Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-zzh7m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-25T18:49:14.993Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Birth of Joint-Stock Banking: England and New England Compared

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 April 2011

Abstract

By the end of the nineteenth century, the banking systems of England and New England were very different. England possessed a small number of large-scale clearing banks that had established extensive branch networks and dominated the domestic market. In contrast, New England banking was characterized by a large number of small-scale institutions. Yet, a century earlier, there were striking similarities between the two systems. An analysis of their evolution over the course of the nineteenth century provides an international and comparative perspective on the continuing debate over banking institutions, lending patterns, and economic growth.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Harvard Business School 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 This study follows a tradition of international comparisons in banking history, notably those of Rondo Cameron. See Cameron, Rondo, Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialisation (Oxford, 1967)Google Scholar; and Cameron, , ed., Banking and Economic Development: Some Lessons from History (Oxford, 1972).Google Scholar

2 Lamoreaux, Naomi, Insider Lending: Banks, Personal Connections and Economic Development in Industrial New England, 1784–1912 (New York, 1994).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

3 The word “proprietaries” is used, rather than “shareholders” or “stockholders,” as these were not modern joint-stock corporations. Shares did not have limited liability, and therefore shareholders, or proprietors, who owned the company were responsible for the financial stability of the institution in which they invested. They were also not distant investors: they were active members of the business community in which the bank was located. Thus, the success of the banks upheld the success of the local economy. They were effectively copartners. The next section on bank shares and shareholders expands on this topic.

4 Cameron, “Scotland,” in Banking in the Early Stages of Industrialisation; Checkland, Sydney G., Scottish Banking: A History, 1695–1973 (Glasgow, 1975)Google Scholar; Munn, Charles W., The Scottish Provincial Banking Companies, 1745–1864 (Edinburgh, 1981).Google Scholar

5 The Bank of England was permitted to establish branches outside London, which serviced other banks, thus limiting their competition with JSBs. Ziegler, Dieter, Central Bank, Peripheral Industry: The Bank of England in the Provinces, 1826–1913 (Leicester, 1990), 67, 8–31.Google Scholar

6 Collins, Michael, Money and Banking in the U.K.: A History (London, 1988), 24.Google Scholar A total of 46 banks out of the 138 established have been analyzed here.

7 The number of private banks fell from 650 in 1825 to 236 by 1875 (with 595 offices and branches), while joint-stock banks numbered 0 in 1825 and rose to 122 by 1875 (with 1,364 offices and branches). Collins, , Money and Banking, 27, 52.Google Scholar

8 The Banking Co-partnerships Act, 1826, 7 Geo. IV, c.46, XIII. See Hickson, Charles R. and Turner, John D., “Shareholder Liability Regimes in English Banking: The Impact upon the Market for Shares,” European Review of Economic History, vol. 7, issue 1 (2003): 99125.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

9 Hickson, Charles R., Turner, John D., and McCann, Claire, “Much Ado about Nothing: The Limitation of Liability and the Market for Nineteenth Century Irish Bank Stock,” Explorations in Economic History 42, no. 3 (2005): 463.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10 See Richard Sylla, “The United States,” 199–262, in Banking and Economic Development, ed. Cameron.

11 Bodenhorn, Howard, Store Banking in Early America: A New Economic History (Oxford, 2003), 73, 78, 85.Google Scholar

12 Bodenhorn, Howard, A History of Banking in Antebellum America: Financial Markets and Economic Development in an Era of Nation-Building (New York, 2000), 12.Google Scholar See also Schweikart, Larry, Banking in the American South from the Age of Jackson to Reconstruction (Baton Rouge, 1987), ch. 5Google Scholar; and Green, George, Finance and Economic Development in the Old South: Louisiana Banking, 1804–1861 (Stanford, 1972), 18.Google Scholar

13 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 4, 12–18.Google Scholar

14 Following the New York Free Bank Act of 1838, the principle of “free banking”-whereby banking was not to be restricted to a privileged few but rather was to be open to all-was largely adopted in the United States. By 1860, over half of the states had enacted some type of free banking law. Rockoff, Hugh, The Free Banking Era: A Reexamination (New York, 1975).Google Scholar

15 See Newton, Lucy A., “Regional Bank-Industry Relations during the Mid-Nineteenth Century: Links between Bankers and Manufacturers, c.1850 to c.1855,” Business History 38, no. 3 (1996): 6483CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 82.Google Scholar

16 Rhode Island banks chartered in the early 1830s were an exception. Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 29.Google Scholar

17 For the variety in legislation in early nineteenth-century New England alone, see Bodenhorn, , State Banking, 8187Google Scholar; and Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 57.Google Scholar

18 Two national banks had been chartered before this date: the First Bank of the United States in 1791, and the Second Bank of the United States in 1816, which ceased in 1836.

19 Bodenhorn, , Sfare Banking, 1218, 250, 270.Google Scholar

20 Temin, Peter, ed., Engines of Enterprise: An Economic History of New England (Cambridge Mass., 2000), chs. 3, 4Google Scholar; Johnson, Arthur M. and Supple, Barry, Boston Capitalists and Western Railroads: A Study in Nineteenth-Century Railroad Investment (Cambridge Mass., 1967).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

21 Mathias, Peter, The First Industrial Nation: The Economic History of Britain, 1700–1914 (London, 2001, 2nd ed.).Google Scholar

22 Newton, Lucy A., The Victorian Economy in Transition: A Regional Perspective (Alder-shot, forthcoming).Google Scholar

23 Sykes, Joseph, The Amalgamation Movement in English Banking, 1825–1924 (London, 1926), 817.Google Scholar

24 For example, HBC Prospectus, H41/18, HSBCGA.

25 Bailey, Cheryl, “The Circular to Bankers,” Bulletin: Newsletter from the European Association of Business Historians (EABH), 1999, no. 2: 2021.Google Scholar

26 For example, Coventry Union Banking Co. [CUBC], Board of Directors minutes [BDM], AB3, HSBCGA.

27 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 1819, 58, 62–63.Google Scholar

28 Coventry & Warwickshire Banking Co. [CWBC], BDM, 24 Oct. 1835, 045, LTSBGA.

29 The influence of specific families on boards of banks was often long lasting. See Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 2325Google Scholar; and Newton, Lucy A., “Change and Continuity: The Development of Joint Stock Banking in the Early Nineteenth Century,” University of Reading discussion paper, 2007.Google Scholar

30 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 34, 77.Google Scholar

31 Wright, Robert E., “Bank Ownership and Lending Patterns in New York and Pennsylvania, 1781–1831,” Business History Review 73 (Spring 1999): 58, 59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

32 For example, see Sheffield Union Bank [SUB], BDM, 12 June 1844, AD2, HSBCGA.

33 See Bradford Banking Company [BradBC], book no. 5, 25 May 1846, B6, HSBCGA.

34 Nottingham & Nottinghamshire Banking Co. [NNBC], BDM, 21 Jan. 1834, 574, RBSGA. The rejection rate of 29 percent was higher than the rate for credit applications (24.3 percent). See also Hickson, Charles R. and Turner, John D., “The Trading of Unlimited Liability Bank Shares: The Bagehot Hypothesis,” Journal of Economic History 63, no. 4 (2003): 940.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

35 For an analysis of investment patterns of Londoners on the London Stock Exchange, see Davies, Lance E. and Huttenback, Robert A., Mammon and the Pursuit of Empire: The Economics of British Imperialism, abridged ed. (New York, 1988), 178–79.Google Scholar

36 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 22.Google Scholar

37 Ibid., 19,71,68.

38 Casson, Mark, “Culture as an Economic Asset,” in Business History and Business Culture, ed. Godley, Andrew C. and Westall, Oliver M. (Manchester, 1996), 68.Google Scholar

39 Ollerenshaw, Philip, “The Development of Banking in the Bristol Region, 1750–1914,” in Studies in the Business History of Bristol, ed. Harvey, Charles E. and Press, Jon (Bristol, 1988), 65.Google Scholar

40 Liverpool Union Banking Co., BDM, 24 Apr. 1835 and 17 Sept. 1835, book no. 093, LTSBGA.

41 CUBC, BDM, 13 May 1836, AB3, HSBCGA.

42 North & South Wales Bank, prospectus, 1836, M166, HSBCGA.

43 CUBC, BDM, 13 May 1836, AB3, HSBCGA.

44 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 72.Google Scholar

45 Sayers, , Lloyds Bank, 109–38Google Scholar; Newton, Lucy A. and Cottrell, Philip L., “Female Investors in the First English and Welsh Commercial Joint-Stock Banks,” Accounting Business and Financial History 16, no. 2 (2006): 331–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

46 Wright, , “Bank Ownership,” 44.Google Scholar

47 BradBC, Prospectus, B42/3, HSBCGA.

48 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 73.Google Scholar

49 Ibid., 74.

50 Wright, , “Bank Ownership,” 52.Google Scholar

51 Dunlavy, Colleen A., “Corporate Democracy: Stockholder Voting Rights in Nineteenth-Century American and Prussian Railroad Corporations,” in Institutions in the Transport and Communications Industries, ed. Andersson-Skog, Lena and Krantz, Olle (Canton, Mass., 1999), 3359Google Scholar; Pearson, “Shareholder Democracies?”; and Newton, Victorian Economy in Transition, ch. 7.

52 Newton, Victorian Economy in Transition, chs. 3, 4.

53 Bill discounting could also act as a source of information about customers and a point of regular contact with them. Nishimura, Shizuya, The Decline of Inland Bills of Exchange in the London Money Market, 1855–1913 (Cambridge, U.K., 1971).Google Scholar

54 Newton, Lucy A., “Trust and Virtue in Banking: The Assessment of Borrowers by Bank Managements at the Turn of the Twentieth Century,” Financial History Review 7, no. 2 (2000): 177–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

55 For example, LUBC, BDM, 23 June 1836, book No. 93, LTSBGA.

56 Ashton, Stalybridge, Hyde and Glossop Banking Co. [ASHGBC], 14 Feb. i860, 10145, RBSGA.

57 LamoTeaux, Insider Lending, 1–3, 19.

58 Ibid., 26, 76.

59 Lending data that corresponded in time to shareholding data were found for twelve of the forty-six banks surveyed. Lending data were sampled, taking three years that corre sponded with shareholding data from the following sources: LTSBGA: Halifax Joint Stock Bank (Securities notebook, 1668), LUBC, BDM, 93; HSBCGA: BBC (BDM, A12 and A16), BradBC (BDM, B2 and B28), HBC (BDM, H4 and H7), CWBC (BDM, 45 and 47), SUBC (BDM, AD2); and RBSGA: ASHGBC (BDM, 10144 and 10145), Bilston District Banking Co. (BDM, 11342), NNBC (BDM, 574), Sheffield & Rotherham Banking Co. (BDM, SR/1/1, 01095S and SR/1/5, 01097S).

60 SUBC, BDM, AD2, HSBCGA.

61 Similar localization of lending occurred in the northeastern United States in the early nineteenth century. More lending occurred outside the area after 1870. See Beveridge, Andrew A., “Local Lending Practice: Borrowers in a Small Northeastern Industrial City, 1832–1915,’ Journal of Economic History 45, no. 2 (1985): 397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

62 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 53.Google Scholar

63 Newton, , “Regional Bank-Industry Relations,” 67, 73–75.Google Scholar

64 The two Sheffield banks are fairly representative, in terms of lending practices, of the industrial regions of England.

65 Under the National Banking Act of 1864, country banks were allowed to hold a fraction of their reserves as deposits with reserve city banks located in New York or other large financial centers. Yet this system was not sensitive to changes in demand for credit. Degen, Robert A., The American Monetary System: A Concise Survey of its Evolution since 1896 (Lexington, Mass., 1987), 18Google Scholar; Klebaner, Benjamin J., American Commercial Banking: A History (Boston, 1990), 9298.Google Scholar

66 Stiglitz, Joseph E. and Weiss, Andrew M., “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information,” American Economic Review 71, no. 3 (1981): 393410Google Scholar; Stiglitz, and Weiss, , “Incentive Effects of Terminations: Applications to the Credit and Labor Markets,” American Economic Review 73, no. 5 (1983): 912–27.Google Scholar

67 The data cover the period from 1826 to 1870. The findings are similar to those of Capie, Forrest and Collins, Michael, “Industrial Lending by English Commercial Banks, 1860s-1914: Why did Banks Refuse Loans?Business History 38, no. 1 (1996): 35CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Capie, and Collins, , “Banks, Industry and Finance, 1880–1914,” Business History 41, no. 1 (1999): 42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

68 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 101, 82.Google Scholar

69 Beveridge, , “Local Lending Practice,” 399.Google Scholar

7 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 2.Google Scholar

71 BradBC, BDM, 1 June 1827, B2, HSBCGA.

72 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 21.Google Scholar

73 For example, see CWBC, BDM, 3 Feb. 1837, 045, LTSBGA.

74 For example, deposits and balances due by the Sheffield Union Bank increased from £86,000 in 1850 to £161,000 in i860. SUB, BDM, AD 2, 3, 4, and 5, HSBCGA.

75 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 84, 88–89.Google Scholar

76 Bencivenga, Valerie and Smith, Bruce D., “Financial Intermediation and Endogenous Growth,” Review of Economic Studies 58 (Apr. 1991): 195209CrossRefGoogle Scholar; King, Robert G. and Levine, Ross, “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter May Be Right,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, no. 3 (1993): 717–37CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Levine, Ross, “Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda,” Journal of Economic Literature 35, no. 2 (1997): 701–9Google Scholar; Rousseau, P. L. and Sylla, Richard, “Emerging Financial Markets and Early U.S. Growth,” Explorations in Economic History 42, no. 1 (2005): 126.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

77 See Crafts, Nicholas F. R., “British Economic Growth, 1700–1850: Some Difficulties of Interpretation,” Explorations in Economic History 24, no. 3 (1987): 177–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hoppit, Julian, “Counting the Industrial Revolution,” Economic History Review 43, no. 2 (1990): 173–93CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jackson, R. V., “Rates of Industrial Growth during the Industrial Revolution,” Economic History Review 45, no. 1 (1992): 123CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Berg, Maxine and Hudson, Pat, “Rehabilitating the Industrial Revolution,” Economic History Review 45, no. 1 (1992): 2450CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Crafts, Nicholas F. R. and Knick Harley, C., “Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View,” Economic History Review 45, no. 4 (1992): 703–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

78 Crafts, and Harley, , “Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution,” 712–13.Google Scholar

79 The establishment of JSBs occurred after the start of industrial growth in Britain (from 1826 onward), yet their formation coincided with a marked increase in industrial activity during the 1820s and 1830s, as measured by Crafts and Harley.

80 Hudson, Pat, The Genesis of Industrial Capital: A Study of the West Riding Wool Textile Industry, c. 1750–1850 (Cambridge, U.K., 1986)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Capie and Collins, “Industrial Lending”; Capie and Collins, “Banks, Industry and Finance”; Collins, and Baker, , Commercial Banks and Industrial Finance in England, 1860–1913 (Oxford, 2005).Google Scholar

81 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 159.Google Scholar

82 Ibid., 1,4,158.

83 Ibid., 82–83.

84 See Newton, “Change and Continuity.”

85 Cottrell, Philip L., Industrial Finance, 1830–1914: The Finance and Organisation of Manufacturing Industry (London, 1979), 236–44Google Scholar; Holmes, and Green, , Midland, 109–12Google Scholar; Lavington, Frederick, The English Capital Market (London, 1921; reissued New York, 1968), 143Google Scholar; Newton, “Trust and Virtue.”

86 For a summary of these arguments, see Newton, Lucy A., “Government, the Banks and Industry in Interwar Britain,” in Business and Politics in Europe, 1900–1970, ed. Gourvish, Terry (Cambridge, U.K., 2003), 145–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

87 Collins, and Baker, , Commercial Banks, ch. 3Google Scholar; Newton, , “Trust and Virtue,” 182–83Google Scholar; Sayers, Richard S., Lloyds Bank in the History of English Banking (Oxford, 1957), 271Google Scholar; Cottrell, , Industrial Finance, 236–44.Google Scholar

88 Collins, Michael and Baker, Mae, “English Commercial Bank Liquidity, 1860–1913,” Accounting, Business and Financial History 11, no. 2 (2001): 171–91Google Scholar; Scott, Peter M. and Newton, L. A., “Jealous Monopolists? British Banks and Responses to the Macmillan Gap during the 1930s,” Enterprise and Society 8 (Dec. 2007): 881919.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

89 Lamoreaux, , Insider Lending, 133–42.Google Scholar

90 Ibid., 139–41.

91 Ibid., 105,154,155.

92 For example, see Bamberg, James H., “The Rationalization of the British Cotton Industry in the Interwar Years,” Textile History 19, no. 1 (1988): 83102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

93 Temin, , Engines of Enterprise, ch. 4Google Scholar; and Johnson and Supple, Boston Capitalists.