Hostname: page-component-54dcc4c588-5q6g5 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-10-03T15:31:56.496Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An experimental test of Taylor-type rules with inexperienced central bankers

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Jim Engle-Warnick*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, McGill University, 855 Sherbrooke St. W., Montreal QC H3A 2T7, Canada
Nurlan Turdaliev*
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, 401 Sunset Avenue, University of Windsor, Windsor ON N9B 3P4, Canada

Abstract

We experimentally test monetary policy decision making in a population of inexperienced central bankers. In our experiments, subjects repeatedly set the short-term interest rate for a computer economy with inflation as their target. A large majority of subjects learn to successfully control inflation by correctly putting higher weight on inflation than on the output gap. In fact, the behavior of these subjects meets a stability criterion. The subjects smooth the interest rate as the theoretical literature suggests they should in order to enhance stability of the uncertain system they face. Our study is the first to use Taylor-type rules as a framework to identify inflation weighting, stability, and interest-rate smoothing as behavioral outcomes when subjects try to achieve an inflation target.

Information

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Economic Science Association 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10683-010-9233-9) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58, 277297.10.2307/2297968CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arifovic, J., & Sargent, T. (2003). Laboratory experiments with an expectational Phillips curve. In Altig, D., & Smith, B. (Eds.), Evolution and procedures in central banking (pp. 2355). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511510762.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ball, L. (1997). Efficient rules for monetary policy (Working Paper No. 5952, NBER).Google Scholar
Bernanke, B., & Woodford, M. (Eds.) (2005). The inflation targeting debate. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Blinder, A. (1998). Central banking in theory and practice. Cambridge: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Blinder, A., & Morgan, J. (2005). Are two heads better than one? An experimental analysis of group versus individual decision making. Journal of Money Credit and Banking, 37, 789811.Google Scholar
Caplin, A., & Leahy, J. (1997). The money game. New Economy, 4, 2629.10.1111/j.1468-0041.1997.tb00165.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clarida, R., Gali, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). The science of monetary policy: a new Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 16611707.10.1257/jel.37.4.1661CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cukierman, A. (1996). Why does the fed smooth interest rates. In Belongia, M. (Ed.), Monetary policy on the 75th anniversary of the federal reserve system (pp. 111147). Norwell: Kluwer Academic.Google Scholar
Doornik, J. A. (2002). Object-oriented matrix programming using ox (3rd edn.). London: Timberlake Consultants Press. www.nuff.ox.ac.uk/Users/Doornik.Google Scholar
Farebrother, R. (1973). Simplified Samuelson condition for cubic and quartic equations. Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 41, 396400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U. (2007). Z-tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 10, 171178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fuhrer, J., & Moore, G. (1995). Inflation persistence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 440, 127159.10.2307/2118513CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goodfriend, M. (1991). Interest rates and the conduct of monetary policy. In Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy (vol. 34, pp. 730).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Houser, D., Keane, M., & McCabe, K. (2004). Behavior in a dynamic decision problem: an analysis of experimental evidence using a Bayesian type classification algorithm. Econometrica, 72, 781822.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, J., & Rudebusch, G. (1998). Taylor's rule and the Fed: 1970-1997. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review, 3, 316.Google Scholar
Levin, A., Wieland, V., & Williams, J. (1999). Robustness of simple monetary policy rules under model uncertainty. In Taylor, J. (Ed.), Monetary policy rules (pp. 263299). Chicago: Chicago University Press.Google Scholar
Onatski, A., & Stock, J. H. (2002). Robust monetary policy under model uncertainty in a small model of the US economy. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 6, 85110.10.1017/S1365100502027050CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orphanides, A. (2001). Monetary policy rules based on real-time data. American Economic Review, 91, 964985.10.1257/aer.91.4.964CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Orphanides, A., & Williams, J. (2007). Robust monetary policy with imperfect knowledge. Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 14061435.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2007.06.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pesaran, M., & Smith, R. (1995). Estimating long-run relationships from dynamic heterogeneous panels. Journal of Econometrics, 68, 79113.10.1016/0304-4076(94)01644-FCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rotemberg, J., & Woodford, M. (1997). An optimization-based econometric framework for the evaluation of monetary policy. In NBER macroeconomic annual (vol. 12, pp. 297346).10.1086/654340CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rudebusch, G. (2001). Is the Fed too timid? Monetary policy in an uncertain world. Review of Economics and Statistics, 83, 203217.10.1162/00346530151143752CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sack, B. (1998). Uncertainty, learning, and gradual monetary policy. In Finance and economics discussion series, Paper 34, Federal Reserve Board.10.17016/feds.1998.34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Srour, G. (2001). Why do central banks smooth interest rates? (Working Paper 2001-17). Bank of Canada.Google Scholar
Svensson, L. (1997a). Inflation forecast targeting: implementing and monitoring inflation targets. European Economic Review, 41, 11111146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, L. (1997b). Optimal inflation targets, ‘conservative’ central banks, and linear inflation contracts. American Economic Review, 87, 98114.Google Scholar
Taylor, J. (1993). Discretion vs. policy rules in practice. In Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy (vol. 39, pp. 195214).10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-LCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, J. (Ed.) (1999a). Monetary policy rules. Chicago: Chicago University Press.10.7208/chicago/9780226791265.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, J. (1999b). A historical analysis of monetary policy rules. In Taylor, J. (Ed.), Monetary policy rules (pp. 319341). Chicago: Chicago University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, J. (1999c). The robustness and efficiency of monetary policy rules as guidelines for interest rate setting by the European Central Bank. Journal of Monetary Economics, 43, 655679.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weymark, D. (2004). Economic structure, policy objectives, and optimal interest rate policy at low inflation rates. North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 15, 2551.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodford, M. (2003). Optimal interest-rate smoothing. Review of Economic Studies, 70, 861886.10.1111/1467-937X.00270CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Engle-Warnick and Turdaliev supplementary material

On-Line Appendix
Download Engle-Warnick and Turdaliev supplementary material(File)
File 565.4 KB