Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Home
Hostname: page-component-cf9d5c678-h2mp8 Total loading time: 0.961 Render date: 2021-07-27T22:44:17.878Z Has data issue: true Feature Flags: { "shouldUseShareProductTool": true, "shouldUseHypothesis": true, "isUnsiloEnabled": true, "metricsAbstractViews": false, "figures": true, "newCiteModal": false, "newCitedByModal": true, "newEcommerce": true, "newUsageEvents": true }

Broadening the role of “self-interest” in folk-economic beliefs

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 August 2018

Mia Karabegović
Affiliation:
Department of Cognitive Science, Central European University, Budapest 1051, Hungary. karabegovic_mia@phd.ceu.eduhttps://cognitivescience.ceu.edu/people/mia-karabegovic-0
Amanda Rotella
Affiliation:
Department of Psychology, University of Guelph, Guelph, ON N1G 2W1, Canada. arotella@uoguelph.cabarclayp@uoguelph.cahttp://amandarotella.ca/research/http://www.patbarclay.com/
Pat Barclay
Affiliation:
Department of Psychology, University of Guelph, Guelph, ON N1G 2W1, Canada. arotella@uoguelph.cabarclayp@uoguelph.cahttp://amandarotella.ca/research/http://www.patbarclay.com/

Abstract

We extend Boyer & Petersen's (B&P's) model of folk-economic beliefs (FEBs) by suggesting FEBs serve self-interest (broadly defined), which includes indirect benefits such as creating alliances, advancing self-beneficial ideologies, and signaling one's traits. By expanding the definition of self-interest, the model can predict who will hold what FEBs, which FEBs will propagate, when they will change, why, and in which direction.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2018 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

Mia Karabegović and Amanda Rotella contributed equally to the preparation of this commentary.

References

Barclay, P. (2013) Strategies for cooperation in biological markets, especially for humans. Evolution and Human Behavior 34(3):164–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barclay, P. (2016) Biological markets and the effects of partner choice on cooperation and friendship. Current Opinion in Psychology 7:3338. Available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.copsyc.2015.07.012.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barclay, P. & Willer, R. (2007) Partner choice creates competitive altruism in humans. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 274(1610):749–53.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cialdini, R. B. & Goldstein, N. J. (2004) Social influence: Compliance and conformity. Annual Review of Psychology 55:591621.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
DeScioli, P. & Kurzban, R. (2013) A solution to the mysteries of morality. Psychological Bulletin 139(2):477–96. doi: 10.1037/a0029065.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
DeScioli, P., Massenkoff, M., Shaw, A., Petersen, M. B. & Kurzban, R. (2014) Equity or equality? Moral judgments follow the money. Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B: Biological Sciences 281(1797):e20142112.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Galperin, A. & Haselton, M. G. (2013) Error management and the evolution of cognitive bias. In: Sydney Symposium of Social Psychology: Social thinking and interpersonal behavior, ed. Forgas, J. P., Fiedler, K. & Sedikides, C., pp. 4564. Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Higham, J. P. (2014) How does honest costly signaling work? Behavioral Ecology 25(1):811.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naumann, E., Buss, C. & Bähr, J. (2015) How unemployment experience affects support for the welfare state: A real panel approach. European Sociological Review 32(1):8192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owens, L. A. & Pedulla, D. S. (2014) Material welfare and changing political preferences: The case of support for redistributive social policies. Social Forces 92(3):1087–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petersen, M. B., Aarøe, L., Jensen, N. H. & Curry, O. (2014) Social welfare and the psychology of food sharing: Short-term hunger increases support for social welfare. Political Psychology 35(6):757–73. doi: 10.1111/pops.12062.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petersen, M. B., Sznycer, D., Sell, A., Cosmides, L. & Tooby, J. (2013) The ancestral logic of politics: Upper-body strength regulates men's assertion of self-interest over economic redistribution. Psychological Science 24(7):1098–103.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Roccas, S., Sagiv, L., Schwartz, S. H. & Knafo, A. (2002) The big five personality factors and personal values. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 28(6):789801.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shalvi, S., Gino, F., Barkan, R. & Ayal, S. (2015) Self-serving justifications: Doing wrong and feeling moral. Current Directions in Psychological Science 24(2):125–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weeden, J. & Kurzban, R. (2014) The hidden agenda of the political mind: How self-interest shapes our opinions and why we won't admit it. Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Send article to Kindle

To send this article to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about sending to your Kindle. Find out more about sending to your Kindle.

Note you can select to send to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be sent to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Broadening the role of “self-interest” in folk-economic beliefs
Available formats
×

Send article to Dropbox

To send this article to your Dropbox account, please select one or more formats and confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your <service> account. Find out more about sending content to Dropbox.

Broadening the role of “self-interest” in folk-economic beliefs
Available formats
×

Send article to Google Drive

To send this article to your Google Drive account, please select one or more formats and confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your <service> account. Find out more about sending content to Google Drive.

Broadening the role of “self-interest” in folk-economic beliefs
Available formats
×
×

Reply to: Submit a response

Please enter your response.

Your details

Please enter a valid email address.

Conflicting interests

Do you have any conflicting interests? *