Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-9pm4c Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T08:56:32.648Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2012

Gordon C. Rausser
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley
Johan Swinnen
Affiliation:
Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium
Get access
Type
Chapter
Information
Political Power and Economic Policy
Theory, Analysis, and Empirical Applications
, pp. 489 - 514
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. 2003. “Why Not a Political Coase Theorem? Social Conflict, Commitment, and Politics.” Journal of Comparative Economics 31:620–652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and J.A., Robinson. 2000. “Political Losers as a Barrier to Economic Development.” American Economic Review 90:126–130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and J.A., Robinson. 2001a. “A Theory of Political Transitions.” American Economic Review 91:938–963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and J.A., Robinson. 2001b. “Inefficient Redistribution.” American Political Science Review 95:649–661.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D.A. and J.A., Robinson, 2005. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D. and J.A., Robinson. 2008. “Persistence of Power, Elites and Institutions.” American Economic Review 98:267–293.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., M., Golosov and A., Tsyvinski. 2006. “Markets versus Governments: Political Economy of Mechanisms.” NBER Working Paper No. 12224.
Ackrill, R. 2000. The Common Agricultural Policy. Sheffield Academic Press, Sheffield.Google Scholar
Adams, G., G., Rausser and L., Simon. 1996. “Modelling Multilateral Negotiations: An Application to California Water Policy.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 30:97–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P., A., Alesina, and F., Trebbi. 2004. “Endogenous Political Institutions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119:565–611.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aghion, P. and O.J., Blanchard. 1993. “On the Speed of Transition in Eastern Europe.” Unpublished, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.Google Scholar
Ahmed, S. 1966. “On the Theory of Induced Innovation.” Economic Journal 76: 344–357.Google Scholar
Alston, J. and B.H., Hurd. 1990. “Some Neglected Social Costs of Government Spending in Farm Programs.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72:150–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, J. and J.S., James. 2002. “The Incidence of Agricultural Policy.” In Handbook of Agricultural Economics, B., Gardner and G., Rausser (eds.). Volume 2, Chapter 33, Elsevier North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Alston, J. and W., Martin. 1995. “Reversal of Fortune: Immiserizing Technical Change in Agriculture.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 77:225–259.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, J. and P.G., Pardey. 1994. “Distortions in Prices and Agricultural Research Investments.” In Agricultural Technology: Policy Issues for the International Community, J.R., Anderson (ed.). CAB International, Wallingford, 59–84.Google Scholar
Alston, J.M. and P.G., Pardey. 1996. Making Science Pay: The Economics of Agricultural R & D Policy. American Enterprise Institute Press, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Alston, J., G., Edwards, and J., Freebairn. 1988. “Market Distortions and Benefits from Research.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 70:281–288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, J., G.W., Norton, and P.B., Pardey. 1995. Science Under Scarcity: Principles and Practice for Agricultural Research Evaluation and Priority Setting. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY.Google Scholar
Alston, J., P.G., Pardey, and J., Roseboom. 1998. “Financing Agricultural Research: International Investment Patterns and Policy Perspectives.” World Development 26:1057–1071.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alston, J.M., P.G., Pardey, J.S., James and M.A., Andersen. 2009. “A Review of Research on the Economics of Agricultural R&D.” In Annual Review of Resource Economics 1.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alt, J.E. and K.A., Shepsle. 1990. Perspectives of Positive Political Economy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amacher, G.S., E., Koskela, E.M., Ollikainen. 2004. “Environmental Quality Competition and Eco-labeling.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 47:284–306.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amemiya, T. 1985. Advanced Econometrics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Amiti, M., and J., Konings. 2007. “Trade Liberalization, Intermediate Inputs, and Productivity: Evidence from Indonesia.” American Economic Review 97:1611–1638.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anbar, D. and E., Kalai. 1978. “A One-Shot Bargaining Problem.” International Journal of Game Theory 7:13–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, J.R., P.G., Pardey, and J., Roseboom. 1994. “Sustaining Growth in Agriculture: A Quantitative Review of Agricultural Research Investments.” Agricultural Economics 10:107–123.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K. 1995. “Lobbying Incentives and the Pattern of Protection in Rich and Poor Countries.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 43:401–423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K. (ed.) Forthcoming. Distortions to Agricultural Incentives: A Global Perspective, 1955 to 2007. Palgrave Macmillan, London.CrossRef
Anderson, K. and E., Valenzuela. 2007. “Do Global Trade Distortions Still Harm Developing County Farmers?Review of World Economics 143:108–139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, K. and Y., Hayami. 1986. The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection. Allen & Unwin Inc., Winchester.Google Scholar
Anderson, K., R., Damania, and L.A., Jackson. 2004. “Trade, Standards, and the Political Economy of Genetically Modified Food.” CEPR Discussion Papers 4526, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
Arndt, T.M., D.G., Dalrymple, and V.W., Ruttan. 1977. Resource Allocation and Productivity in National and International Agricultural Research. University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values, 1st edition, Wiley, New York.Google Scholar
Aslund, A. 1991. “Principles of Privatization.” In Systematic Change and Stabilization in Eastern Europe, L., Csaba (ed.), Aldershot, Dartmouth, UK, 17–31.Google Scholar
Asscher, N. 1976. “An Ordinal Bargaining Set for Games without Side Payments.” Mathematics of Operations Research 1:381–389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. and J., Stiglitz. 1980. Lectures on Public Economics. McGraw-Hill: New York.Google Scholar
Aumann, R.J. 1985. “An Axiomatization of the Non-Transferable Utility Value”. Econometrica 53:599–612.Google Scholar
Aumann, R.J. and M., Kurz. 1977. “Power and Taxes.” Econometrica 45:1137–1161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Austen-Smith, D. 2000. “Redistributing Income under Proportional Representation.” Journal of Political Economy 108:1235–1269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balaoing, A. and J., Francois. 2006. “The Political Economy of Protection in a Customs Union: What Drives the Tariff Structure of the EU?” Tinbergen Institute, Erasmus University Rotterdam, Working Paper.
Baland, J.M. and A., Kotwal. 1998. “The Political Economy of Underinvestment in Agriculture.” Journal of Development Economics 55:233–247.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, R. and F., Robert-Nicoud. 2007. “Entry and Asymmetric Lobbying: Why Governments Pick Losers.” Journal of the European Economic Association 5:1064–1093.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bale, M.D. and B.L., Greenshields. 1978. “Japanese agricultural distortions and their welfare value”. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 60:59–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, R.J. 1995. “Interest Groups, Influence and Welfare.” Economics and Politics 7: 119–146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, V.E. 1985. “Output, Input, and Productivity Measurement in U.S. Agriculture, 1948–79.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67:475–486.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardhan, P. 1989. The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions. Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Baron, D.P. and J.A., Ferejohn. 1987.“Bargaining and Agenda Formation in Legislatures.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 14:117–173.Google Scholar
Baron, D.P. and J.A., Ferejohn. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83:1181–1206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrett, S. 1994. “Strategic Environmental Policy and International Trade. Journal of Public Economics 54:325–338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barrett, C.B. and Y., Yang. 2001. “Rational Incompatibility with International Product Standards.” Journal of International Economics 54:171–191.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basset, T. and D., Crummey. 1993. Land in African Agrarian Systems. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.Google Scholar
Becker, G.S. 1983. “A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98:371–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G.S. 1985. “Public Policies, Pressure Groups, and Dead Weight Costs.” Journal of Public Economics 28:329–347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, G. and C.B., Mulligan. 2003. “Deadweight Costs and the Size of Government.” Journal of Law and Economics 46:293–340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beghin, J.C. 1990. “A Game Theoretic Model of Endogenous Public Policies.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72:138–148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beghin, J.C. and M., Kherallah. 1994. “Political Institutions and International Patterns of Agricultural Protection.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 76:482–489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beghin, J.C., W.E., Foster and M., Kherallah. 1996. “Institutions and Market Distortions: International Evidence for Tobacco.” Journal of Agricultural Economics, 47:355–365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Belloc, M. and P., Guerrieri. 2008. “Special Interest Groups and Trade Policy in the EU.” Open Econ Review 19:457–478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, A. and J., Sachs. 1992. “Structural Adjustment and International Trade in Eastern Europe: The Case of Poland.” Economic Policy 14:117–173.Google Scholar
Bernheim, B.D., and M.D., Whinston. 1986. “Menu Auctions, Resource Allocation, and Economic Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 101:1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and M., Ghatak. 2007. “Retailing Public Goods: The Economics of Corporate Social Responsibility.” Journal of Public Economics 91:1645–663.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T. and S., Coate. 1998. “Sources of Inefficiency in a Representative Democracy: A Dynamic Analysis.” American Economic Review 88:139–156.Google Scholar
Besley, T. and S., Coate. 2001. “Lobbying and Welfare in a Representative Democracy.” Review of Economic Studies 68: 67–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bhagwati, J.N. 1971. ‘The Generalized Theory of Trade and Welfare.’ In Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth, J.N., Bhagwati, R.W., Jones, R.A., Mundell, J., Vanek (eds.). North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Bhagwati, J.N. 1982. “Directly Unproductive Profit Seeking Activities: A Welfare Theoretic Synthesis and Generalization.” Journal of Political Economy 90:988–1002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bindseil, U. and C., Hantke. 1997. “The Power Distribution in Decision Making among EU Member States.” European Journal of Political Economy 13:171–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K. 1987. “Nash Bargaining Theory II”. In The Economics of Bargaining, K., Binmore and P., Dasgupta (eds.). Basil Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. and P., Dasgupta. 1987. “Nash Bargaining Theory: An Introduction.” In The Economics of Bargaining, K., Binmore and P., Dasgupta (eds.). Basil Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Binmore, K.G., A., Rubinstein, and A., Wolinsky. 1986. “The Nash Bargaining Solution in Economic Modelling.” Rand Journal of Economics 17:176–188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binswanger, H., K., Deininger, and G., Feder. 1995. “Power, Distortions, Revolt and Reform in Agricultural Land Relations. In Handbook of Development Economics, Volume 3, C, Hollis and T.N., Srinivasan (eds.). Elsevier North Holland, Amsterdam: 2659–2672.Google Scholar
Binswanger, H., Y., Mundlak, M., Yang, and A., Bowers. 1985. “Estimation of Aggregate Agricultural Supply Response.” Unpublished manuscript, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Bishop, R.L. 1964. “A Zeuthen-Hicks Theory of Bargaining.” Econometrica 32: 410–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, D. 1948. “On the Rationale of Group Decision Making.” Journal of Political Economy 56:23–34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, D. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Blanchard, E. and G., Willmann. 2007. “Political Statis or Protectionist Rut? Policy Mechanisms for Trade Reform in a Democracy.” Unpublished manuscript, University of Virginia.Google Scholar
Bockstael, N. 1984. “The Welfare Implications of Minimum Quality Standards.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 66:466–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bombardini, M. 2008. “Firm Heterogeneity and Lobby Participation.” Journal of International Economics 75:329–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bordes, G. and N., Tideman. 1991.“Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives in the Theory of Voting.” Theory and Decision 30:163–186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. and H., Gintis. 1993.“Power and Wealth in a Competitive Capitalist Economy”. Philosophy and Public Affairs 21:334–353.Google Scholar
Boyce, J. and R., Evenson. 1975. National and International Agricultural Research and Extension Programs. Agricultural Development Council, New York.Google Scholar
Brandow, G.E. 1961. “Interrelations Among Demands for Farm Products and Implications for Control of Market Supply.” Bulletin No. 680, Pennsylvania Agricultural Experiment Station, University Park, PA.Google Scholar
Bredahl, M., W.K., Bryant, and V.W., Ruttan. 1980. “Behavior and Productivity Implications of Institutional and Project Funding of Research.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62:371–383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brock, W.A. and S.P., Magee. 1979. “Tariff Formation in a Democracy.” In Current Issues in International Commercial Policy and Economic Diplomacy, J., Black and B., Hindley (eds.). MacMillan Press, London.Google Scholar
Browning, E.K.The Marginal Cost of Public Funds.” Journal of Political Economy 84:283–298.
Buchanan, J.M. 1965. “An Economic Theory of Clubs.” Economica 32:1–13.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchanan, J.M. 1975. The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Buchanan, J.M. and G., Tullock. 1962. The Calculus of Consent. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burton, D.M., H.A., Love, and G.C., Rausser. 2004. “Estimating Statistical Properties of Political Economic Decisions”, Applied Economics 36:1489–1499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buccola, S. and C., Sukume. 1993. “Social Welfare of Alternative Controlled-Price Policies.” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 75:86–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bullock, D.S. 1994a. “Are Government Transfers Efficient? An Alternative Test of the Efficient Redistribution Hypothesis.” A paper prepared for the 1994 Annual Meeting of the American Agricultural Economics Association (San Diego, CA), University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign.Google Scholar
Bullock, D.S. 1994b. “In Search of Rational Government: What Political Preference Studies Measure and Assume.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76: 347–361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burt, O.R. and V.E., Worthington. 1988. “Wheat Acreage Supply Response in the United States.” Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 13:100–111.Google Scholar
Cadot, O., J., Melo, and M., Olarreaga. 2004. “Lobbying, Counterlobbying, and the Structure of Tariff Protection in Poor and Rich Countries.” World Bank Economic Review 18:345–366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carter, M.R. 1987.“Risk Sharing and Incentives in the Decollectivization of Agriculture.” Oxford Economic Papers 39:577–595.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caselli, F. and M., Morelli. 2004. “Bad Politicians.” Journal of Public Economics 88: 759–782.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castanheira, M. and R., Gerard. 2000. “The Optimal Speed of Transition: A General Equilibrium Analysis.” International Economic Review 41:219–239.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, R.G. and R.J., Just. 1979. “A Critique of Exchange Rate Treatment in Agricultural Trade Models.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 61:249–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, R.G. and R.J., Just. 1981. “Effects of Exchange Rate Changes on U.S. Agriculture: A Dynamic Analysis.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63:32–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chambers, R.G. and R., Lopez. 1993. “Public Investment and Real-Price Supports.” Journal of Public Economics 52:73–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chavas, J.P. and R.M., Klemme. 1986. “Aggregate Milk Supply Response and Investment Behavior on U.S. Dairy Farms.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 678:55–66.Google Scholar
Che, J. 2009. “A Dynamic Model of Privatization with Endogenous Post-Privatization Performance.” Review of Economic Studies 76:563–596.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cho, I. K. and D.M., Kreps. 1987. “Signalling Games and Stable Equilibria.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 102:179–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chow, G.C. 1981. Econometric Analysis by Control Methods, John Wiley & Sons, NewYork.Google Scholar
Coase, R.H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 16:386–405.Google Scholar
Coase, R.H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coate, S. and S., Morris. 1995. “On the Form of Transfers to Special Interests.” Journal of Political Economy 103:1210–1235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coate, S. and S., Morris. 1999. “Policy Persistence.” American Economic Review 89: 1327–1336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cochrane, W.W. 1979. The Development of American Agriculture: A Historical Analysis. The University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.Google Scholar
Coggins, J.S. 1995. “Rent Dissipation and the Social Cost of Price Policy.” Economics and Politics 7:147–166.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coleman, W.D. and S., Tangermann. 1999. “The 1992 Reform, the Uruguay Round and the Commission: Conceptualizing Linked Policy Games.” Journal of Common Markets 37:385–405.Google Scholar
Cooper, R.N. and R., Layard. 2002. What the Future Holds: Insights from Social Science. MIT Press, Boston.Google Scholar
Cooper, R. and W., Ross. 1985. “Product Warranties and Double Moral Hazard.” Rand Journal of Economics 16:103–113.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corden, W.M. 1969. “Effective Protection Rates in the General Equilibrium Model.” Oxford Economic Papers 21:135–141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coricelli, F., F., Milesi, and M., Gian. 1993. “On the Credibility of Big Bang Programs: A Note on Wage Claims and Soft Budget Constraints in Economies in Transition.” Discussion Paper 124, Center for Economic Performance, London School of Economics.
Cornes, R. and T., Sandler, 1996. The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corson, W. and W., Nicholson. 1981. “Trade Adjustment Assistance for Workers: Results of a Survey of Recipients under the Trade Act of 1974.” In Research in Labor Economics, Vol. 4, JAI Press, Greenwich, CT, 417–469.Google Scholar
Coyle, W.T. 1981. Japan's Rice Policy, Foreign Agricultural Economics Report Number 164(July), Economics and Statistics Service, USDA.
Craeybeckx, J., 1973. “De agrarische depressie van het einde der XIXe eeuw en de politieke strijd om de boeren I.” Belgisch Tijdschrift voor Nieuwste Geschiedenis 4: 190–230.
Crampes, C. and A., Hollander. 1995. “Duopoly and Quality Standards.” European Economic Review 39:71–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremer, J. and T.R., Palfrey. 2000. “Federal Mandates by Popular Demand.” Journal of Political Economy 108: 905–927.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 1996. “Legislative Procedures in the European Community.” British Journal of Political Science 26:199–228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 1997. “The Codecision Procedure in the European Union.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 22:97–119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C. 2000. “Institutional Reform and Codecision in the European Union.” Constitutional Political Economy 11:41–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Crombez, C., T., Groseclose, and K., Krehbiel. 2006. “Gatekeeping.” Journal of Politics 68:322–334.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Currie, J. and A., Harrison, 1997, “Sharing the Costs: The Impact of Trade Reform on Capital and Labor in Morocco.” Journal of Labor Economics 15:44–71.
Curtis, K.R., J., McCluskey, and T., Wahl. 2004. “Consumer Acceptance of Genetically Modified Food Products in the Developing World.” AgBioForum 7:69–74.Google Scholar
Curtis, K.R., J., McCluskey, and J., Swinnen. 2008. “Differences in Global Risk Perceptions of Biotechnology and the Political Economy of the Media.” International Journal of Global Environmental Issues 8:79–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dahl, R.A. 1957. “The Concept of Power.” Behavioral Science 2:201–215.Google Scholar
Dal Bo, E. and R. Di, Tella. 2006. “Plato O Plomo: Bribes and Punishments in a Theory of Political Influence.” American Political Science Review 100: 41–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Gorter, H. and D., Zilberman. 1990. “On the Political Economy of Public Good Inputs in Agriculture.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72:131–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Gorter, H. and J., Swinnen. 1994. “The Economic Polity of Farm Policy.” Journal of Agricultural Economics 45:312–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Gorter, H. and J., Swinnen. 1998. “The Impact of Economic Development on Redistributive and Public Research Policies in Agriculture.” Review of Development Economics 2:41–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Gorter, H. and J., Swinnen. 2002. “Political Economy of Agricultural Policies.” In The Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume 2, B., Gardner and G.C., Rausser (eds.). Elsevier Science: North Holland, Amsterdam, 2073–2123.Google Scholar
de Gorter, H. and Y., Tsur. 1991. “Explaining Price Policy Bias in Agriculture: The Calculus of Support-Maximizing Politicians.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 73:1244–1254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Gorter, H., D.J., Nielson, and G.C., Rausser. 1992. “Productive and Predatory Public Policies.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74: 27–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Gorter, H., D.J., Nielson, and G.C., Rausser. 1995. “The Determination of Technology and Commodity Policy in the U.S. Dairy Industry.” In GATT Negotiations and the Political Economy of Policy Reform, G.C., Rausser (ed.). Springer-Verlag, New York, 253–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Gorter, H., J., Pokrivcak, and J., Swinnen. 1998. “The ‘Restaurant-Table’ Effect: Europe and the Common Agricultural Policy.” In World Agricultural Trade, T., Yildrim, A., Schmitz and W. H., Furtan (eds.), Westview Press, Boulder.Google Scholar
Deininger, K. and G., Feder. 2002. “Land Institutions and Land Markets.” In Handbook of Agricultural Economics, B., Gardner and G.C., Rausser (eds.). Amsterdam: Elsevier North Holland, 288–331.Google Scholar
de Janvry, A. 1981. The Agrarian Question and Reformism in Latin America. The John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.Google Scholar
de Janvry, A. 1984.“The Role of Land Reform in Economic Development.” In Agricultural Development in the Third World, C.K., Eicher and J.M., Statz (ed.), The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 263–274.Google Scholar
de Janvry, A., E., Sadoulet, and M., Fafchamps. 1989. “Agrarian Structure, Technological Innovation, and the State.” In The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions, P., Bardhan (ed.), Clarendon Press, Oxford, 356–382.Google Scholar
Dennis, R. 2000. Steps Toward Identifying Central Bank Policy Preferences. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, San Francisco, CA.Google Scholar
Dewan, T. and K.A., Shepsle. 2008a. “Recent Economic Perspectives on Political Economy, Part I.” British Journal of Political Science 38:362–382.Google ScholarPubMed
Dewan, T. and K.A., Shepsle. 2008b. “Recent Economic Perspectives on Political Economy, Part II.” British Journal of Political Science 38:543–564.Google ScholarPubMed
Dewatripont, M. and G., Roland. 1995. “The Design of Reform Packages under Uncertainty.” American Economic Review 8:1207–1223.Google Scholar
Dewatripont, M., I., Jewitt, and J., Tirole. 1999. “The Economics of Career Concerns, Part II: Application to Missions and Accountability of Government Agencies.” Review of Economic Studies 66:199–217.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A. 1980. “The Role of Investment in Entry Deterrence.” The Economic Journal 90:95–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A.K. 1996. The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction Cost Politics Perspective. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Dixit, A.K. and J.B., Londregan. 1995. “Redistributive Politics and Economic Efficiency.” American Political Science Review 89:856–866.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A.K., G.E., Grossman, and E.L., Helpman. 1997. “Common Agency and Coordination: General Theory and Application to Government Policy Making.” Journal of Political Economy 105:752–769.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domar, E.D. 1970. “The Causes of Slavery and Serfdom: A Hypothesis.” Journal of Economic History 30:18–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dutt, P. and D., Mitra. 2005. “Political Ideology and Endogenous Trade Policy: An Empirical Investigation.” Review of Economics and Statistics 87:59–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, A. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. Harper, New York.Google Scholar
Eaton, J., and G.E., Grossman. 1985. “Tariffs as Insurance: Optimal Commercial Policy When Domestic Markets Are Incomplete.” Canadian Journal of Economics 18: 258–272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Edwards, G.W. and J.W., Freebairn. 1984. “The Gains from Research into Tradable Commodities.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 66:41–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ehrlich, S.D. 2007. “Access to Protection: Domestic Institutions and Trade Policy in Democracies.” International Organization 61:571–605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Efron, B. 1979. “Bootstrap Methods: Another Look at the Jackknife.” Annals of Statistics 7:1–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Efron, B. 1987. “Better Bootstrap Confidence Intervals, with Discussion.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 82:181–185.Google Scholar
Efron, B. and G., Gong. 1983. “A Leisurely Look at the Bootstrap, the Jackknife, and Cross-Validation.” The American Statistician 37:36–48.Google Scholar
Efron, B. and R., Tibshirani. 1986. “Bootstrap Methods for Standard Errors, Confidence Intervals, and Other Measures of Statistical Accuracy.” Statistical Science 1:54–75.Google Scholar
Elbasha, E.H. and T.L., Riggs. 2003. “The Effects of Information on Producer and Consumer Incentives to Undertake Food Safety Efforts: A Theoretical Model and Policy Implications.” Agribusiness 19:29–42.Google Scholar
Elster, J. 1989. The Cement of Society: A Study of Social Order. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Emons, W. 1988. “Warranties, Moral Hazard, and the Lemons Problem.” Journal of Economic Theory 46:16–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evenson, R.E. and W., Huffman. 1993. “The Effects of R&D on Farm Size, Specialization and Productivity.” In Industrial Policy for Agriculture in the Global Economy, S.R., Johnson and S.A., Martin (eds.). Iowa State University Press, Ames, Iowa.Google Scholar
Evenson, R.E. and W., Huffman. 2001. “Structural and Productivity Change in U.S. Agriculture.” Agricultural Economics 24:127–147.Google Scholar
European Commission. 2006. “Allocation of 2005 EU Expenditure by Member State.” DG-Budget. http://ec.europa.eu/budget/documents/revenue_expenditure_en.htm
Fafchamps, M., E., Sadoulet, and A., Janvry. 1993. “Tariff Seeking in a General Equilibrium Framework.” Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 2:167–189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Falck-Zepeda, J.B., G., Traxler and R.G., Nelson. 2000. “Surplus Distribution from the Introduction of a Biotechnology Innovation.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 82:360–369.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fearne, A. 1991. “The CAP Decision-Making Process.” In The Common Agricultural Policy and the World Economy, C., Ritson and D., Harvey (eds.). C.A.B International, Wallingford.Google Scholar
Fernandez, R. and D., Rodrik. 1991. “Resistance to Reform: Status Quo Bias in the Presence of Individual-Specific Uncertainty.” American Economic Review 81: 1146–1155.Google Scholar
Findlay, R. and S., Wellisz. 1982. “Endogenous Tariffs, the Political Economy of Trade Restrictions, and Welfare.” In Import Competition and Response, J., Bhagwati (ed.). University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 223–243.Google Scholar
Fischer, R. and P., Serra. 2000. “Standards and Protection.” Journal of International Economics 52:377–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fishel, W.D. 1971. Resource Allocation in Agricultural Research. University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.Google Scholar
Foster, W.E. and G.C., Rausser. 1993. “Price-distorting Compensation Serving the Consumer and Taxpayer Interest.” Public Choice, 77:275–291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, G. 1985. “Is the United States Really Underinvesting in Agricultural Research?American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67:806–812.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freedman, D.A. 1984. “On Bootstrapping Two-stage Least Squares Estimation in Stationary Linear Models.” The Annals of Statistics 12:827–842.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freedman, D.A. and S.C., Peters. 1983. “Using the Bootstrap to Evaluate Forecasting Equations.” Technical Report, Department of Statistics, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Freedman, D.A. and S.C., Peters. 1984a. “Bootstrapping an Econometric Model: Some Empirical Results”, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 2:150–158.Google Scholar
Freedman, D.A. and S.C., Peters. 1984b. “Bootstrapping a Regression Equation: Some Empirical Results.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 79:97–106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Froelich, N.J., A., Oppenheimer, and J., Young. 1971. Political Leadership and Collective Goods. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
Frye, T. and A., Shleifer. 1997. “The Invisible Hand and the Grabbing Hand.” American Economics Review 87:354–358.Google Scholar
Fulton, M. and K., Giannakas. 2004. “Inserting GM Products into the Food Chain: The Market and Welfare Effects of Different Labeling and Regulatory Regimes.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86:42–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fulton, M. and L., Karp. 1989. “Estimating the Objectives of Public Firm in a Natural Resource Industry.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 16: 268–287.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furtan, W.H. 1983. “Economics of Crop and Oilseed Research in Canada.” Paper presented to the Outlook Conference, Ottawa, Canada.Google Scholar
Galbis, V. 1994. “Sequencing of Financial Sector Reforms: A Review.” Working Paper WP/94/101, International Monetary Fund, New York.Google Scholar
Gardner, B.L. 1983. “Efficient Redistribution through Commodity Markets.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 65:225–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardner, B.L. 1987a. The Economics of Agricultural Policies. Macmillan Publishing Company, New York.Google Scholar
Gardner, B.L. 1987b. “Causes of U.S. Farm Commodity Programs.” Journal of Political Economy 95:290–310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gardner, B.L. 1989. “Price Supports and Optimal Spending on Agricultural Research.” Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Working Paper, University of Maryland, April.Google Scholar
Gastil, R. 1987. Freedom in the World. Greenwood, Westport, CT.Google Scholar
Gates, S., P., Milgrom, and J., Roberts. 1993. “Complementarities in the Transition from Socialism: A Firm-Level Analysis.”Unpublished manuscript, Stanford University, Palo Alto, CA.Google Scholar
Gawande, K. and P., Krishna. 2003. “The Political Economy of Trade Policy: Empirical Approaches.” In Handbook of International Trade, E. K., Choi and J., Harrigan (eds.). Blackwell Publishing, Oxford, 213–250.Google Scholar
Geertz, C. 1973. “Ideology as a Cultural System.” In The Interpretation of Cultures, C., Geertz (ed.), Basic Books, New York, Chapter 9.Google Scholar
Goldberg, P.K. and N., Pacvnic. 2003. “The Response of the Informal Sector to Trade Liberalization.” Journal of Development Economics 72:463–496.Google Scholar
Gray, J. 1989. “Hayek on the Market Economy and the Limits of State Action.” In The Economic Borders of the State, D., Helm (ed.). Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M., and E., Helpman. 1994. “Protection for Sale.” American Economic Review 84: 833–850.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M., and E., Helpman. 1995.“Trade Wars and Trade TalksJournal of Political Economy 103:675–708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G.M., and E., Helpman. 2001. Special Interest Politics. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and E., Helpman. 2002. Interest Groups and Trade Policy. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and E., Helpman. 2005a. “A Protectionist Bias in Majoritarian Politics.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 120:1239–1282.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, G.M. and E., Helpman. 2005b. “Party Discipline and Pork Barrel Politics.” NBER Working Paper No. W11396.
Gutman, J.M. 1978. “Interest Groups and the Demand for Agricultural Research.” Journal of Political Economy 86:467–484.Google Scholar
Hadwiger, D.F. 1981. The Politics of Agricultural Research. University of Nebraska Press, Lincoln, Nebraska.Google Scholar
Hall, B.H., C., Cummins, and R., Schnake. 1995. Time Series Processor Version 4.3, TSP International, Palo Alto, CA.Google Scholar
Hansen, L.P. 1982. “Large Sample Properties of Generalized Method of Moments Estimation.” Econometrica 50:1029–1054.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harberger, A.C. 1964. “The Measurement of Waste.” American Economic Review 74: 58–76.Google Scholar
Hardin, R. 1982. Collective Action. The John Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future, Baltimore, MD.Google Scholar
Hare, P., and T., Revesz. 1992. “Hungary's Transition to a Market Economy: The Case Against a ‘Big-Bang.’Economic Policy 14:227–264.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J.C. 1956. “Approaches to the Bargaining Problem Before and After the Theory of Games.” Econometrica 24:144–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J.C. 1962a. “Measurement of Social Power, Opportunity Cost, and the Theory of Two-Person Bargaining Game.” Behavioral Science 7:67–80.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, J.C. 1962b. “Measurement of Social Power in n-Person Reciprocal Power Situations.” Behavioral Science 7:81–91.
Harsanyi, J.C. 1963. “A Simplified Bargaining Model for n-Person Cooperative Game.” International Economic Review 4:194–220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, J.C. 1977. Rational Behavior and Bargaining Equilibrium in Games and Social Situations. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harvey, D. 1982. “National Interests and the CAP.” Food Policy 7:174–190.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, D.M. and M.S., McPherson. 1993. “Taking Ethics Seriously: Economics and Contemporary Moral Philosophy.” Journal of Economic Literature 31:671–731.Google Scholar
Hayami, Y. and V.W., Ruttan. 1985. Agricultural Development: An International Perspective. John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.Google Scholar
Hayami, Y., A.R. Ma, Quisumbing, and L.S., Adriano. 1990. Towards an Alternative Land Reform Paradigm. Ateneo de Manila University Press, Manilla.Google Scholar
Hayek, F.A. 1960. The Constitution of Liberty. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Heckscher, E. 1949. “The Effects of Foreign Trade on the Distribution of Income.” In Readings in the Theory of International Trade, H.S., Ellis and L.A., Metzler (eds.). Blackston Press, Philadelphia.Google Scholar
Hellman, J.S. 1998. “Winners Take All: The Politics of Partial Reforms in Postcommunist Transitions.” World Politics, 50:203–234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henning, C. 2004. “The Role of Institutions in Agricultural Protection.” In The Role of Institutions in Rural Policies and Agricultural Markets, G., Van Huylenbroeck, W., Verbeke, and L., Lauwers (eds.). Elsevier B.V., Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Henning, C. and U., Latacz-Lohmann. 2004. “Will Enlargement Gridlock CAP Reforms? A Political Economy Perspective.” EuroChoices 3:38–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hertel, T.W. 1989. “Technology and Factor Mobility.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71:559–573.Google Scholar
Hertel, T.W., V.E., Ball, K.S., Huang, and M.E., Tsigas. 1989. “Farm Level Demand Elasticities for Agricultural Commodities.” Research Bulletin # 988, Agricultural Experiment Station, Purdue University, West Lafayette, Indiana.Google Scholar
Hertford, R. and A., Schmitz. 1977. “Measuring Economic Returns to Agricultural Reserch.” In Resource Allocation and Productivity in National and International Agricultural Research, T.M., Arndt, D.G., Dalrymple, and V.W., Ruttan (eds.), University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis, 148–167.Google Scholar
Hillman, A.L. 1982. “Declining Industries and Political-Support Protectionist Motives.” American Economic Review 72:1180–1187.Google Scholar
Hillman, A.L. 1989. The Political Economy of Protection. Harwood Academic Publishers, New York.Google Scholar
Hillman, A.L. and J.G., Riley. 1989. “Politically Contestable Rents and Transfers.” Economics and Politics 1:17–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, J. 1991. “The Paradox of Power.” Economics and Politics 3:177–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopkins, R., A., Powell, A., Roy, and C.L., Gilbert. 2000. “The World Bank, Conditionality and the Comprehensive Development Framework.” In The World Bank: Structure and Policies, C.L., Gilbert, and D., Vines, (eds.). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 282–298.Google Scholar
Hosli, M. 1996. “Coalitions and Power: Effects of Qualified Majority Voting in the Council of the European Union.” Journal of Common Market Studies 34:255–273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huffman, W.E. and J.A., Miranowski. 1981. “An Economic Analysis of Research Expenditures on Agricultural Experiment Station Research.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 63:104–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huffman, W.E. and R.E., Evenson. 1992. “Contributions of Public and Private Science and Technology to U.S. Agriculturalm Productivity.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics. 74:751–756.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huffman, W.E. and R.E., Evenson. 1994. “The Development of US Agricultural Research and Education: An Economic Perspective.” Iowa State University Department of Economics, Ames, IA.Google Scholar
Huffman, W.E. and R.E., Evenson. 2006. Science for Agriculture: A Long-Term Perspective. (2nd edition) Blackwell Publishing, Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Institute of Farm Income Research. 1971. The Profitability of Dairy Farming and Cost of Fodder Crops in Israel in 1969–70. Institute of Farm Income Research Series D, No. 6, Tel Aviv, Israel.
Intriligator, M.D. 1971. Mathematical Optimization and Economic Theory. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.Google Scholar
Israel Central Bureau of Statistics. 1973. Statistical Abstracts of Israel, 1972. Government of Israel, Jerusalem.
Jeanneret, M. and T., Verdier. 1996. “Standardization and Protection in a Vertical Differentiation Model.” European Journal of Political Economy 12:253–271.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jessop, B. 1977. “Recent Theories of the Capitalist State.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 1:353–373.Google Scholar
Johnson, D.G. 1973. World Agriculture in Disarray. Macmillan St. Martin's Press, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, D.G. 1991. World Agriculture in Disarray, 2nd edition. Macmillan, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Johnson, D.G. and K.M., Brooks (eds.). 1983. Prospects for Soviet Agriculture in the 1980s. Indiana University Press, Bloomington.
Jones, R.W. 1970. “Effective Protection and Substitution.” Journal of International Economics 1:59–82.Google Scholar
Jones, R.W. 1975. “Income Distribution and Effective Protection in a Multicommodity Trade Model.” Journal of Economic Theory 11:1–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Josling, T. and H.W., Moyer. 1991. “The Common Agricultural Policy of the European Community: A Public Choice Interpretation.” In The Political Economy of International Organizations. A Public Choice Approach, R., Vaubel and T.D., Willet (eds.). Westview Press, Boulder.Google Scholar
Judd, K.L. 1987. “The Welfare Cost of Factor Taxation in a Perfect-Foresight Model.” Journal of Political Economy 95:675–709.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, M.A., J.K., Boyce, and R.E., Evenson. 1983. “Investing in Agricultural Supply.” Discussion Paper No. 442, Economic Growth Center, Yale University, New Haven.Google Scholar
Just, R.E. 1981. Farmer-Owned Grain Reserve Program Needs Modi?cation to Improve Effectiveness: Theoretical and Empirical Considerations in Agricultural Buffer Stock Policy Under the Food and Agriculture Act of 1977. CED–81.70, Volume 3, June, U.S. General Accounting Office, Washington.Google Scholar
Just, R.E. and G.C., Rausser. 1984. “Uncertain Economic Environments and Conditional Policies.” In Alternative Agricultural and Food Policies and the 1985 Farm Bill, G.C., Rausser and K. R., Farrell (eds.). Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Just, R.E., D.L., Hueth, and A., Schmitz. 1982. Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy, Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.Google Scholar
Just, R.E., D.L., Hueth, and A., Schmitz. 2008. Applied Welfare Economics. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kalt, J.P. and M.R., Zupan. 1984. “Capture and Ideology in the Economic Theory of Politics.” American Economic Review 74:279–300.Google Scholar
Karp, L. and J., Perloff. 2002.“A Synthesis of Agricultural Trade Economics.” In Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume 2, B., Gardner and G.C., Rausser (eds.). Elsevier North Holland, Amsterdam, Chapter 37.Google Scholar
Katranidis, S. and A., Vakrou. 2002. “Member States Positions and Voting Coalitions on the Agenda 2000 CAP Reform.” Cahiers d'Economie and Sociologie Rurales 63:5–30.Google Scholar
Kau, J.B. and P., Rubin. 1979. “Self Interest, Ideology and Log-Rolling.” Journal of Law and Economics 22:365–384.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keefer, P. and S., Khemani. 2005.“Democracy, Public Expenditures, and the Poor: Understanding Political Incentives for Providing Public Services.” World Bank Research Observer 20:1–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khanna, J., W.E., Huffman and T., Sandler. 1994. “Agricultural Research Expenditures in the United States: A Public Goods Perspective.” Review of Economics and Statistics 76:267–277.Google Scholar
Kirschke, D. 1983. “Maximizing Welfare in Customs Unions: The Case of Agricultural Price Policy within the EEC.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 65: 791–795.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kletzer, L.G. 2004. “Trade-Related Job Loss and Wage Insurance: A Synthetic Review.” Review of International Economics 12:724–748.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koester, U. 1977. “The Redistributional Effects of the Common Agricultural Financial System.” European Review of Agricultural Economics 4:321–345.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koisch, Y. and J., Zukerman. 1968. Survey of the Dairy Processing Sector. Israel Institute of Labor Productivity, Tel Aviv, Israel.Google Scholar
Konings, J. and H., Vandenbussche. 2005. “Antidumping Protection and Markups of Domestic Firms: Evidence from Firm Level Data.” Journal of International Economics 65:151–165.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konings, J. and H., Vandenbussche. 2008. “Heterogeneous Responses to Trade Protection.” Journal of International Economics 76:371–383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kornai, J. 1990. The Road to a Free Economy, Shifting from a Socialist System: The Example of Hungary. W.W. Norton and Company, New York.Google Scholar
Kornblut, A.E. and M.D., Shear. 2007 “‘Architect’ Envisioned GOP Supremacy.” Washington Post, August 14, Page A1.
Krishna, V. and R., Serrano. 1995. “Multilateral Bargaining.” Review of Economic Studies 63:61–80.Google Scholar
Krueger, A.O. 1974. “The Political Economy of the Rent Seeking Society.” American Economic Review 64:291–303.Google Scholar
Krueger, A.O. 1993.“Virtuous and Vicious Circles in Economic Development.” American Economic Review 83:351–355.Google Scholar
Krueger, A.O., M., Schiff, and A., Valdes. 1988. “Agricultural Incentives in Developing Countries.” World Bank Economic Review 2:255–272.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kruse, D.L. 1988. “International Trade and the Labor Market Experience of Displaced Workers.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 41:402–417.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laffont, J.J. and J., Tirole. 1991. “The Politics of Government Decision Making: A Theory of Regulatory Capture.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106:1089–1127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lakatos, I. 1970. “Falsification and Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes.” In Criticism and Growth of Knowledge, I., Lakatos and A., Musgrave (eds.). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lapan, H.E. and G., Moschini. 2007. “Grading, Minimum Quality Standards, and the Labeling of Genetically Modified Products.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 89:769–783.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laver, M. and K.A., Shepsle. 1990. “Coalitions and Cabinet Governments.” American Political Science Review 84:873–890.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, D.R. and G., Rausser. 1992. “The Structure of Research and Transfer Policies in International Agriculture.” In Issues in Agricultural Development, Sustainability and Cooperation, Margot, Bellamy and Bruce, Greenshields (eds.). International Association of Agricultural Economists Occasional Paper 6:34–42.Google Scholar
Lee, D.R. and P.G., Helmberger. 1985. “Estimating Supply Response in the Presence of Farm Programs.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 676:191–203.Google Scholar
Lee, H.Y. 1991. From Revolutionary Cadres to Party Technocrats in Socialist China. University of California Press, Berkeley, CA.Google Scholar
Leland, H.E. 1979. “Quacks, Lemons, and Licensing: A Theory of Minimum Quality Standards.” Journal of Political Economy 87:1328–1346.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, D.D. 1998. “Changing Incentives of the Chinese Bureaucracy.” American Economic Review 88:393–397.Google Scholar
Lichtenberg, E. and D., Zilberman. 1986. “The Welfare Economics of Price Supports in U.S. Agriculture.” American Economic Review 76:1135–4111.Google Scholar
Lin, J.Y. 1992. “Rural Reforms and Agricultural Growth in China.” American Economic Review 82:34–51.Google Scholar
Lindner, R.K. and F.G., Jarrett. 1978. “Supply Shifts and the Size of Research Benefits.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 69:48–58.Google Scholar
Lipsey, R.G. and K., Lancaster. 1957. “The General Theory of ‘Second Best’.” Review of Economic Studies 24:11–32.Google Scholar
Lipton, D. and J., Sachs. 1990. “Creating a Market Economy in Eastern Europe: The Case of Poland.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 75–147.
Lizzeri, A. and N., Persico. 2001. “The Provision of Public Goods under Alternative Electoral Incentives.” The American Economic Review 91:225–239.Google Scholar
Lizzeri, A. and N., Persico. 2004.“Why Did the Elites Extend the Suffrage? Democracy and the Scope of Government, with an Application to Britain's ‘Age of Reform’.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 119:707–765.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lockwood, B. 2002. “Distributive Politics and the Cost of Centralization.” Review of Economic Studies 69:313–337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Love, H.A. and E., Muriningtyas. 1992. “Measuring the Degree of Market Power Exerted by Government Trade Agencies.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74: 546–555.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Love, H.A., G.C., Rausser, and D.M., Burton. 1990. “Policy Preference Functions: Grand Themes and New Directions.” Working Paper No. 571, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Love, H.A., G.C., Rausser, and J., Freebairn. 1974. “The Effectiveness of Government Policy in Controlling Agricultural Output.” Paper presented at the American Economic Association Meeting, Cornell University.Google Scholar
Lyons, R.F., G.C., Rausser, and L.K., Simon. 1994.“Disruption and Continuity in Bulgaria's Agrarian Reform.” In Privatization of Agriculture in New Market Economies: Lessons from Bulgaria, A., Buckwell, S., Davidova, K., Mounton, and A., Schmitz (eds.). Kluwer Academic Publishers, Norwell, MA.Google Scholar
Luce, D.R. and H., Raiffa. 1957. Games and Decisio Coricelli ns. Wiley, New York.Google Scholar
Lueck, T. J. 1989. “The Bulk-for-Benefits Deal in Zoning.” New York Times, July 12, sec. 10, p. 1.
Maclennan, A. 1982. “A General Noncooperative Theory of Bargaining.” Unpublished, manuscript, University of Toronto.Google Scholar
Macours, K. and J., Swinnen. 2002. “Patterns of Agrarian Transition.” Economic Development and Cultural Change 50:365–394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madison, J. 1898. Federalist Paper No. 10. In The Federalist and Other Constitutional Papers, E.H., Scott (ed.). Scott, Forsman, Chicago.Google Scholar
Maertens, M. and J., Swinnen. 2009. “Trade, Standards and Poverty: Evidence from Senegal.” World Development 37:161–178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maertens, M. and J., Swinnen. 2010. “Standards, Trade and Developing Countries.” In Trade Adjustment Costs in Developing Countries: Impact, Determinants and Policy Responses, Porto, G. and B.M., Hoekman (eds.). World Bank Publications, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Magee, C. 2001. “Administered Protection for Workers: Analysis of the Trade Adjustment Assistance Program.” Journal of International Economics 53:105–125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Magee, S.P., W.A., Brock and L., Young. 1989. Black Hole Tariffs and Endogenous Policy Theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Mahé, L.M. and T.L., Roe. 1996. “The Political Economy of Reforming the 1992 CAP Reform.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78:1314–1323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marette, S. and J.C., Beghin. 2010. “Are Standards Always Protectionist?Review of International Economics 18:179–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, W. 1984. “Endogenous Tariff Formation.” American Economic Review 74: 970–985.Google Scholar
Mayer, W. and R., Riezman. 1987. Endogenous Choice of Trade Policy Instruments. Journal of International Economics 23:337–381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayer, W., and R., Riezman. 1989. “Tariff Formation in a Multidimensional Voting Model.” Economics and Politics 1:61–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCubbins, M.D., R.G., Noll, and B.R., Weingast. 1989. “Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies.” Virginia Law Review 75:431–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMillan, J. 2002. Reinventing the Bazaar. The Natural History of Markets. W. W. Norton & Company, New York.Google Scholar
McMillan, J. and B., Naughton. 1992. “How to Reform a Planned Economy: Lessons from China.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 8:130–143.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McMillan, J., G.C., Rausser, and S.R., Johnson. 1993. “Freedoms and Economic Growth: Transitional and Permanent Components.” WP 93-WP 115, CARD, Iowa State University.Google Scholar
Meade, J.E. 1955. Trade and Welfare. Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Milesi-Ferretti, G.M., R., Perotti, and M., Rostagno. 2002. “Electoral Systems and Public Spending.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117:609–657.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mishan, E.J. 1976. Cost-Bene??t Analysis. Prager Publishers, New York.Google Scholar
Mitchell, D.J.B. 1989. Human Resource Management: An Economic Approach. PWS-Kent Publishing Co., Boston.Google Scholar
Mitra, D. 1999.“Endogenous Lobby Formation and Endogenous Protection: A Long-run Model of Trade Policy Determination.” American Economic Review 89:1116–1134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, T.M. 1980. The Organization of Interests. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Moravcsik, A. 1994. “Preferences and Power in the European Community: A Liberal Intergovernmentalist Approach.” In Economic and Political Integration in Europe: Internal Dynamics and Global Context, S., Bulmer and A., Scott (eds.). Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Moschini, G., L., Menapace, and D., Pick. 2008. “Geographical Indications and the Competitive Provision of Quality in Agricultural Markets.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 90:794–812.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moulin, H. 1982. “Bargaining and Noncooperative Implementation.” Unpublished, manuscript, Ecole Polytechnique, Paris.Google Scholar
Moyer, H.W. and T.E., Josling. 1990. Agricultural Policy Reform: Politics and Process in the EC and the USA. Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York.Google Scholar
Mueller, D.C. 2003. Public Choice III. Cambridge University Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mundlak, Y. 1978. “On the Pooling of Time Series and Cross Section Data.” Econometrica 46:69–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, J.A., W.H., Furtan, and A., Schmitz. 1993.“The Gains from Agricultural Research under Distorted Trade.” Journal of Public Economics, 51:161–172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murphy, K., A., Shleifer, and R., Vishny. 1992. “The Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107:8989–906.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Murrell, P. 1993. “What is Shock Therapy? What Did it Do in Poland and Russia?Post-Soviet Affairs 9:111–140.Google Scholar
Mussa, M. 1982. “Imperfect Factor Mobility and the Distribution of Income.” Journal of International Economics 12:125–141.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mussa, M. and S., Rosen. 1978. “Monopoly and Product Quality.” Journal of Economic Theory 18:301–317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nagel, J.H. 1968. “Some Questions About the Concept of Power.” Behavioral Science 13:129–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J.F. 1950. “The Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 18:155–162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J.F. 1951. “Non-cooperative Games.” Annals of Mathematics 54:286–295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, J.F. 1953. “Two-Person Cooperative Games.” Econometrica 21:128–140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neville-Rolfe, E. 1984. The Politics of Agriculture in the European Community. European Centre for Policy Studies, London.Google Scholar
Newbery, D. 1993. “Transformation in Mature Versus Emerging Economies: Why Has Hungary Been Less Successful than China?China Economic Review 4:89–116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nitzan, S. and J., Paroush. 1985. Collective Decision Making: An Economic Outlook. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
North, D.C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. W. W. Norton and Co, New York.Google Scholar
North, D.C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge University Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D.C. 1991. “Institutions, Transaction Costs, and the Rise of Merchant Empires.” In The Political Economy of Merchant Empires, James D., Tracy (ed.), Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Nugent, N. 2003. The Government and Politics of the European Union. Palgrave, Basingstoke.Google Scholar
Núñez-Ferrer, J. 2001. “The Council of the EU and the Common Agricultural Policy.” PhD Thesis, University of London.
Nyberg, A. and S., Rozelle. 1999. Accelerating Development in Rural China. World Bank Monograph, Series, Rural Development Division. The World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Nykamp, P. and W.H., Somermeyer. 1971. “Explicating Implicit Social Preference Functions.” Economics of Planning 11:101–119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O'Conner, J. 1973. The Fiscal Crisis of the State. St. Martin's Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oehmke, J.F. 1988. “The Calculation of Returns to Research in Distorted Markets.” Agricultural Economics 2:291–302.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olper, A. 1998. “Political Economy Determinants of Agricultural Protection in EU Member States: An Empirical Investigation.” European Review of Agricultural Economics 24:463–487.Google Scholar
Olper, A. 2007. “Land Inequality, Government Ideology, and Agricultural Protection.” Food Policy 32:67–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olper, A. and J., Swinnen. 2009. “Mass Media e Politiche Agroalimentari: Alcune Recenti Evidenze Empiriche.” Agriregionieuropa 19.Google Scholar
Olson, M. Jr., 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Olson, M. Jr., 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities. Yale University Press, New Haven.Google Scholar
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 1987. National Policies and Agricultural Trade, Country Study Japan. OECD.
O'Rourke, K.H. and A.M., Taylor. 2006. “Democracy and Protectionism.” NBER Working Paper No. 12250.
Ostrom, E. 1986. “An Agenda for the Study of Institutions.” Public Choice 48:3–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Otsuka, K., H., Chuma, and Y., Hayami. 1992. “Land and Labor Contracts in Agrarian Economies: Theories and Facts.” Journal of Economic Literature 30:1965–2018.Google Scholar
Pappi, F.U. and C., Henning. 1999. “The Organization of Influence on the EC's Common Agricultural Policy: A Network Approach.” European Journal of Political Research 36:257–281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pardey, P.G. and B., Craig. 1989.“Causal Relationships between Public Sector Agricultural Research Expenditures and Output.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71: 9–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pardey, P.G. and J., Roseboom. 1989. ISNAR Agricultural Research Indicator Series: A Global Data Base on National Agricultural Research Systems. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Pardey, P.G., M.S., Kang, and H., Elliott. 1989. “Structure of Public Support for National Agricultural Research: A Political Economy Perspective.” Agricultural Economics 3:261–278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Paul, G.S. and T., Verdier. 1997. “Power, Distributive Conflicts and Multiple Growth Paths.” Journal of Economic Growth 2:155–168.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pearce, J. 1983. “The Common Agricultural Policy: The Accumulation of Special Interests.” In Policy Making in the European Union, H., Wallace, W., Wallace and C., Webb (eds.). Wiley, Chichester.Google Scholar
Pell, J. and I., Van Staveren, (eds.). 2009. Handbook of Economics and Ethics. Edward Elgar, Northampton, MA.CrossRef
Peltzman, S. 1976. “Toward a More General Theory of Regulation.” Journal of Law and Economics 19:211–240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, T. and G., Tabellini. 2000. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Persson, T. and G., Tabellini. 2003. The Economic Effects of Constitutions. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Persson, T., G., Roland, and G., Tabellini. 2000. “Comparative Politics and Public Finance.” Journal of Political Economy 108:1121–1161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, H. and P., Wakker. 1991. “Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives and Revealed Group Preferences.” Econometrica 59:1787–1801.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, S.C. and D.A., Freedman. 1984. “Some Notes on the Bootstrap in Regression Problems.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 2: 406–409.Google Scholar
Pirzio-Biroli, J. 2008. “An Inside Perspective on the Fischler Reforms.” In The Perfect Storm: The Political Economy of the Fischler Reforms of the Common Agricultural Policy, J., Swinnen (ed.). Centre for European Policy Studies Publications, Brussels.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.P. 2000. Institutions, Social Norms, and Economic Development. Harwood Academic, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Pokrivcak, J. 1997. “The Politics of Price Determination in the EU's CAP and the “Restaurant Table” Effect: Implications for East European Accession.” M.S. Thesis, Department of Agricultural, Resource and Managerial Economics, Cornell University.
Pokrivcak, J., H., Gorter, and J., Swinnen. 2001. “Does a “Restaurant Table Effect” Exist with the EU's Common Agricultural Policy?: A Note.” Journal of Agricultural Economics 52:28–30.Google Scholar
Prendergast, C. 2007. “The Motivation and Bias of Bureaucrats.” American Economic Review 97:180–196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Przeworski, A. and F., Limongi. 1993. “Political Regimes and Economic Growth.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 7:51–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Putterman, L. 1993. Continuity and Change in China's Rural Development. Oxford University Press, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qian, Y. and C., Xu. 1993. “Why China's Economic Reforms Differ: The M-form Hierarchy and Entry/Expansion of the Non-State Sector.” Economics of Transition 1:135–170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Qian, Y., G., Roland, and C., Xu. 1999. “Why is China Different from Eastern Europe? Perspectives from Organization Theory.” European Economic Review 43:1085–1094.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C. 1982. “Political Economic Markets: PERTs and PESTs in Food and Agriculture.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64:821–833.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C. 1992. “Predatory Versus Productive Governments: The Case of U.S. Agricultural Policy.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 6:133–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C. 1995. GATT Negotiations and the Political Economy of Policy Reform. Springer-Verlag, Berlin.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and E., Hochman. 1979. Dynamic Agricultural Systems: Economic Prediction and Control. Elsevier North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and G., Roland. 2010. “Special Interests Versus the Public Interest: The Determination of Policy Instruments.” In Political Economy of Distortions to Agricultural Incentives, K., Anderson (ed.), World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and H., Gorter. 1990. “Endogenizing Policy in Models of Agricultural Markets.” In Agriculture and Governments in an Interdependent World, A., Maunder (ed.). Gower, Aldershot.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and J.W., Freebairn. 1974. “Estimation of Policy Preference Functions: An Application to U.S. Beef Import Policy.” Review of Economics and Statistics 56: 437–449.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and L.K., Simon. 1992a. “The Political Economy of Alliances: Structure and Performance.” Working Paper No. 665, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and L.K., Simon. 1992b. “The Political Economy of Transition in Eastern Europe: Packaging Enterprises for Privatization.” In The Emergence of Market Economies, C., Clague and G.C., Rausser (eds.). Blackwell Publishers, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and L.K., Simon. 1999. “A Noncooperative Model of Collective Decision Making: A Multilateral Bargaining Approach.” Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics Working Paper No. 620, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and P., Zusman. 1991. “Organizational Failure and the Political Economy of Water Resource Management.” In The Economics and Management of Water and Drainage in Agriculture, A., Dinar and D., Zilberman, (eds.). Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston, 735–758.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and P., Zusman. 1992. “Public Policy: Explanation and Constitutional Prescription.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 74:247–257.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and R.E., Goodhue. 2002. “Public Policy: Its Many Analytical Dimensions”. in Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume 2, B., Gardner and G.C., Rausser (eds.). Elsevier North Holland, Amsterdam, Chapter 39.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and R., Stevens. 2009. “Public-Private Partnerships: Goods and the Structure of Contracts.” Annual Review of Resource Economics 1, forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C. and W.E., Foster. 1990. “Political Preference Functions and Public Policy Reform.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 72:642–652.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G.C., E., Litchtenberg, and R., Lattimore. 1982. “Developments in Theory and Empirical Applications of Endogenous Governmental Behavior.” In New Directions in Econometric Modeling and Forecasting in U.S. Agriculture, G.C., Rausser (ed.). New York: Elsevier North-Holland, Inc., New, York, 547–614.Google Scholar
Rausser, G.C., J.A., Chalfant, H.A., Love, and K.G., Stamoulis. 1986. “Macroeconomic Linkages, Taxes, and Subsidies in the U.S. Agricultural Sector.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 68:399–412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rausser, G. C., L.K., Simon, and K. van't, Veld. 1994. “Political Economic Processes and Collective Decision Making.” Working Paper No. 718, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. 1973. “Distributive Justice.” In Economic Justice, E.S., Phelps (ed.), Penguin Books, Harmondsworth, England, 319–362.Google Scholar
Ray, P. 1973. “Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives.” Econometrica 41:987–991.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rayner, R.K. 1990. “Bootstrapping ρ Values and Power in the First-order Autoregression: A Monte Carlo Investigation.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 8:251–263.Google Scholar
Richardson, J.D. 1982. “Trade-Adjustment Assistance under the U.S. Trade Act of 1974.” In Import Competition and Adjustment: Theory and Policy, J.N., Bhagwati (ed.). University of Chicago Press, Chicago.Google Scholar
Riethmuller, P. and T.L., Roe. 1998. “Government Intervention in Commodity Markets: The Case of Japanese Rice and Wheat Policy.” Journal of Policy Modeling 8:327–349.Google Scholar
Riker, W.H. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. Yale University Press, New Haven.Google Scholar
Rimland, D. 1968. Economic Analysis of the Israeli Dairy Market and the Milk Marketing Board. M.Sc. thesis, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem.
Robinson, J.A. and T., Verdier. 2003. “The Political Economy of Clientelism.” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3205.
Rodrik, D. 1995. “The Political Economy of Trade Policy.” In Handbook of International Economics, Volume 3, G., Grossman and K., Rogoff (eds.). North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Roe, B. and I., Sheldon. 2007. “Credence Good Labeling: The Efficiency and Distributional Implications of Several Policy Approaches.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 89:1020–1033.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roelfsema, H. 2004. “Political Institutions and Trade Protection.” TC Koopmans Research Institute, Discussion Paper Series 04–06.
Roemer, J.E. 1978. “Neoclassicism, Marxism, and Collective Action.” Journal of Economic Issues 12:147–161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roland, G. 1991. “Political Economy of Sequencing Tactics in the Transition Period.” In Systematic Change and Stabilization in Eastern Europe, L., Casab (ed.). Aldershot, Dartmouth, UK, 47–64.Google Scholar
Roland, G. 1994. “The Role of Political Constraints in Transition Strategies.” Economics of Transition 2:27–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roland, G. 2000. Transition and Economics: Politics, Markets and Firms. MIT Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Ronnen, U. 1981. “Minimum Quality Standards, Fixed Costs, and Competition.” RAND Journal of Economics 22:490–504.Google Scholar
Rose-Ackerman, S. and R.E., Evenson. 1985. “The Political Economy of Agricultural Research and Extension: Grants, Votes, and Reapportionment.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67:1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rozelle, S. 1996. “Gradual Reform and Institutional Development: The Keys to Success of China's Rural Reforms.” In Reforming Asian Socialism: The Growth of Market Institutions, J., McMillan and B., Naughton (eds.). University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, 197–220.Google Scholar
Rozelle, S. and J., Swinnen. 2004. “Success and Failure of Reforms: Insights from Transition Agriculture.” Journal of Economic Literature 42:404–456.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubinstein, A. 1982. “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model.” Econometrica 50: 97–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Runge, C.F. and H. von, Witzke. 1987. “Institutional Change in the Common Agricultural Policy of the European Community.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 69:213–222.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Russell, B. 1938. Power: A Social Analysis. Allen and Unwin, London.Google Scholar
Ruttan, V.W. 1982. Agricultural Research Policy. University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.Google Scholar
Ruttan, V.W. 1983. “Agricultural Research Policy Issues.” Horticultural Science 108: 809–818.Google Scholar
Sachs, J. and W.T., Woo. 1994. “Structural Factors in the Economic Reforms of China, Eastern Europe, and the Former Soviet Union.” Economic Policy 9:101–145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sadoulet, E., R., Murgai, and A., Janvry. 2001. “Access to Land via Land Rental Markets.” In Access to Land, Rural Poverty, and Public Action, A., Janvry, G., Gordillo, J.-P., Platteau, and E., Sadoulet (eds.). Oxford University Press, New York, 197–227.Google Scholar
Salemi, M.K. 1995. “Revealed Preference of the Federal Reserve: Using Inverse-control Theory to Interpret the Policy Equation of aVector Autoregression.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 13:419–433.Google Scholar
Salter, W.E.G. 1960. Productivity and Technological Change, 2nd edition. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Schleich, T. 1999. “Environmental Quality with Endogenous Domestic and Trade Policies.” European Journal of Political Economy 15:53–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitz, A. and D., Seckler. 1970. “Mechanized Agriculture and Social Welfare: The Case of the Tomato Harvester.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 52:569–577.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, T.W. 1953. The Economic Organization of Agriculture. McGraw Hill, New York.Google Scholar
Scully, G. 1988. “The Institutional Framework and Economic Development.” Journal of Political Economics 96:652–662.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A.K. 1970. Collective Choice and Social Welfare. Holden-Day, San Francisco.Google Scholar
Sen, A.K. 1986. “Social Choice Theory.” In Handbook of Mathematical Economics, K.J., Arrow and M.D., Intriligator (eds.). North-Holland, Amsterdam, 1073–1181.Google Scholar
Shleifer, A. 1997. “Government in Transition.” European Economic Review 41: 385–410.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, H. 1956. “Dynamic Programming under Uncertainty with a Quadratic Criterion Function.” Econometrica 24:74–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, M. 1976. “Product Differentiation and Welfare.” American Economic Review 66:407–414.Google Scholar
Stahl, I. 1972. Bargaining Theory. Stockholm School of Economics, Stockholm, Sweden.Google Scholar
Stahl, I. 1977. “An n-Person Bargaining Game in the Extensive Form.” In Mathematical Economics and Game Theory, R., Henn and O., Moeschlin (eds.). Springer-Verlag, Berlin.Google Scholar
Staiger, R.W. and G., Tabellini. 1987. “Discretionary Trade Policy and Excessive Protection.” American Economic Review 77:823–837.Google Scholar
Steiner, Peter O. 1969. “The Public Sector and the Public Interest.” In The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditures: The PPB System, Vol 1. Joint Economic Committee Print, U.S. Government Printing Office Washington, D.C., 13–46.Google Scholar
Steunenberg, B. 1994. “Decision Making Under Different Institutional Arrangements: Legislation by the European Community.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 150:642–669.Google Scholar
Stigler, G.J. 1971. “The Theory of Economic Regulation.” Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2:3–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stopler, W.F. and P.A., Samuelson. 1941. “Protection and Real Wages.” Review of Economic Studies 9:58–73.Google Scholar
Straffin, P.D. 1988. “The Shapley-Shubik and Banzhaf Power Indices as Probabilities.” In The Shapley Value: Essays in Honor of Lloyd S. Shapley, A. E., Roth (ed.). Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Sturm, D.M. 2006. “Product Standards, Trade Disputes, and Protectionism.” Canadian Journal of Economics 39:564–581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, Robert. 1986. The Economics of Rights, Co-operation, and Welfare. Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Summers, R. and A., Heston. 1991. “The Penn World Table (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of International Comresearchsons, 1950–1988.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106:327–368.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sumner, D.A. and S., Tangermann. 2002. “International Trade Policy and Negotiations.” In Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume 2, B., Gardner and G.C., Rausser (eds.). Elsevier North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Sunding, D. and D., Zilberman. 2001. “The Agricultural Innovation Process: Research and Technology Adoption in a Changing Agricultural Sector.” In Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume 1, B., Gardner and G.C., Rausser (eds.). Elsevier North Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Sutton, J. 1986. “Non-cooperative Bargaining Theory: An Introduction.” Review of Economic Studies 53:709–724.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. 1994a. “A Positive Theory of Agricultural Protection.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 76:1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. 1994b. “Political Economy of Policy Reform in Bulgarian Agriculture.” In Privatization of Agriculture in New Market Economies: Lessons from Bulgaria, A., Buckwell, S., Davidova, K., Moulton, and A., Schmitz (eds.). Kluwer Academic Publishers, Norwell, MA.Google Scholar
Swinnen, J. 1997. “Does Compensation for Disruptions Stimulate Reforms? The Case of Agricultural Reform in Central Europe.” European Review of Agricultural Economics 24:249–266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. (ed.). 1997. The Political Economy of Agrarian Reform in Central and Eastern Europe. Ashgate: Aldershot.
Swinnen, J. 1999. “The Political Economy of Land Reform Choices in Central and Eastern Europe.” The Economics of Transition 7:637–664.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. 2001. “Will Enlargement Cause a Flood of Eastern Food Imports, Bankrupt the EU Budget, and Create WTO Conflicts?EuroChoices 1:48–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. 2002a. “Transition and Integration in Europe: Implications for Agricultural and Food Markets, Policy and Trade Agreements.” The World Economy 25:481–501.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. 2002b. Political Reforms, Rural Crises, and Land Tenure in Western Europe. Food Policy 27:371–394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. 2008a. The Political Economy of the Agricultural Policy Distortions in Europe in the 19th and 20th Century, paper prepared for the World Bank.
Swinnen, J. (ed.) 2008b. “The Political Economy of the Fischler Reforms of the Common Agricultural Policy.” Center for European Policy Studies.
Swinnen, J. and H., Gorter. 1993. “Why Small Groups and Low Income Sectors Obtain Subsidies: The ‘Altruistic’ Side of a ‘Self-Interested’ Government.” Economics and Politics 4:285–293.Google Scholar
Swinnen, J. and H., Gorter. 1998. “Endogenous Commodity and the Social Benefits from Public Research Expenditures.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 80:107–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. and H., Gorter. 2002. “On Government Credibility, Compensation, and Under-Investment in Public Research.” European Review of Agricultural Economics 29:501–522.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. and S., Rozelle. 2006. From Marx and Mao to the Market: The Economics and Politics of Agricultural Transition. Oxford University Press, Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J. and T., Vandemoortele. 2009. “Are Food Safety Standards Different from Other Food Standards? A Political Economy Perspective.” European Review of Agricultural Economics 36:507–523.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J., H., Gorter and A., Banerjee. 2001. “Agricultural Protection and Economic Development: An Econometric Study of the Determinants of Agricultural Protection in Belgium since the 19th Century.” Agricultural Economics 26:25–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J., H., Gorter, G., Rausser, and A., Banerjee. 2000. “The Political Economy of Public Research Investment and Commodity Policies in Agriculture: An Empirical Study.” Agricultural Economics 22:111–122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swinnen, J.F.M. and T., Vandemoortele. 2010. “On Butterflies and Frankenstein: A Dynamic Theory of Regulation.” Unpublished Manuscript. University of Leuven: LICOS Centre for Institutions and Economics.Google Scholar
Thies, C.G. and S., Porche. 2007. “The Political Economy of Agricultural Protection.” Journal of Politics 69:116–127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tian, H. 2003. “Eco-Labelling Scheme, Environmental Protection, and Protectionism.” Canadian Journal of Economics 36:608–633.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tinbergen, J. 1954. Centralization and Decentralization in Economic Policy. North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Tinbergen, J. 1956. Economic Policy: Principles and Design. North-Holland, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Tirole, J. 1988. The Theory of Industrial Organization. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Tirole, J. 1990.“Privatization and Eastern Europe: Incentives and the Economics of Transition.” Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Tollison, R.D. 1982. “Rent Seeking: A Survey.” Kyklos 35:575–602.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tracy, M. 1984. “Issues of Agricultural Policy in a Historical Framework.” Journal of Agricultural Economics 35:307–318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tracy, M. 1996. Agricultural Policy in the European Union and Other Market Economies. APS-Agricultural Policy Studies, Brussels.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, G. 1994. “The Power of the European Parliament as a Conditional Agenda Setter.” American Political Science Review 88:128–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, G. and G., Garrett. 1996. “Agenda Setting Power, Power Indices, and Decision Making in the European Union.” International Review of Law and Economics 16: 345–361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyers, R. and K., Anderson. 1992. Distortions in World Food Markets. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, for the Trade Policy Research Center.Google Scholar
Tullock, G. 1967. “The Welfare Cost of Tariffs, Monopolies, and Theft.” The Western Economic Journal 5:224–232.Google Scholar
Tweeten, L.G. 1967.“The Demand for U.S. Farm Output.” Food Research Institute Studies 7:343–369.Google Scholar
Tweeten, L.G. 1979. Foundations of Farm Policy. University of Nebraska Press, Lincoln.Google Scholar
U.S. Department of Agriculture. 1986. Food Security Act of 1985: Major Provisions Affecting Commodities. Agriculture Information Bulletin No. 497, January. Economic Research Service, Washington, DC.
U.S. Department of Agriculture. 1988. “Estimates of Producer and Consumer Equivalents: Government Intervention in Agriculture,” Economic Research Service, ATAD Staff Report No. AGES 880127.
U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA). 1995. Agricultural Research and Development: Public and Private Investments Under Alternative Markets and Institutions Economic Research Service, Natural Resources and Environment Division, Staff Paper Number AGES–9517.
Valletti, T.M. 2000. “Minimum Quality Standards under Cournot Competition.” Journal of Regulatory Economics 18:235–245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Varian, H.R. 1992. Microeconomic Analysis, 3rd edition. Norton and Co., New York.Google Scholar
Viner, J. 1950. The Customs Unions Issue. Carnegie Endowment for International, Peace, New York.Google Scholar
von Cramon-Taubadel, S. 1992. “A Critical Assessment of the Political Preference Function.” Agricultural Economics 7:371–394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vranken, L. and J., Swinnen. 2006. “Land Rental Markets in Transition: Theory and Evidence from Hungary.” World Development 34:481–500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wädekin, K-E. 1990. “Determinants and Trends of Reform in Communist Agriculture: a Concluding Essay.” In Communist Agriculture: Farming in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe, K-E, Wädekin (ed.). Routledge, New York, 321–339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallace, H. 1983. “Negotiation, Conflict, and Compromise: The Elusive Pursuit of Common Policies.” In Policy Making in the European Union, H., Wallace, W., Wallace, and C., Webb (eds.). Wiley, Chichester.Google Scholar
Webb, A.M., M., Lopez and R., Penn (eds.). 1990. “Estimates of Producer and Consumer Subsidy Equivalents: Government Intervention in Agriculture: 1982–97.” Statistical Bulletin No. 803, ERS USDA, Washington DC.
Wegren, S.K. (ed.). 1998. Land Reform in the Former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. Routledge, London.CrossRef
Wei, S.J. 1993. “Gradualism versus Big Bang: Speed and Sustainability of Reforms.” Working Paper R93–2. John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University.Google Scholar
Weingast, B.R. and D., Wittman, (eds.). 2006. The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Weingast, B.R., K.A., Shepsle, and C., Johnsen. 1981. “The Political Economy of Benefits and Costs: A Neoclassical Approach to Distributive Politics.” General Political Economy 89:642–664.Google Scholar
Widgren, M. 1994. “Voting Power in the EC Decision Making and the Consequences of Two Different Enlargements.” European Economic Review 38:1153–1170.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O.E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. The Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
Williamson, O.E. 1979. “Transaction Cost Economics: The Governance of Contractual Relations.” Journal of Law and Economics 22:233–260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, O.E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. Free Press, New York.Google Scholar
Williamson, O.E. 1993. “Opportunism and its Critics,” Managerial and Decision Economics 14:97–107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willig, R.D. 1976. “Consumer's Surplus Without Apology.” American Economic Review 66:589–597.Google Scholar
Wilson, J.Q. 1989. Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It. Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
Winkler, G.M. 1998. “Coalition-Sensitive Voting Power in the Council: The Case of Eastern Enlargement.” Journal of Common Market Studies 36:391–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winters, L.A., N., McCulloch, and A., McKay. 2004. “Trade Liberalization and Poverty: The Evidence So Far.” Journal of Economic Literature 42:72–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wohlgenant, M.K. 1989. “Demand for Farm Output in a Complete System of Demand Functions.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 1:241–252.Google Scholar
Wong, C.P.W. (ed.) 1997. Financing Local Government in the People's Republic of China. Oxford University Press (for Asian Development Bank), Hong Kong.
Woo, W.T. 1994. “The Art of Reforming Centrally Planned Economies: Comparing China, Poland, and Russia.” Journal of Comparative Economics 18:276–308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
World Bank. 1986. World Development Report 1986. Oxford University Press, New York, for the World Bank.
World Bank. 2007. World Development Report 2008: Agriculture for Development. The World Bank, Washington, DC.
Wright, B.D. 1985. An Assessment of the United States Farmer-Owned Reserve and Commodity Credit Corporation Storage as Market Stabilization Policies. American Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Yang, D. 1996. Calamity and Reform in China: State, Rural Society, and Institutional Change since the Great Leap Famine. Stanford University Press, Palo Alto, CA.Google Scholar
Zellner, A. and H., Theil. 1962. “Three Stage Least Squares: Simultaneous Estimation of Simultaneous Equations.” Econometrica 30:54–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zerbe, R.O., (ed.). 2007. Research in Law and Economics: A Journal of Policy. Volume 23. Elsevier, New York.
Zeuthen, F. 1930. Problem of Monopoly and Economic Warfare. Routledge & Kagan, London.Google Scholar
Zusman, P. 1976. “The Incorporation and Measurement of Social Power in Economic Models.” International Economic Review 17:447–462.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zusman, P. 1988. Individual Behavior and Social Choice in a Cooperative Settlement. The Hebrew University of Jerusalem Magnes Press, Jerusalem.Google Scholar
Zusman, P. 1992. “Constitutional Selection of Collective Choice Rules in a Cooperative Enterprise.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 17:353–362.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zusman, P. 1993. “Participants' Ethical Attitudes and Organizational Structure and Performance: Application to the Cooperative Enterprise.” In Agricultural Cooperatives in Transition, C., Csaki and Yoav, Kislev (eds.). West-View Press, San Francisco, 23–54.Google Scholar
Zusman, P. and A., Amiad. 1977. “A Quantitative Investigation of a Political Economy— The Israeli Dairy Program.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 59: 88–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zusman, P. and C., Bell. 1989. “The Equilibrium Vector of Pairwise-Bargained Agency Contracts with Diverse Actors and Principals Owning a Fixed Resource.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 11:91–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zusman, P. and G.C., Rausser. 1990.“Equilibrium States and Dynamic Behavior of a Political Economy: Application to Water Resource Management.” Working Paper No. 531, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley.Google Scholar
Zusman, P. and G.C., Rausser. 1994. “Intraorganizational Influence Relations and the Optimality of Collective Action.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 24:1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Gordon C. Rausser, University of California, Berkeley, Johan Swinnen, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium, Pinhas Zusman
  • Book: Political Power and Economic Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511978661.026
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Gordon C. Rausser, University of California, Berkeley, Johan Swinnen, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium, Pinhas Zusman
  • Book: Political Power and Economic Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511978661.026
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Gordon C. Rausser, University of California, Berkeley, Johan Swinnen, Katholieke Universiteit Leuven, Belgium, Pinhas Zusman
  • Book: Political Power and Economic Policy
  • Online publication: 05 June 2012
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511978661.026
Available formats
×