Skip to main content
×
Home

Patent Alchemy: The Market for Technology in US History

Abstract

The literature on inventors has traditionally focused on entrepreneurs who exploited their ideas in their own businesses and on researchers who worked in large firms' R&D laboratories. For most of US history, however, it was as common for inventors to profit from their ideas by selling off or licensing the patent rights. This article traces the different ways in which inventors resolved the information problems involved in marketing their patents. We focus in particular on the patent attorneys who emerged during the last third of the nineteenth century to help inventors find buyers for their intellectual property.

Copyright
References
Hide All

1 See Merges Robert P., “The Trouble with Trolls: Innovation, Rent-Seeking, and Patent Law Reform,” Berkeley Technology Law Journal 24 (Fall 2009): 15831614; and Bessen James, Ford Jennifer, and Meurer Michael J., “The Private and Social Costs of Patent Trolls,” Boston University School of Law Working Paper no. 11–45 (Sept. 2011).

2 See, for example, McCurdy Daniel P., “Patent Trolls Erode the Foundation of the US Patent System,” Science Progress 1, no. 2 (2009): 7886.

3 US Federal Trade Commission, “The Evolving IP Marketplace: Aligning Patent Notice and Remedies with Competition” (Mar. 2011), http://www.ftc.gov/os/2011/03/110307patentreport.pdf, accessed 12 Oct. 2012.

4 For numbers of patents, see Carter Susan B.et al., eds., Historical Statistics of the United States: Earliest Times to the Present, Millennial Edition, vol. 3 (New York, 2006), 426–29.

5 Arrow Kenneth J., “Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention,” in The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, ed. Universities—National Bureau Committee for Economic Research (Princeton, NJ, 1962), 609–25; Teece David J., “Technological Change and the Nature of the Firm,” in Technical Change and Economic Theory, ed. Dosi Giovanniet al. (London, 1988), 256–81; Mowery David C., “The Boundaries of the US Firm in R&D,” in Coordination and Information: Historical Perspectives on the Organization of Enterprise, ed. Lamoreaux Naomi R. and Raff Daniel M. G. (Chicago, 1995), 147–76.

6 Lamoreaux Naomi R. and Sokoloff Kenneth L., “Inventors, Firms, and the Market for Technology in the Late Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries,” in Learning by Doing in Markets, Firms, and Countries, ed. Lamoreaux Naomi R., Raff Daniel M. G., and Temin Peter (Chicago, 1999), 1957; Gans Joshua and Stern Scott, “The Product Market and the Market for ‘Ideas’: Commercialization Strategies for Technology Entrepreneurs,” Research Policy 32 (Feb. 2003): 333–50; Arora Ashish, Fosfuri Andrea, and Gambardella Alfonso, Markets for Technology: The Economics of Innovation and Corporate Strategy (Cambridge, MA, 2001); Graham Margaret B. W., “Entrepreneurship in the United States, 1920–2000,” The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times, ed. Landes David S., Mokyr Joel, and Baumol William J. (Princeton, NJ, 2010), 401–42. See also the introduction and essays in Clarke Sally H., Lamoreaux Naomi R., and Usselman Steven W., eds., The Challenge of Remaining Innovative: Insights from Twentieth-Century American Business (Stanford, CA, 2009).

7 Khan B. Zorina and Sokoloff Kenneth L., “Institutions and Technological Innovation during Early Economic Growth: Evidence from the Great Inventors of the United States, 1790–1930,” NBER Working Paper no. 10966 (Dec. 2004).

8 US Congress, “An Act to Promote the Progress of Useful Arts,” ch. 357, 5 Stat. 117 (4 July 1836).

9 Both sets of volumes are stored in the National Archives in Washington, DC, in the Records of the Patent and Trademark Office, Record Group 241. For a primer on how to use these records, see Cooper Carolyn C., “Thomas Blanchard's Woodworking Machines: Tracking Nineteenth-Century Technological Diffusion,” Industrial Archaeology 13, no. 1 (1987): 4154.

10 Edison's patents are available through the Web site of the Thomas Edison Papers at Rutgers University, http://edison.rutgers.edu/patents.htm, accessed 17 July 2012.

11 Liber vol. W–3, Records of the Patent and Trademark Office, Record Group 241, National Archives, 295.

12 Liber vol. W–3, 9, 335–36.

13 Cooper Carolyn C., “William Woodworth's Planer: The Patent and Its Politics, 1828–1856,” Dutchess County Historical Society Yearbook 91 (2012): 101–16.

14 Cooper Carolyn C., “Social Construction of Invention through Patent Management: Thomas Blanchard's Woodworking Machinery,” Technology and Culture 32 (Oct. 1991): 960–98.

15 Winder Gordon M., “Before the Corporation and Mass Production: The Licensing Regime in the Manufacture of North American Harvesting Machinery, 1830–1910,” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 85 (Sept. 1995): 520–52.

16 See Lipman Jean, Rufus Porter: Yankee Pioneer (New York, 1968), 2748.

17 Advice manuals showered inventors with suggestions about how to market their patents. See, for example, Simonds William Edgar, Practical Suggestions on the Sale of Patents (Hartford, CT, 1871).

18 Liber vol. G–2, 319–20, 420–21.

19 For a picture of one such wagon from a somewhat later period, see Cooper , “Social Construction of Invention,” 963.

20 Simonds , Practical Suggestions, 2829.

21 See Patent Rights, and the Way Farmers are Humbugged,” Transactions of the New York State Agricultural Society 28 (1868): 501–3.

22 Hardesty v. Smith, 3 Ind. 41 (1851).

23 Adams v. Johnson, 15 Ill. 345 (1854). Of course, buyers could use claims of fraud as an excuse to renege, but this would itself be possible only in an environment fraught with information asymmetries.

24 “In the Matter of Hon. Platt Potter and Winsor B. French, Esq.,” Appendix: Breach of Cases Privilege, Reports of Cases in the Supreme Court of the State of New York, vol. 55 (Albany, NY, 1870), 665–66.

25 Brown v. Wright, 17 Ark. 9 (1856).

26 Foss v. Richardson, 81 Mass. 303 (1860).

27 Simonds , Practical Suggestions, 28. The classic study of this problem is Akerlof George A., “The Market for ‘Lemons’: Quality Uncertainty and the Market Mechanism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84 (Aug. 1970): 488500.

28 Supplement to the Statutes of Indiana in Force 1870, vol. 3, 364–65. For a list of states passing such laws, see Cresee F. A., Practical Pointers for Patentees: Containing Valuable Information and Advice on the Sale of Patents (New York, 1902), 8891.

29 Ex parte Robinson, 20 F. Cas. 961 (1870).

30 Cresee , Practical Pointers, 8891. The Supreme Court later ruled that a state could impose licensing requirements on sellers of patented articles so long as it did not discriminate in favor of residents. By that time, however, geographic patent assignments were no longer of much importance. See Webber v. Virginia, 103 US 344 (1881).

31 Hardesty v. Smith, 3 Ind. 41 (1851) at 43.

32 Rockafellow v. Baker, 31 Pa. 319 (1862) at 320, 321.

33 Miller v. Young's Administrator, 33 Ill. 355 (1864). See also Gatling v. Newell, 12 Ind. 99 (1859); Bond and Green v. Clark, 35 Vt. 577 (1863). For a summary of the case law, see William C. Robinson, The Law of Patents for Useful Inventions, vol. 3 (Boston, 1890), 6593–470.

34 Gatling v. Newell, 12 Ind. 99 (1859). For other grounds on which assignments claimed to be fraudulent were upheld, see Adams v. Johnson, 15 Ill. 345 (1854); Myers v. Turner, 17 Ill. 179 (1855); Jolliffe & Holland v. Collins, 21 Mo. 338 (1855); and Galpin v. Atwater, 29 Conn. 93 (1860). For examples where courts did not side with sellers see McClure v. Jeffrey, 8 Ind. 73 (1856); Bierce v. Stocking, 77 Mass. 174 (1858); Pierce v. Wilson, 34 Ala. 596 (1859); Lester v. Palmer, 86 Mass. 145 (1862); Clough v. Patrick, 37 Vt. 421 (1865), and David v. Park, 103 Mass. 501 (1870).

35 See, for example, the evaluations of new technologies that the New York Agricultural Society published in its annual Transactions; The Seventh Exhibition of the Massachusetts Charitable Mechanic Association at Faneuil and Quincy Halls, in the City of Boston, September, 1853 (Boston, 1853), vi; and Report of the Twentieth Exhibition of American Manufacturers,” published as an appendix to the Journal of the Franklin Institute 20 (1850). More generally, see Khan B. Zorina, “Promoting the Useful Arts: Technological Innovation outside the Patent System, 1790–1880,” unpublished paper (Aug. 2009); and Sinclair Bruce, Philadelphia's Philosopher Mechanics: A History of the Franklin Institute, 1824–1865 (Baltimore, 1974).

36 On this point, see especially Khan, “Promoting the Useful Arts.” Khan's evidence shows, moreover, that prizes were not awarded exclusively or perhaps even primarily on grounds of technical merit.

37 American Patents,” Journal of the Franklin Institute 20 (Dec. 1835): 385407.

38 Borut Michael, “The Scientific American in Nineteenth Century America,” unpublished PhD dissertation, New York University (1977), 4262.

39 Scientific American 11 (6 Oct. 1855): 26.

40 Ibid.

41 Ibid., 31. Munn greatly exaggerated the journal's circulation. Based on Munn's own diary, Borut concluded that circulation peaked at around 25,000 during the 1850s. See Borut , “Scientific American,” 6571.

42 A series of articles that Scientific American published during the late 1840s and early 1850s exposing popular inventions as fraudulent or based on bad science may have helped build the journal's reputation. See Borut , “Scientific American,” esp. 101–2. However, David A. Hounshell found that, as late as the 1880s, even the magazine's feature articles were for sale. See Hounshell , “Public Relations or Public Understanding? The American Industries Series in Scientific American,” Technology and Culture 21 (Oct. 1980): 589–93.

43 This figure is based on an examination (for patentees whose surnames began with the letter “B”) of the correspondents recorded as handling patent assignments in the Patent Office Digests.

44 Borut concluded from examining advertisements in Scientific American that Munn & Company did not use the journal to promote the sale of patents. See Borut , “Scientific American,” 125–26.

45 As one might expect, Munn & Company's success fostered imitation. In 1864 two of the agency's employees quit to found a competing journal, the American Artisan, in combination with a patent agency, Brown, Coombs & Company. A few years later another agency called the US Patent Right Association began publishing the Patent Right Gazette, and in the 1870s the American Patent Agency began publishing the American Inventor. Unlike Scientific American, however, none of these other publications lasted very long. Judging from the entries in WorldCat, the American Artisan survived from 1864 to 1875; the Patent Right G azette from 1871 to 1877; and the American Inventor from 1878 to 1887.

46 Again, this figure is based on an examination (for patentees whose surnames began with the letter “B”) of the correspondents recorded as handling patent assignments in the manuscript Digests.

47 Cresee , Practical Pointers, 4142; Hutchinson W. B. and Criswell J. A. E., Patents and How to Make Money Out of Them (New York, 1899), 162. See also Simonds , Practical Suggestions, 79; and An Experienced and Successful Inventor, Inventor's Manual: How to Work a Patent to Make It Pay, rev. ed. (New York, 1901), 61. It is difficult to assess the validity of these charges, but it does appear that few patents were actually sold by such agencies. We have collected samples of assignment contracts from the Patent Office Digests and have not found any assignments handled by agencies that appear in these advertisements.

48 Simonds , Practical Suggestions, 2425.

49 Ibid., 19–28; Hutchinson and Criswell, Patents; An Experienced and Successful Inventor, Inventor's Manual; Cresee , Practical Pointers, 4652.

50 “Testimony Taken on Behalf of James Edward Smith,” Hammerstein v. Smith (1890), 68, Case 13618, Paper No. 48, Box 1868, Interference Case Files, 1836–1905, Records of the Patent and Trademark Office, Record Group 241, National Archives.

51 T. D. Lockwood, Reports of Inventions (Not Approved), 1904–8, Box 1383, courtesy of AT&T Archives and History Center, Warren, NJ.

52 Post Robert C., “‘Liberalizers’ versus ‘Scientific Men’ in the Antebellum Patent Office,” Technology and Culture 17 (Jan. 1976): 2454.

53 Standards for entry into the legal profession were quite lax during this period, and some patent attorneys had little formal training in the law. To conduct business with the Patent Office all patent attorneys had to do was register. From time to time, the Patent Office “disbarred” attorneys, probably because of malfeasance. On professional legal standards in the nineteenth century, see Bloomfield Maxwell, American Lawyers in a Changing Society, 1776–1876 (Cambridge, MA, 1976); and Bloomfield Maxwell, “Law: The Development of a Profession,” in The Professions in American History, ed. Hatch Nathan O. (Notre Dame, IN, 1988), 3349.

54 The table probably overstates the rate of growth of patent attorneys during the 1880s. The Patent Office had just begun to compile its list of registered agents, and it is likely that much of this growth represents an increase in the proportion of agents who were registered rather than in the number of agents themselves.

55 Because our first list of registered agents is for 1883, the table probably understates the importance of patent agents and attorneys relative to other third parties in 1871.

56 See the entries in Van Winkle's business diary for 12 Jan.; 2 Feb.; 22, 23 and 29 Mar.; 6, 20, and 28 Apr.; and 16 Aug. 1905, Edward Van Winkle Papers, Ac. 669, Rutgers University Libraries Special Collections, Rutgers, NJ. On December 29, 1905, the same two men brought Van Winkle a soap shaving machine invented by a Mr. Luis to examine and evaluate.

57 See the letter of 22 July 1912 from Conover Fitch, vice president of the Waltham Watch Company to Wright, Brown, Quinby & May, and Arthur H. Brown's report of 27 July 1912, Wright, Brown, Quinby & May Correspondence Files, Mss. 598, Case 2, Waltham Watch Company records, Baker Library Historical Collections, Harvard Business School, Boston, MA.

58 Letters of 25 Jan. 1915 and 18 Sept. 1917 from the Waltham Watch Company, Wright, Brown, Quinby & May Correspondence Files.

59 Letter of 31 Aug. 1914 from Thurston and Kwis to Rollin H. White, Container 1, Folder 4, Rollin H. White and Walter C. White Papers, Ms. 4734, Western Reserve Historical Society, Cleveland, OH.

60 See 10 May 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

61 See, for examples, 30 Jan.; 16 and 17 Mar.; 1 Apr.; 1 and 7 May 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

62 See, for examples, 6 and 28 Jan.; and 13 June 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

63 See, for examples, 4, 16, and 23 Feb.; 7 Apr.; 11 and 20 May; and 6 Sept. 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

64 See, for examples, 3 Feb., 21 Mar., and 17 July 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

65 See 30 Jan., 7 May, and 18 July 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

66 See 6 and 28 Jan.; and 21 Oct. 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

67 See 24 Aug. 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

68 See the diary entry for 20 May 1905. Oliver and Peters subsequently had some disagreement about the terms of the arrangement, and it is not clear whether the deal actually went through. See also 21 and 24 Jan.; 25 and 28 Feb.; 2 Mar.; 13, 22, and 27 May 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

69 See 27 Feb.; 7 and 8 Mar.; 24 and 26 June; 26 July; 6 and 8 Sept.; and 17 Nov. 1905, Van Winkle Diary. Disagreements developed in this case too between Oliver and the inventor. See, for example, 21 and 31 July; 8 and 17 Aug.; and 22 Nov. 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

70 Usselman Steven W., Regulating Railroad Innovation: Business, Technology, and Politics in America, 1840–1920 (New York, 2002), 108–117, 169–76; and Usselman Steven W., “Patents Purloined: Railroads, Inventors, and the Diffusion of Innovation in Nineteenth-Century America,” Technology and Culture 32 (Oct. 1991): 1047–75. For the Supreme Court decision, see Railway Co. v. Sayles, 97 US 554 (1878).

71 Hayter Earl W., “The Patent System and Agrarian Discontent, 1875–1888,” Mississippi Valley Historical Review 34 (June 1947): 5982; Hayter Earl W., “The Western Farmers and the Drivewell Patent Controversy,” Agricultural History 16 (Jan. 1942): 1628; Magliocca Gerard N., “Blackberries and Barnyards: Patent Trolls and the Perils of Innovation,” Notre Dame Law Review 82 (June 2007): 1809–38.

72 Hayter, “Patent System.” Another source of the difficulty was a ruling by the Commissioner of Patents in 1870 that for a couple of decades allowed the Patent Office to grant design patents for “useful” changes of form. For a discussion of the confusion created by that decision, see Magliocca Gerard N., “Ornamental Design and Incremental Innovation,” Marquette Law Review 86 (Summer 2003): 845–94; and Gerard N. Magliocca, “Blackberries and Barnyards.”

73 Hayter, “Patent System”; Hayter, “Western Farmers”; and Hayter Earl W., “An Iowa Farmers' Protective Association: A Barbed Wire Patent Protest Movement,” Iowa Journal of History and Politics 37 (Oct. 1939): 331–62.

74 The additional examples were flour milling (Imposition on Millers: The Brua Patent Used to Extort Unearned Royalties,” New York Times, 10 Jan. 1896, 14) and brewing (Brewers' Patent Suits,” Scientific American 43 [16 Oct. 1880]: 246). Besides these cases and a few references to the problems in railroads and agriculture, we turned up only a couple of articles about patent sharks: A Note of Warning,” Stone 17 (1 Nov. 1898): 436; and The Patent Bill,” New York Times, 11 Jan. 1879, 4.

75 The one individual on the list in 1891 was at the low end of the scale with 14 patents. Three of the 48 assignees with more than 10 patents in 1911 were individuals. They too were at the low end with 11, 14, and 17 patents respectively, compared to 318 for General Electric, 176 for United Shoe Machinery, and 98 for Westinghouse Electric and Manufacturing Company. The samples include about half the population of assignees. We collected them by recording the number of patents received by assignees that appeared on every other page of the lists of assignees in the Annual Report of the Commissioner of Patents for 1891 and 1911. Because we included all patents received by each assignee, we necessarily included patents from pages that were not part of the sample. Hence, our counts overstate the proportion of assignments obtained by assignees acquiring large numbers of patents.

76 Because the results for the two samples are so similar, we combine them in the analysis that follows. The main difference between the two is that productive patentees in 1910–11 found their preferred attorneys slightly more quickly on average than in 1890–91.

77 See “Testimony on Behalf of Joseph Arbes,” 10, 22–23, 26, Arbes v. Lewis (1900), Case 20,049, Box 2,715, Interference Case Files, 1836–1905.

78 7 May 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

79 We focus our discussion on the second two panels because we do not have any lists of registered patent agents before 1883. To the extent that the patent agents listed as correspondents were not functioning as intermediaries, it should be harder to find support in the data for our hypothesis that patent agents improved the functioning of the market.

80 They also handled a disproportionate number of contracts for which we lack information on the patent's date of issue. After searching for these patents in the Lexis-Nexis and Google patent databases, we concluded that most of them, especially in 1871 and 1911, were assignments recorded before issue for which the Patent Office had neglected to go back and add the patent number. In other cases, however, the assignment was for an invention that never made it through the patent approval process. These latter cases are useful reminders that assignees who contracted for patents before the date of issue could not be certain that the patent would ever be allowed, which made the soundness of the patent attorney's judgments all the more important.

81 The results here and in our subsequent analysis were essentially the same when we used three-year intervals.

82 The proportion for which the change in the absolute number of patents was greater after meeting the preferred attorney than in either of the other two comparisons was even larger: 57.1 percent for those with 10–19 patents and 61.0 percent for those with 20 or more patents. This analysis still does not eliminate the possibility that inventors tended to find their preferred attorneys early in their careers, just at the point where their rate of patenting was taking off. To test for this possibility, we regressed the change in patenting that occurred in the five years after the inventor met the preferred attorney compared to the five years before on the number of years that elapsed between the inventor's first patent and the first one filed by the preferred attorney. We found no statistically significant association, which suggests that inventors got a boost from hooking up with a preferred attorney regardless of career stage. We controlled for the year in which the inventor filed his or her first patent, whether the inventor was part of the 1910–11 (as opposed to 1890–91) sample, and the region in which the patentee resided. We also checked for an interaction between the year of the inventor's first patent and the number of years that elapsed before hooking up with a preferred attorney. Because none of the key variables were significant, we do not report the results.

83 H. W. Boardman & Co., Hints to Inventors and Others Interested in Patent Matters (Boston, 1869), 13.

84 On the weakness of bar associations, see Bloomfield, “Law.” As mentioned above, the Patent Office maintained a list of patent agents certified to practice before it, and small numbers of agents were from time to time disqualified.

85 For a more formal analysis, see Wolinsky Asher, “Competition in a Market for Informed Experts' Services,” Rand Journal of Economics 24 (Autumn 1993): 380–98. See also Garmaise Mark J. and Moskowitz Tobias J., “Informal Financial Networks: Theory and Evidence,” Review of Financial Studies 16 (Winter 2003): 1007–40.

86 16 May 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

87 16 and 17 May 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

88 31 July 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

89 31 Mar. 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

90 8 Aug. 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

91 24 Jan.1905, Van Winkle Diary. See also 5 Mar.; and 7 and 12 June 1905.

92 7 and 8 June 1905, Van Winkle Diary. One might wonder whether inventors' dependence on patent attorneys enabled the latter to earn supra-normal returns at the patentees' expense. However, the number of patent attorneys increased so dramatically in the late nineteenth century, both in absolute terms and relative to the size of the population, that it is likely that any excess returns would have been competed away. Certainly, no attorney ever attained a dominance in the last quarter of the century comparable to that of Munn & Company in the years immediately following the Civil War. The top attorney in our 1871 sample accounted for 5.5 percent of the patent assignments and the top four attorneys 13.5 percent. Those percentages dropped steadily until 1911, when the top attorney handled only 1.3 percent of the assignments and the top four only 4.6 percent. It would also be desirable to know whether patent attorneys benefitted patentees by securing them better prices for their inventions. Unfortunately, the data do not allow us to explore this possibility. By the late nineteenth century contracts typically specified that the assignment was “for one dollar and other consideration.”

93 Nathan John E., Fish & Neave: Leaders in the Law of Ideas (New York, 1997), 13, 19.

94 In Memoriam: Samuel S. Fisher (Cincinnati, OH, 1874), 24.

95 See the Wright, Brown, Quinby & May Correspondence Files for letters among patent agents in different cities. Virtually all agents also had regular dealings with at least one attorney in Washington, who could be called upon to conduct searches of patent records and perhaps represent them in preliminary interviews with patent examiners.

96 Letter of 30 Apr. 1870 from Aug. H. [last name illegible] to Jenks, Box 3, Folder 59, Mss. 867, Lemuel P. Jenks records, Baker Library Historical Collections, Harvard Business School.

97 Letter of 12 July 1877 from Roger Cartwright of London to Blatchford, Seward & Gris-wold, Box 5, Folder 243, Records of Blatchford, Seward & Griswold, 1841–1910, Archives and Special Collections, Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

98 27 Mar. 1905, 28 Apr., 9 May, 1 and 2 June 1905, Van Winkle Diary.

99 On the growing importance of industrial R&D in the middle third of the twentieth century, see Lamoreaux Naomi R., Sokoloff Kenneth L., and Sutthiphisal Dhanoos, “The Reorganization of Inventive Activity in the United States in the Early Twentieth Century,” in Understanding Long-Run Economic Growth: Geography, Institutions, and the Knowledge Economy, eds. Costa Dora L. and Lamoreaux Naomi R. (Chicago, 2011), 235–74. This is not to say that independent inventors completely disappeared or that large firms stopped acquiring technology in the market. See Hintz Eric S., “The Post-Heroic Generation: American Independent Inventors, 1900–1950,” unpublished PhD dissertation, University of Pennsylvania (2010); Nicholas Tom, “Spatial Diversity in Invention: Evidence from Early R&D Labs,” Journal of Economic Geography 9 (Jan. 2009): 131; and Nicholas Tom, “The Role of Independent Invention in US Technological Development, 1880–1930,” Journal of Economic History 70 (Mar. 2010): 5782. Over time, however, large firms increasingly relied on internally generated technology. See Mowery, “Boundaries of the US Firm.”

100 Hicks Dianaet al., “The Changing Composition of Innovative Activity in the US-A Portrait Based on Patent Analysis,” Research Policy 30 (Apr. 2001): 681703. The authors define small patentees as companies that are either outside the Tech-Line database or that had less than 25 patents in the five years ending in 1993. The Tech-Line database includes the companies most active in patenting, about 400 all told.

101 Arora Ashish and Gambardella Alfonso, “The Market for Technology,” in Handbook of the Economics of Innovation, eds. Hall Bronwyn H. and Rosenberg Nathan, vol. 1 (Amsterdam, 2010), 641–78. The authors define large companies as those with more than 25,000 employees. See also the essays in Richard S. Rosenbloom and Spencer William J., eds., Engines of Innovation: US Industrial Research at the End of an Era (Boston, 1996).

102 Serrano Carlos J., “The Dynamics of the Transfer and Renewal of Patents,” RAND Journal of Economics 41 (Winter 2010): 686708. The proportions of patents sold are all seven or eight percentage points higher if the patents are weighted by importance according to the number of subsequent patents that cited them.

103 Since 1980, patent holders have had to pay renewal fees to keep their patents active for more than four years. Carlos Serrano J., “Estimating the Gains from Trade in the Market for Innovation: Evidence from the Transfer of Patents,” NBER Working Paper 17304 (Aug. 2011).

104 Zucker Lynne G., Darby Michael R., and Armstrong Jeff S., “Geographically Localized Knowledge: Spillovers or Markets?Economic Inquiry 36 (Jan. 1998): 6586; and Zucker Lynne J., Darby Michael R., and Brewer Marilynn B., “Intellectual Human Capital and the Birth of US Biotechnology Enterprises,” American Economic Review 88 (Mar. 1998): 290306. See also Galambos Louis, with Sewell Jane Eliot, Networks of Innovation: Vaccine Development at Merck, Sharp & Dohme, and Mulford, 1895–1995 (New York, 1995); and Powell Walter W., Koput Kenneth W., and Smith-Doerr Laurel, “Interorganizational Collaboration and the Locus of Innovation: Networks of Learning in Biotechnology,” Administrative Science Quarterly 41 (Mar. 1996): 116–45.

105 For Silicon Valley, see Saxenian AnnaLee, Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128 (Cambridge, MA, 1994); Castilla Emilio J., et al., “Social Networks in Silicon Valley,” in The Silicon Valley Edge: A Habitat for Innovation and Entre-preneurship, eds. Lee Chong-Moon and Miller William F. (Stanford, CA, 2000), 218–47; Kenney Martin and Florida Richard, “Venture Capital in Silicon Valley: Fueling New Firm Formation,” in Understanding Silicon Valley: The Anatomy of an Entrepreneurial Region, ed. Kenney Martin (Stanford, CA, 2000), 98123; Suchman Mark C., “Dealmakers and Counselors: Law Firms as Intermediaries in the Development of Silicon Valley,” in Understanding Silicon Valley, 7197; and Suchman Mark C., “On the Advice of Counsel: Law Firms and Venture Capital Funds as Information Intermediaries in the Structuration of Silicon Valley,” unpublished PhD dissertation, Stanford University (1994).

106 On software patents, see Bessen James and Meurer Michael J., Patent Failure: How Judges, Bureaucrats, and Lawyers Put Innovators at Risk (Princeton, NJ, 2008), esp. ch. 9. Software and business methods have only recently been made patentable, and the kinds of problems they have created are analogous to those resulting from the recognition of design patents for useful changes of form in the late nineteenth century. See Magliocca, “Ornamental Design.”

107 A search of mainstream publications on the word “troll” easily turns up hundreds, even thousands, of times more articles than comparable searches for the late nineteenth century.

108 See Allison John R., Lemley Mark A., and Walker Joshua, “Extreme Value or Trolls on Top? The Characteristics of the Most-Litigated Patents,” University of Pennsylvania Law Review 158 (Dec. 2009): 137; and Allison John R., Lemley Mark A., and Walker Joshua, “Patent Quality and Settlement among Repeat Patent Litigants,” Georgetown Law Journal 99 (Mar. 2011): 677712. The category of non-practicing entities includes inventor-owned enterprises, universities, and many other entities besides trolls. Allison and his co-authors compared frequently litigated patents (that is, those that are the subject of at least eight legal filings) to a random sample of patents that show up in the litigation records only once. Nearly three-fourths of the patents involved in frequent litigation were in computer software and business methods. The figure for litigation failures varies depending on whether default judgments are included. Information on the Stanford database is available at http://www.law.stanford.edu/node/149621, accessed 12 Oct. 2012.

109 For descriptions of some of these entities, see Millien Raymond and Laurie Ron, “Meet the Middlemen,” Intellectual Asset Management Magazine 28 (Feb.-Mar. 2008): 5358, www.iam-magazine.com.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

Business History Review
  • ISSN: 0007-6805
  • EISSN: 2044-768X
  • URL: /core/journals/business-history-review
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×

Metrics

Altmetric attention score

Full text views

Total number of HTML views: 0
Total number of PDF views: 135 *
Loading metrics...

Abstract views

Total abstract views: 411 *
Loading metrics...

* Views captured on Cambridge Core between September 2016 - 18th November 2017. This data will be updated every 24 hours.