal purchase was not a threat to the US at all. Most of Unocal's assets are in Asia, not America. And CNOOC [would] sell whatever Unocal holdings are [in the US]. Unocal's US employees [wouldn't] have to worry either. CNOOC [would] not fire any of them, he wrote.

CNOOC also had a variety of other interest groups on its side, which were not paid lobbyists, but which (for various reasons) had a vested interest in making sure that the bid was not blocked. The US Chamber of Commerce, the one institution from which we might possibly expect an economic nationalist response, publicly announced that it was not against a CNOOC bid for Unocal (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005). Indeed, a number of economic liberal groups were concerned that the market should be allowed to work. The National Foreign Trade Council, which wished to encourage more FDI from China, tried to speak out against the “paranoia” surrounding the deal (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005). Similarly, the National Association of Manufacturers had spoken out against “China's manipulation of its currency,” but it maintained “a relaxed stance on takeovers” like many other business lobbies, which, again, welcomed such Chinese FDI (Kirchgaessner et al. Reference Kirchgaessner2005). Finally, Jerry Taylor, of the libertarian think-tank the CATO Institute, spoke out often against blocking the deal, usually arguing against Gaffney's position. In fact, he was the only witness at the July 13 Congressional hearing who believed the national security concerns were overblown (AFX 2005c), on the basis that the purchase would not pose a threat to US security because, among other reasons, the US would still be able to purchase oil on the open market.57 Others who were advocates for the deal included Albert Keidel of the Carnegie Endowment, who argued that the US must:

engage China in a rules-based global system, as the bedrock for our national military security…If we try to create a non-price based system for securing or guaranteeing energy resources or other scarce resources, we will be creating a climate that will force China into a similar posture. And that is dangerous, in a national military-security sense.

(Voice of America 2005)

It should be noted that, despite all of this lobbying, two important and influential players in the case remained neutral. The first is the White House, which argued that it would reserve judgment on the deal until it received a report from CFIUS, when – and if – that process was triggered by a transaction agreement between CNOOC and Unocal (see Wright Reference Wright2005).58 Part of the desire to appear neutral may have been because Secretary Rice had previously served as member of Chevron's board (International Oil Daily 2005a). The Administration was very clear that the decision would be made on the merits of the national security assessment of the deal presented to it by the appropriate agency, and that it would not be swayed by interest group efforts.

The second group that remained neutral, and un-swayed by lobbyist pressure, was Unocal itself. As already mentioned, it was quite clear that Unocal's CEO Charles Williams wanted a bidding war, and was actively speaking to both companies throughout the whole process. “Unocal spokesman Barry Lane,” for example, made it clear that “his company [was] not actively lobbying Congress on the issue, but [was] considering the CNOOC counter bid” (Pierce & Newmeyer Reference Pierce and Newmeyer2005). It was also apparent that Unocal's shareholders, one of the most important interest groups in the takeover of a public company, wanted the highest price possible for the company, no matter who the eventual owner was. Two minority shareholders even went so far as to sue “[Unocal's] board of directors for a breach of their fiduciary duty to the shareholders,…contending that the directors failed to test the value of the company fully in the marketplace before hastily accepting Chevron's [original] proposal” (Amaewhule Reference Amaewhule2005), despite the board's comments that it would still consider CNOOC's later offer.59

There also did not seem to be any sort of true labor or union movement against the CNOOC bid, which might have been effective if it had been present. This was probably because of CNOOC's constant claims that it would “seek to retain substantially all Unocal employees” (FD 2005). CNOOC Chairman Fu Chengyu said that the deal would be “good for America,” because CNOOC “[would] protect Unocal's US jobs” (Gold et al. Reference Gold, Pottinger and Berman2005). The attorneys general of some states affected by the deal worried that the CNOOC bid might negatively affect Unocal pension plans and its promises on the environment (International Oil Daily 2005b).60 Yet, these concerns were directed toward Unocal itself, not policymakers, and they did not turn into a widespread movement or seem to have any impact on the deal.

Thus, while some interest groups were pressing for the US government to block a CNOOC/Unocal deal – namely, those sponsored by CNOOC's competitor Chevron – these groups were not the primary motivation behind the US government's strategy of unbounded intervention. For there was an equal amount of pressure on the government coming from CNOOC's lobbyists, as well as from independent free-market and liberal interest groups. Furthermore, it is likely that even if the Chevron-sponsored groups had not lobbied against the deal, a number of these national security issues – especially those involving technology – would have been flagged in the CFIUS process anyway. Finally, Chevron was really only able to make lawmakers aware of existing national security issues involved in the deal, and was not able to coerce them into action. It would not have been able to have any effect on Congress if the geopolitical context of the deal had not been as it was, meaning that interest group presence – though it may have played a role in making legislators aware of the case earlier – was not the primary motivation behind government intervention into this foreign takeover.

Competition Concerns

Importantly, no real competition issues were involved with either CNOOC's or Chevron's bid for Unocal. Indeed, the Chevron/Unocal deal received competition clearance from the Federal Trade Commission by June 10, 2005, and no competition problems were expected to arise from CNOOC's alternative bid. “Marc Schildkraut, an attorney with law firm Heller Ehrman, said he [did] not see antitrust problems for the CNOOC-Unocal deal, commenting, ‘It's extremely rare for the FTC to care about upstream deals’” (International Oil Daily 2005a). In fact, the only evidence of any concern on this issue comes from Charlie Crist, the Florida Attorney General, who wrote a letter to John Snow urging a review of the deal, because “[he was] concerned about the impact of increasing concentration in the petroleum industry on gasoline prices” (AFX 2005d). Yet, Snow's only comment on the deal was that it would be reviewed if the CFIUS process was triggered, and he did not evince any concern on competition grounds. Indeed, the general consensus of the market seemed to be that “whatever legal tools might be used to block a deal, antitrust probably won't be one of them,” because “there is little to suggest an excessive concentration of ownership in the worldwide oil industry” (Orol Reference Orol2005a).

Finally, it should be noted that the US is generally considered to be one of the most competitive economies in the international marketplace, in the sense that it is a state open to liberal economic business practices and foreign investment.

Conclusions on CNOOC/Unocal

Thus, it must be concluded that unbounded intervention in this case was primarily motivated by the geopolitical issues surrounding the Chinese state-owned company's bid for Unocal, and secondarily by economic nationalism. Interest group presence may have also played a much smaller, tertiary, role in motivating intervention. Yet, it is important to note that neither economic nationalism nor interest group presence would have had the effect that they did in the absence of the geopolitical context, without which those opposed to the case would not have been able to gain the support that they eventually found. Finally, competition issues did not seem to play any significant role.

Unbounded intervention in this case was, thus, clearly an example of non-military internal balancing. CNOOC's bid, and the presumed role played by its state-owned parent company, caused apprehension over the use by the Chinese government of its rising economic power to “buy” power in the form of companies that would supply it with resources, knowledge, and technology. Furthermore, certain members of the US government did not wish to allow China to win the “energy race” through the use of government-subsidized asset purchases that might result in control over vital resources. Therefore, intervention was about preventing a transfer in those forms of relative power from occurring. While this situation, in the context of increased Chinese FDI in the US, did arouse a certain amount of economic nationalist sentiment, intervention was not about saving a national champion (as it was in the Danone case). It was about intervening in a market transaction to prevent the loss of relative power to a strategic rival. For, while the CNOOC case was in process, Secretary Rice visited China and made it clear that the US government was aware of “a significant military buildup going on [in China], that is concerning, [and causing the US to]…have concerns about the military balance” (Rice Reference Rice2005). Indeed, those who objected to the deal seemed to honestly believe that the sale of Unocal to CNOOC could lead to the transfer of military technology and of resources that could also eventually be used by the Chinese military. Others, as already mentioned, were concerned that ownership of the company would give the Chinese government more social power and influence in Asia, or even provide it with the ability to gain more power over Taiwan (see e.g., States News Service 2005a). As one member of the US–China ESRC noted, the US was not dealing with “a market economy,” because “[China] see[s] resource acquisition as an integral part of their military plans. We need to look at it on the same basis” (Blustein Reference Blustein2005). Similarly, former CIA director James Woolsey called CNOOC's attempt to take over Unocal a “sharp elbow” (Eckert Reference Eckert2005) from a bully, and said that “anyone who believes this is a purely commercial undertaking…is extraordinarily naïve” (Ivanovich Reference Ivanovich2005).

Finally, the CNOOC/Unocal case provides an excellent example of unbounded intervention as non-military internal balancing. This is because the “balancing” was targeted and finite, and used a tool that was not expected to – and ultimately did not – damage the overall relationship between the two countries involved.

Case 3: Check Point/Sourcefire

The Story

On October 6, 2005, Check Point Software Technologies Ltd. (an Israeli company) made a mixed cash and share offer for Sourcefire Inc. (a US company) for about $225 million. At the time, both companies specialized in security software, and both provided software to the US government, making the deal seem like a smart fit to market and tech analysts alike.61 The deal rationale provided by the companies was that Sourcefire's intrusion prevention system (IPS) software (including a well-known open-source system called Snort) would complement and “strengthen Check Point's perimeter, internal, Web and endpoint security portfolio,” allowing it to “expand” into the “fast-growing intrusion prevention and network awareness” business (Check Point 2005).62 This rationale was well received, and the deal quickly gained the support of the “boards of both companies as well as Sourcefire shareholders” (Vaas Reference Vaas2005), after which it was subjected to an initial thirty-day CFIUS review and the Hart–Scott–Rodino anti-trust process.

On February 13, Check Point confirmed that CFIUS had decided to pursue a further forty-five-day investigation of the deal (Check Point 2006a), and that both companies were cooperating in that process.63 Though the proceedings of the investigation itself are classified, and the Treasury Department refused to officially comment on whether or not the deal would have made it through the investigation unscathed, it emerged that several objections were raised to the deal while CFIUS performed its review (see Dagoni Reference Dagoni2006; FD 2006; Lemos Reference Lemos2006).64 The primary reported objection was against allowing a foreign company (any foreign company) to take control of a software company that provided computer network and systems security for a number of US government agencies, including the Federal Bureau of Investigation (FBI), the DOD, and the National Security Agency (NSA) (see Dagoni Reference Dagoni2006; Greene Reference Greene2006; Rothman Reference Rothman2006; Williams Reference Williams2006). These agencies “expressed concern” that the deal “[put] their networks at risk” (Rothman Reference Rothman2006) and would have allowed Israel to “acquire sensitive technology” related to “the implementation of Sourcefire's anti-intrusion software ‘Snort’” (Williams Reference Williams2006). Peter Cooper, a Morgan Stanley analyst, claimed “CFIUS feared that the takeover would expose SNORT to manipulation by a non-US entity” and “that Check Point would shut down the open source software and limit accessibility by users,” because “similar occurrences (unrelated to Check Point) had happened before” (Dagoni Reference Dagoni2006).

Objections may also have been raised to Check Point, specifically. For, while the company had a “National Security Agency certification” and “has had success in US government security projects,” some commentators questioned whether there was concern over the security of the company itself (McLaughlin Reference McLaughlin2006). One observer, for example, suggested that certain members of government might have had “a dim view of the close ties between key Check Point executives and the [Israeli Defense Forces], especially unit 8200,” which handles signals and encryption intelligence (Dagoni Reference Dagoni2006). Additionally, an industry source claimed at the time that “government contractors [had] told him that they [were] strictly prohibited from using Check Point software” (McLaughlin Reference McLaughlin2006).

Either way, it seems that enough concerns were raised during the CFIUS process to assume that the government's actions were tantamount to unbounded intervention. Throughout the process, it was clear that either the deal would be blocked or the requirements placed on both companies would be so onerous, and the delay to the completion of the deal so great, that Check Point would withdraw its offer voluntarily. For instance, “in private meetings between the panel and Check Point, FBI and Pentagon officials” made it obvious to the company that they “took exception to letting foreigners acquire the sensitive technology” (Williams Reference Williams2006). Apparently, Check Point's “lawyers had tried to salvage the deal by offering to attach conditions intended to satisfy the Feds, despite execs feeling they were onerous,” but “agreement could still not be reached” between the parties (Williams Reference Williams2006). It was even reported that “the US [government] made the approval process so miserable for both parties that they threw in the towel” (Rothman Reference Rothman2006).

Thus, on March 23, 2006, Check Point announced that it was withdrawing from the CFIUS process, a week ahead of the recommendation the Committee was due to make to the President regarding the deal (Lemos Reference Lemos2006). CFIUS agreed to its withdrawal, and Check Point declared in a press release that it was now seeking a simple “business partnership” with Sourcefire, rather than continuing to pursue its acquisition of the company (Check Point 2006b; Dagoni Reference Dagoni2006). Check Point also released a statement providing its rationale for abandoning the transaction, stating that “given the complex technology, the complexity of the process, [and] the current scrutiny of CFIUS, we have come to the conclusion that it may be simpler and better to pursue other partnership alternatives or take more time to work with the government” (Lemos Reference Lemos2006). Sourcefire's Chief Marketing Officer similarly blamed the pullout on “the complexities of the overall CFIUS process, the lengthy ongoing delays and the current climate for international acquisitions” (Chickowski Reference Chickowski2006). One industry source believed that “the government” may have “put forward requirements that the companies found unacceptable” or that “CFIUS was dragging its feet” on purpose (Brockmeier Reference Brockmeier2006).

Yet, it was more than the costly delays and complex negotiations that scuttled the deal. For a number of analysts agreed that “the Bush Administration would have vetoed the Check Point…Sourcefire deal and that withdrawal from the acquisition was the only way for Check Point to avoid being branded a security risk” (Dagoni Reference Dagoni2006). Thus, in the end, the deal was dropped because of unbounded government intervention: multiple objections were raised by the government agencies that took part in the CFIUS investigation, the process was lengthy and difficult enough to be viewed as discouraging the transaction, and it was overwhelmingly believed that the deal would be blocked by the government at the end of that process.

Because Sourcefire's spokesman had mentioned the “current political climate,” some observers blamed the government's intervention, and thus the ultimate failure of this deal, on the negative attitudes toward FDI raised by the DPW dispute, which was in full swing by the time Check Point withdrew from the CFIUS investigation.65 Yet, the member agencies of CFIUS had raised objections to the deal long before the ports row began (Weisman & Schmidt Reference Weisman and Schmidt2006).66 Furthermore, the nature and tenor of their concerns, which were not politicized by lawmakers as they were in the DPW transaction, suggest that the DPW dispute did not play a significant role in motivating government intervention in this case, as the software deal was unlikely to survive the CFIUS process anyway (see e.g., Brockmeier Reference Brockmeier2006). Indeed, the only role the ports dispute may have played was to contribute to the belief on the part of Check Point that its bid would be blocked by CFIUS, though it has yet to be proven that CFIUS can be swayed in its recommendations by political pressure, and enough reasons can be cited for the deal to have been blocked beyond the existence of a negative “political climate.

Geopolitical Competition

Though the US and Israel are not formal military allies,67 the historical relationship between them has been extremely close, and is considered by many to constitute a security community (see Adler in Katzenstein et al. Reference Katzenstein1996, 434; Adler & Barnett Reference Adler and Barnett1998, 33). For, “even though there is no treaty obligation” between them, “President Bush has said several times that the United States would defend Israel militarily in the event of an attack” (Migdalovitz Reference Migdalovitz2007, 23), a fact ensured by the close historical, diplomatic, and political relationship between the two countries.68 As Adler points out, however, even this “special relationship” can be subject “to corrosive forces,” and will, therefore, at times experience tension within it (Adler in Katzenstein et al. Reference Katzenstein1996, 434).

At the time of this particular transaction, for example, tensions between the two countries had only just begun to ease after a 2003 dispute over “Israeli arm sales to China,” which caused the “annual interagency strategic dialogue” between the two countries to be suspended until November 2005 (Migdalovitz Reference Migdalovitz2007, 29–30). And while Israel itself is obviously not perceived as a strategic competitor or general threat, US government agencies remain concerned that its lack of cooperation on issues relating to US export control laws could negatively impact US national security.69 Part of the problem has been that Israel is not a party to any of the multilateral export control regimes, and only “voluntarily adhere[s] to the Wassenaar Arrangement on Export Controls for Conventional Arms and Dual-Use Goods and Technologies” (Migdalovitz Reference Migdalovitz2007, 32; SIPRI 2004). Just over a month before Check Point made it its bid for Sourcefire,

the US DOD and the Israeli Ministry of Defense issued a joint press statement reporting that they had signed an understanding “designed to remedy problems of the past that seriously affected the technology security relationship and to restore confidence in the technology security area. In the coming months additional steps will be taken to restore confidence fully.”

(Migdalovitz Reference Migdalovitz2007, 25)

Given this climate, it is not surprising that the US would be concerned about the purchase of a US company, which developed network security for its federal agencies, by an Israeli one. For, as one industry commentator noted, even among the closest of “allies,…all bets are off relative to source code” (Rothman Reference Rothman2006).70 Indeed, a great deal of legitimacy would have been given to the concern that the sensitive code, which would have been purchased as part of this deal, might be passed on not only to the Israeli government, but also possibly to third-party governments that might be on less friendly terms with the US.

While it seems clear that these geostrategic concerns provided strong motivation for the US government's unbounded intervention in this case, it is unlikely that any of the remaining geopolitical factors to be examined in this section played such a significant role. First, it is unlikely that US resource dependency played any role in this case. The level of US resource dependency, while not low at 36.35% in 2005 and 37.68% in 2006, is also not excessively high compared to that of other nations.71 Moreover, Israel is not a major supplier of energy to the US, providing just 0.04% of US imports of crude oil and petroleum products in 2005 and 2006 combined (EIA 2008c). Second, the relative power differential between the two countries is not only decidedly in the US’ favor, but does not seem to be changing in any significant way. Unlike the US, Israel is not considered a major power, and it is also not considered a rising power. The five-year average economic growth rates of both countries remained largely similar.72 Furthermore, Israel's military expenditure remained under 2.5% of that of the US, and its five-year average military growth rate actually declined during 2005 and 2006, while that of the US increased.73

Economic Nationalism

As discussed in the CNOOC case, the level of economic nationalism in the US was considered to be fairly low.74 Sourcefire was never referred to as a national champion and, though it is very important to the government, it is an extremely small company.75 Overall, the industry at the time seemed to believe the combination would be good for the technology involved, and for the industry as a whole (see McLaughlin Reference McLaughlin2006; Rothman Reference Rothman2006; Vaas Reference Vaas2005). The US is also “Israel's largest trading partner,” and that trade is far from insignificant, totaling $29.9 billion in 2005 (Jones 2006; Migdalovitz Reference Migdalovitz2007). This can partly be attributed to the US–Israeli free-trade agreement (Migdalovitz Reference Migdalovitz2007, 21). Thus, it would not have made a huge amount of sense for the government to block the deal on economic nationalist grounds, and there seems to be no evidence available to show that this was a motivation behind its unbounded intervention.

Presence of Interest Groups

Finally, the control variable of interest group presence did not seem to provide a motivation for government intervention in this case, either. No evidence can be found of interest groups lobbying against the deal (outside of the government agencies themselves), and the only lobbying that does seem to have occurred was in favor of the deal. Though “Check Point had committed to an all out effort to lobby the committee for approval,” its efforts were reportedly unsuccessful (Lemos Reference Lemos2006). In fact, the most powerful interest group in the US, the Israel lobby, would have been in favor of the deal. No reason can be found for the labor pool involved in the deal to protest either, as Check Point announced to the press that it “w[ould] be adding SourceFire's 140 employees to its own staff of 1400 and expect[ed] no layoffs” (Vaas Reference Vaas2005). Thus, in addition to the lack of evidence that this particular variable motivated government intervention, it is also highly unlikely that it would have done so.

Competition Concerns

Nor is there evidence available to show that competition concerns played any role in motivating government intervention in this case. The US concern with its competitive role in the international marketplace has already been explained in the CNOOC case, and is unlikely to have played any role here. Furthermore, there is definitive proof that anti-trust competition concerns did not affect this transaction in a negative way. Check Point was “granted early termination” of the competition waiting period that is part of the Hart–Scott–Rodino process by both the FTC and the DOJ's Antitrust Division in November 2005 (Federal Register 2005), long before CFIUS even started its forty-five-day investigation.

Conclusions on Check Point/Sourcefire

Thus, we must conclude that it was national security concerns, motivated by specific geopolitical concerns, which were the root cause of unbounded government intervention in this case. It is rare for geopolitical concerns to be the primary motivating factor within the context of a security community relationship, and this case is critical because it demonstrates how and why this can occur. The US was worried not only about maintaining access to the Snort intrusion protection software created by Sourcefire (which was “open source”), but also over other Sourcefire systems used by the government (which were “not open source”), which would have been wholly owned by a foreign company if the transaction had been successful (Brockmeier Reference Brockmeier2006). Indeed, the US concerns over the deal seem to be legitimate given Israel's fairly lax approach to export controls of sensitive technology in the past. Thus, it can be concluded that the primary (and sole) motivating factor behind government intervention in this case was geostrategic concern.

Case 4: Macquarie/PCCW

The Story

On June 19, 2006, PCCW Ltd. (based in Hong Kong) confirmed that a consortium led by Macquarie Bank (of Australia) had made a preliminary offer for its core media and telephone assets for an estimated $5.15 billion (International Herald Tribune 2006a; Mitchell Reference Mitchell2006; Zephyr 2006c).76 The potential transaction came under fire almost immediately, as the Chinese state-owned China Netcom77 raised major objections to the sale. At the time, China Netcom was the second-largest shareholder of PCCW, with a 20% stake in the company, as well as a “shareholder's agreement” that gave it control over any future sale of the company beyond a certain threshold (Fellman & Ong Reference Fellman2006).78 The state-run company claimed on June 21 that it was not “willing to see any major changes to the asset structure of PCCW” (Fellman & Ong Reference Fellman2006), and it was reported only two days later to have “objected to any sale of PCCW's assets on the basis that the company is and should remain ‘owned and managed by Hong Kong people’” (Lau & Mitchell Reference Lau and Mitchell2006b).

China Netcom made it clear it would not approve of the sale to such a foreign consortium,79 an action that had, at the very least, the tacit approval of the Chinese government. By June 27, it was reported that “China Netcom, the State-owned Assets Supervision and Administration Commission, and the Ministry of Information submitted reports to China's State Council about the bids for PCCW and are awaiting instruction” (Kwong Reference Kwong2006). Such actions made it apparent that the state-run shareholder would do what Beijing wished in the matter, and “most people involved in the PCCW saga think the Chinese government worked through China Netcom to scuttle the Macquarie and TPG Newbridge bids on nationalist grounds” (Dyer et al. Reference Dyer, Tucker and Mitchell2006). The issue was greater than simply one of nationalism, however: the telecommunications sector is viewed as “a very strategic asset” in China, making the Chinese government “sensitiv[e] toward overseas ownership” in that industry (Chan & Fellman Reference Chan and Fellman2006).

Macquarie's consortium tried to overcome China's stark opposition by offering to incorporate China Netcom into the deal. By June 25, “Macquarie, seeking to make its bid acceptable to China, had offered China Network a 50% stake in a new Hong Kong phone company it planned to set up with the assets” purchased in the proposed deal (Mitchell Reference Mitchell2006). Yet, this only seemed to cause more political problems, as the Hong Kong authorities were concerned it would only increase the “political and commercial clout” of Beijing in Hong Kong (Mitchell Reference Mitchell2006). Similarly, it was argued that “China's perceived sensitivity over the sale of Hong Kong assets to foreign parties raises questions about whether there are in fact unwritten limits to the territory's economic and financial freedoms, which are guaranteed under its mini-constitution, the Basic Law” (Lau & Mitchell Reference Lau and Mitchell2006a). This solution seemed unworkable not only for Beijing, but for Hong Kong as well.

Thus, it was not surprising when PCCW rejected approaches from both Macquarie and TPG on July 25. PCCW blamed the failure of the bids on China Netcom, because the company had, “in its capacity as a shareholder,…repeatedly indicated its opposition to such an asset sale” (Tucker & Mitchell Reference Mitchell2006). By July 29, Rupert Murdoch told the press that China was “treating Macquarie as hostile invaders” (Lau Reference Lau2006).80 Indeed, the market widely accepts that the Chinese government would have blocked the Macquarie/PCCW deal if necessary, though this was in effect achieved through the objections of its company China Netcom.81 As the following exploration of the motivations behind this behavior show, this was again a case of geopolitical competition and economic nationalism leading to state intervention in a cross-border acquisition.

Geopolitical Competition

Though their relationship is not necessarily negative, China and Australia are not allies or members of the same security community. Certainly, Australia is not really perceived as a threat to China, though there are points of tension and disagreement on issues such as human rights, intellectual property, and the treatment of Taiwan (Australia DFAT 2007b). Indeed, China is considered a major, and rising, power, while Australia is not, and China is clearly more powerful than Australia in both military and economic terms. China's five-year average economic growth rate was 12.09% in 2006, while Australia's was 4.94%, and Australia's PPP GDP in 2006 was only 9.28% of China's.82 Similarly, China's five-year average growth rate of military expenditure was 12.35% in 2006, compared with Australia's 4.56% (SIPRI 2006). Considering that Australia's military expenditure was only about 27.87% that of China's at the time (SIPRI 2006), Australia had much greater concern for China's power than the other way around.

Furthermore, China's general level of dependence on energy imports was fairly low in 2006 at 0.14%, but there are some resource areas in which China recognizes the importance of its geopolitical relationship to Australia. First, China has signed two agreements with Australia on the transfer of nuclear material: the Australia–China Nuclear Material Transfer Agreement and the Nuclear Cooperation Agreement, which entered into force on February 3, 2006 (Australia DFAT 2007a). This is because China expected that it would soon be required to import uranium for the purposes of electrical generation in nuclear plants, as its own supply of nuclear energy is outstripped by demand (Australia DFAT 2007a). Australia's cooperation on this resource issue makes it seem more likely that China would wish to maintain a cordial economic relationship between the two countries.

Yet, China has also recently made it clear that it does not wish to become reliant on any individual country generally, or on Australia specifically, for natural resources. Only two years after the PCCW case, the Chinese government sought to block the acquisition of Rio Tinto by BHP Billiton, by purchasing enough shares of Rio Tinto in a “dawn raid” to achieve a 9% stake in the company, “mak[ing] it more difficult for BHP to buy Rio” (Bream et al. Reference Bream2008). Though steel is a non-energy-related basic resource, it is vitally important to the running of any nation, especially one with a rapidly developing infrastructure and military. It was reported that “the Chinese government [was] dismayed at the prospect of a BHP takeover of Rio as it would give the combined company a virtual monopoly on iron ore supplies to China, which it fears would lead to higher prices and damage the country's economic growth” (Bream et al. Reference Bream2008). The “dawn raid” was “a joint exercise” between “Chinalco, a state-owned mining company” and “Alcoa, the US aluminum group,” which “spent $14bn in [the] move designed to block [the] planned $119bn takeover bid from rival miner BHP Billiton” (Bream et al. Reference Bream2008). As one market source, who spoke on the condition of anonymity, confirmed, the primary mover behind the intervention was the Chinese government, whose concern over its source of steel prompted it to willingly (and greatly) overpay for the stake in order to prevent the takeover.83 Thus, China is obviously quite willing to block M&A that threaten its access to or control over certain key industries and resources.

Furthermore, China exhibits a tendency to view most nations as strategic competitors – especially in geo-economic terms – irrespective of the historical details of their bilateral relationship. Thus, it would be difficult to imagine a scenario in which China's actions to prevent a foreign takeover were not at least partially motivated by this larger geostrategic concern and the desire to protect its position of power within the international system. As examined next, China's outlook means that economic nationalism is tied in this case to geopolitical competition.

Economic Nationalism

China and Australia have a fairly good economic relationship. Both are members of APEC and the East Asia Summit (Australia DFAT 2008). A free-trade agreement also exists between the two countries, and bilateral trade is one of the foundations of the relationship and of continued dialogue between them (Australia DFAT 2007b).

Despite this, however, economic nationalism in China is on the rise, and it is clear that economic nationalism played some role in the government intervention in this case. It is true that at this time the level of national pride in China was not overwhelming, at 24.7% (WVS 2001–04), and that pro-globalization sentiment was just above the median value of fifty-four countries surveyed in 2006, and on a similar level to the attitudes toward globalization in the US that year (see IMD 2007b).84 Yet, in China, an unusually high disconnect exists between these measurements – determined through questions asked of the general population – and the actual levels of nationalism or economic nationalist sentiment present in the Chinese government, which still runs a large portion of the state's economy. Barry Naughton argued in his 2007 testimony to the US–China ESRC that there had been “a clear increase in economic nationalism” in China in recent years (US–China ESRC 2007).85 In fact, there was widespread concern over “rising economic nationalism in China” at this time, not only among analysts and academics, but also among “senior officials from a number of countries” – especially in relation to recent Chinese opposition to the proposed foreign takeovers of Chinese companies (XFN 2006b; see also XFN 2006a; Morgan Reference Morgan2006).

There has also been a history of significant support for national champions in China since the 1980s (US–China ESRC 2007). That was when China began to “experiment with industrial policies…designed to strengthen larger firms and grow ‘national champions’” (US–China ESRC 2007). While this policy weakened in the mid-1990s, experts agree that China seems to have resumed its support for national champions over “the past five years” (US–China ESRC 2007). Though the Chinese government never referred to PCCW as a “national champion” on record, the company held the majority of the telecommunications business in Hong Kong and was referred to as China Netcom's “cash cow” (Schwankert Reference Schwankert2006), making it – at the very least – an important asset for a national champion, namely China Netcom.

Significantly, the Chinese government formally banned foreign investment in the telecommunications industry, and thus in companies such as PCCW, just months after the Macquarie bid was blocked, indicating the degree of sentiment against foreign takeovers in China at the time, and the negative reactions to deals such as the one being investigated here. In September 2006, less than two months after the Macquarie/PCCW transaction failed, the new Provisions for Mergers and Acquisitions of Domestic Enterprises by Foreign Investors, regulating foreign takeovers in China, came into force. Article 12 of these Provisions establishes the right to review foreign M&A that would establish control over Chinese companies that are in a “major industry, ha[ve] or may have influence on state security, or…[involve a] domestic enterprise owning [a] famous trademark.”86

In addition to the new Provisions on Acquisitions, two separate Chinese government bodies that have played a significant role in protectionist policies against foreign takeovers – the State Asset Supervision and Administration Commission (SASAC) and the National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC) – issued new directives around the time of the failed Macquarie/PCCW transaction. First, the Chairman of SASAC announced in December 2006 that the Chinese state would “retain absolute control over [seven] sectors that are important to state security and economy,” namely “telecommunications,…petroleum,…military-related industry, power and power networks, coal, civil aviation, and shipping,” though some limited foreign investment would be allowed in some areas (Zheng Reference Zeng2007). This meant the Chinese government would maintain “more than 50% ownership stakes in the primary firms in those industries” (US–China ESRC 2007).87 According to Naughton's testimony, this law “merely re-affirms the status quo” (US–China ESRC 2007), demonstrating that it was always unlikely the Chinese government would have allowed Macquarie to take control of PCCW. Second, in February 2007, it was reported that the NDRC wanted to create a body called the Joint Review Commission for Foreign Investment Sectors, which would review foreign takeovers in a large number of Chinese sectors (AFX 2007).88

It should also be noted here that by September 2011, the Chinese government had established a national “security review” for foreign takeovers, which – while loosely similar in form to the CFIUS process – retains a very different character. For example, the Chinese government Circular on the process states that the “content of [the] security review” will include not only “the effect of [the transaction] on the national security,” but also its “effect” on “national steady economic growth” and “basic social living order.”89 (For a more detailed discussion of the Chinese FDI laws that have been introduced since this case, see Chapter 5).

Thus, it is clear that a high level of economic nationalism existed before, during, and after the failed Macquarie bid for PCCW: economic nationalism specifically targeted against foreign takeovers. It is also clear that telecommunications and media are particularly sensitive industries for the Chinese government when it comes to foreign takeovers for strategic reasons. The directives issued shortly after Macquarie's bid illustrate the Chinese government's desire to deter any such attempted takeovers in the future, and indicate its willingness to block those bids that are attempted. With all of this in mind, it is fairly obvious that economic nationalism – in addition to geopolitical concerns over their economic and military power – played a distinct role in motivating the Chinese to engage in unbounded intervention in this particular case.

Presence of Interest Groups

It is highly unlikely that interest group presence played a role in motivating intervention in this case. This is because the Chinese political system does not allow interest groups to flourish, and frequently crushes any such opposition to the will of the government. No interest groups were observed to be placing pressure on the government to block the deal at the time. Indeed, the only interest groups that seemed to appear in relation to the case represented members of Macquarie's consortium, and they were, obviously, in favor of the deal. This variable, therefore, can be ruled out as a motivating factor in this case.

Competition Concerns

As will be recalled, one form of “competition” that might be connected to China's actions has to do with whether or not China is believed to be “competitive” in the international market as a state open to foreign investment and business. It is fairly clear that, in certain industries, such as the telecommunications industry examined here, China is not open to such investment insofar as large-scale takeovers are concerned. Yet, China has made a distinct effort to encourage such foreign investment in other sectors, and even to encourage alternative forms of FDI in sensitive sectors, whether through JVs or co-sponsored projects. This is why the subjective economic competitiveness rating for China in 2006 was 4.58, just below the mean rating for the countries examined in the database. Though it does seem clear, in this case, that government intervention was connected to one of those areas it had “closed” to such competition.

On the other hand, competition concerns, as they are traditionally understood, are unlikely to have played a role in motivating government intervention in this case. At the time, several laws existed in China “incorporating antitrust provisions and prohibitions on anti-competitive conduct,” but these laws were largely “fragmented, confined in scope, and rarely enforced” (Ha & O'Brien Reference Ha and O'Brien2008; see Huang & Richardson Reference Huang and Richardson2005).90 For example, in relation to merger controls to address anti-trust competition concerns arising from cross-border M&A, the 2003 Interim Provisions on Mergers and Acquisitions of Domestic Enterprises by Foreign Investors prohibited foreign takeovers that “might lead to over-concentration, impair fair competition, or damage consumers’ interests.”91 But the Interim Provisions did “not specify any penalties…for non-compliance with the [law], and no follow-up activity appears to be taken in the vast majority of [cases]” (Ha & O'Brien Reference Ha and O'Brien2008). Thus, China did not yet have a formal comprehensive anti-competition regime in place at the time of the failed Macquarie bid, of the type that was later adopted under the 2008 Anti-Monopoly Law (AML).92 Even had there been one, there is no evidence to suggest that the proposed transaction would have caused an unwelcome concentration within the telecommunications or media industries, as Macquarie is an investment bank and not a telecoms company.

Conclusions on Macquarie/PCCW

The Chinese government's effort to block the takeover of PCCW by the consortium led by Australia's Macquarie through the actions of its State-run company China Netcom was primarily motivated by geopolitical and economic nationalist concerns that were deeply interrelated. In China, it seems to be more difficult to separate these two variables from one another, as economic nationalism in the M&A sector plays such an unambiguous role in the State's efforts to increase or maintain its relative power, at the very same time that it is trying to open up other areas of its economy under World Trade Organization (WTO) rules in order to enhance its international standing. Indeed, this remains one of the areas in which China can protect itself from unwanted FDI, as the “sensitivity” of the sectors allows it to engage in such protectionism with some measure of impunity and without fear of retaliation. Indeed, Macquarie's failed bid did not seem to cause any tangible damage to the overall relationship between Australia and China, though it may have discouraged similar attempts at investment from being made in the near future.

Conclusion

The four cases of unbounded intervention examined in this chapter provide excellent supporting evidence for both the theory of non-military balancing and the conclusions reached in Chapter 2. In keeping with the fundamental argument of this book, each case demonstrates that government interventions were usually motivated by either geopolitical or economic nationalist concerns, with one or the other being the primary and/or secondary motivation in every case. In further support of the conclusions reached in Chapter 2, geopolitical concerns were also the primary reason for unbounded intervention in every case where the two states involved were not members of the same security community. This includes the CNOOC/Unocal and Macquarie/PCCW cases, though the nature of China's capitalist autocracy does make geopolitical concerns and economic nationalism more difficult to disentangle in the latter.

Interestingly, the Check Point/Sourcefire case illustrates that geopolitical concerns can, under certain conditions, also be the primary motivator behind unbounded intervention within the security community context if, for example, the acquiring state raises very specific, and hard to avoid, security concerns regarding the takeover in question. In the Check Point/Sourcefire case, for example, the issue was Israel's history of lax adherence to export control laws in combination with a target company with extremely sensitive technology used by US government agencies.

Not surprisingly, the only case in which economic nationalism provided the primary motivation behind unbounded intervention was the PepsiCo/Danone one. Yet, it is important to note that, even in this case, geopolitical tension was the secondary reason for the government's desire to block the transaction in question. This suggests that geopolitical competition is usually present in some form or another when a state chooses a strategy of unbounded intervention over, say, one of “bounded” intervention (a point that will be explored further in Chapter 5).

Furthermore, the control variable of “interest group presence” was found to play only a minor role, and the control variable of “competition concern” no role at all, in the government's action in the four cases explored in this chapter. Indeed, interest groups were only moderately effective in raising awareness in the CNOOC/Unocal case. It is significant, however, that the role of interest groups was simply to alert government actors to pre-existing concerns, and was not a primary or secondary motivator of intervention, per se.

In sum, the four cases examined here provide clear support for the primary hypothesis and its supporting assumptions. Figure 27 summarizes the motivations for unbounded intervention uncovered in each of these cases.

CaseGeopolitical CompetitionEconomic Nationalism
Security Community Cases
PepsiCo/DanoneSecondaryPrimary
Check Point/SourcefirePrimary
Non-Security Community Cases
CNOOC/UnocalPrimarySecondary
Macquarie/PCCWPrimarySecondary

Figure 27 Motivation matrix: unbounded intervention

Finally, each of these cases supports the secondary hypothesis that the type of intervention employed by the state would be closely correlated to the deal outcome. In each case, governments engaged in unbounded intervention, and in each case, the deal was either completely or “effectively” blocked.

Figure 0

Figure 26 Unbounded intervention: critical cases examined in Chapters 3 and 4

Figure 1

*

Figure 2

Figure 27 Motivation matrix: unbounded intervention

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Unbounded Intervention
  • Ashley Thomas Lenihan, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: Balancing Power without Weapons
  • Online publication: 30 March 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316855430.005
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Unbounded Intervention
  • Ashley Thomas Lenihan, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: Balancing Power without Weapons
  • Online publication: 30 March 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316855430.005
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Unbounded Intervention
  • Ashley Thomas Lenihan, London School of Economics and Political Science
  • Book: Balancing Power without Weapons
  • Online publication: 30 March 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316855430.005
Available formats
×