Hostname: page-component-cb9f654ff-9knnw Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-08-29T02:30:36.610Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Procedural fairness in lotteries assigning initial roles in a dynamic setting

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 March 2025

Gianluca Grimalda*
Affiliation:
Universitat Jaume I of Castelló, Castelló de la Plana, Spain Institute for the World Economy, Kiel, Germany Centre for the Study of Global Cooperation Research, University of Duisburg-Essen, Essen, Germany
Anirban Kar
Affiliation:
Delhi School of Economics, University of Delhi, New Delhi, India
Eugenio Proto*
Affiliation:
University of Warwick, Coventry, UK IZA, Bonn, Germany CESifo, Munich, Germany

Abstract

We extend the study of procedural fairness in three new directions. Firstly, we focus on lotteries determining the initial roles in a two-person game. One of the roles carries a potential advantage over the other. All the experimental literature has thus far focused on lotteries determining the final payoffs of a game. Secondly, we modify procedural fairness in a dynamic—i.e. over several repetitions of a game—as well as in a static—i.e. within a single game-sense. Thirdly, we analyse whether assigning individuals a minimal chance of achieving an advantaged position is enough to make them willing to accept substantially more inequality. We find that procedural fairness matters under all of these accounts. Individuals clearly respond to the degree of fairness in assigning initial roles, appraise contexts that are dynamically fair more positively than contexts that are not, and are generally more willing to accept unequal outcomes when they are granted a minimal opportunity to acquire the advantaged position. Unexpectedly, granting full equality of opportunity does not lead to the highest efficiency.

Information

Type
Original Paper
Copyright
Copyright © 2015 Economic Science Association

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

Footnotes

Electronic supplementary material The online version of this article (doi:https://doi.org/10.1007/s10683-015-9469-5) contains supplementary material, which is available to authorized users.

References

Alesina, A, & La Ferrara, E (2005). Preferences for redistribution in the land of opportunities. Journal of Public Economics, 89(5–6), 897931. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2004.05.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anand, P (2001). Procedural fairness in economic and social choice: Evidence from a survey of voters. Journal of Economic Psychology, 22(2), 247270. 10.1016/S0167-4870(01)00031-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreozzi, L., Ploner, M., & Soraperra, I. (2013). Justice among strangers. On altruism, inequality aversion and fairness. Working paper No. 1304, CEEL, Trento University.Google Scholar
Armantier, O (2006). Do wealth differences affect fairness considerations?. International Economic Review, 47(2), 391429. 10.1111/j.1468-2354.2006.00383.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, A, & Miller, L (2009). Promoting justice by treating people unequally: An experimental study. Experimental Economics, 12(4), 437449. 10.1007/s10683-009-9222-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bewley, T (1999). Why wages don’t fall during a recession, Harvard: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benabou, R, & Tirole, J (2006). Belief in the just world and redistributive politics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(2), 699746. 10.1162/qjec.2006.121.2.699CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binmore, K, Morgan, P, Shaked, A, & Sutton, J (1991). Do people exploit their bargaining power? An experimental study. Games and Economic Behavior, 3, 295322. 10.1016/0899-8256(91)90030-ICrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, GE, Brandts, J, & Ockenfels, A (2005). Fair procedures: Evidence from games involving lotteries. Economic Journal, 115(506), 10541076. 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2005.01032.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, G, & Ockenfels, A (2000). A theory of equity, reciprocity and competition. American Economic Review, 90, 166193. 10.1257/aer.90.1.166CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buchan, N, Croson, R, & Johnson, E (2004). When do fair beliefs influence bargaining behavior? Experimental bargaining in Japan and the United States. Journal of Consumer Research, 31, 181190. 10.1086/383433CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burrows, P, & Loomes, G (1994). The impact of fairness on bargaining. Empirical Economics, 19(2), 201221. 10.1007/BF01175872CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cappelen, AW, Konow, J, Sorensen, EO, & Tungodden, B (2013). Just luck: An experimental study of risk-taking and fairness. American Economic Review, 103(4), 13981413. 10.1257/aer.103.4.1398CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cappelen, A, Drange, A, Sørensen, E, & Tungodden, B (2007). The pluralism of fairness ideals: An experimental approach. American Economic Review, 97(3), 818827. 10.1257/aer.97.3.818CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charness, G, & Rabin, M (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 817869. 10.1162/003355302760193904CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Corneo, G, & Gruner, HM (2002). Individual preferences for political redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 83, 83107. 10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00172-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Diamond, P (1967). Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparison of utility: A comment. Journal of Political Economy, 75(5), 765766. 10.1086/259353CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elster, J (1989). Solomonic judgements: Studies in the limitation of rationality, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Erkal, N, Gangadharan, L, & Nikiforakis, N (2010). Relative earnings and giving in a real-effort experiment. American Economic Review, 101(7), 33303348. 10.1257/aer.101.7.3330CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fehr, E, & Schmidt, K (1999). A theory of fairness, competition and cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 817868. 10.1162/003355399556151CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Experimental Economics, 102, 171178. 10.1007/s10683-006-9159-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fong, C (2001). Social preferences, self-interest, and the demand for redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 82(2), 225246. 10.1016/S0047-2727(00)00141-9CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frey, B, & Stutzer, A (2005). Beyond outcomes, measuring procedural utility. Oxford Economic Papers, 57, 90111. 10.1093/oep/gpi002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gill, D., Prowse, V., & Vlassopoulos, M. (2012). Cheating in the workplace: An experimental study of the impact of bonuses and productivity. Available at SSRN 2109698.Google Scholar
Guth, W, Tietz, R, & Scholz, RW (1986). Auctioning ulitmatum bargaining positions—How to act rational if decisions are unacceptable?. Current issues in West German decision research, Frankfurt: Verlag Peter Lang 173185.Google Scholar
Hammond, P (1988). Consequentialist foundations for expected utility. Theory and Decision, 25(1), 2578. 10.1007/BF00129168CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Handgraaf, M, Van Dijk, E, Vermunt, R, Wilke, H, & De Dreu, C (2008). Less power or powerless? Egocentric empathy gaps and the irony of having little versus no power in social decision making. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 95(5), 11361149. 10.1037/0022-3514.95.5.1136CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hargreaves-Heap, S, & Varoufakis, Y (2002). Some experimental evidence on the evolution of discrimination, co-operation and perceptions of fairness. Economic Journal, 112, 679703. 10.1111/1468-0297.00735CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E, & Spitzer, ML (1985). Entitlements, rights and fairness: An experimental examination of subjects’ concepts of distributive justice. Journal of Legal Studies, 14, 259297. 10.1086/467773CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, E, McCabe, K, Shachat, K, & Smith, V (1994). Preferences, property rights, and anonymity in bargaining games. Games and Economic Behavior, 7(3), 346380. 10.1006/game.1994.1056CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D, & Tversky, A (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263292. 10.2307/1914185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karni, E, Salmon, T, & Sopher, B (2008). Individual sense of fairness: An experimental study. Experimental Economics, 11(2), 174189. 10.1007/s10683-007-9165-1CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Karni, E, & Safra, Z (2002). Individual sense of justice: A utility representation. Econometrica, 70, 263284. 10.1111/1468-0262.00275CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keren, G, & Teigen, K (2010). Decisions by coin toss: Inappropriate but fair. Judgement and Decision Making, 5(2), 83101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Konow, J (2003). Which is the fairest one of all? A positive analysis of justice theories. Journal of Economic Literature, 41(4), 11881239. 10.1257/002205103771800013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krawczyk, M (2011). A model of procedural and distributive fairness. Theory and Decision, 70(1), 111128. 10.1007/s11238-009-9189-4CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krawczyk, M (2010). A glimpse through the veil of ignorance: Equality of opportunity and support for redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 94, 131141. 10.1016/j.jpubeco.2009.10.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krawczyk, M, & Le Lec, F (2010). Give me a chance! An experiment in social decision under risk. Journal of Experimental Economics, 13, 500511. 10.1007/s10683-010-9253-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leventhal, GS (1980). What should be done with equity theory?, Detroit: Springer 10.1007/978-1-4613-3087-5_2CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Machina, M (1989). Dynamic consistency and non-expected utility models of choice under uncertainty. Journal of Economic Literature, 27(4), 16221668.Google Scholar
Nozick, R (1994). The nature of rationality, Princeton: Princeton University Press 10.1515/9781400820832CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oosterbeek, H, Sloof, R, & van de Kuilen, G (2004). Cultural differences in ultimatum game experiments: Evidence from a meta-analysis. Experimental Economics, 7(2), 171188. 10.1023/B:EXEC.0000026978.14316.74CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rawls, J (1999). A theory of justice, revCambridge, MA: Belknap.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmitt, PM (2004). On perceptions of fairness: The role of valuations, outside options, and information in ultimatum bargaining games. Experimental Economics, 7(1), 4973. 10.1023/A:1026210021955CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schurter, K, & Wilson, BJ (2009). Justice and fairness in the dictator game. Southern Economic Journal, 76(1), 130145. 10.4284/sej.2009.76.1.130CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suleiman, R (1996). Expectations and fairness in a modified UG. Journal of Economic Psychology, 17, 531554. 10.1016/S0167-4870(96)00029-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thibaut, JW, & Walker, L (1975). Procedural justice: A psychological analysis, Hillsdale: L. Erlbaum Associates.Google Scholar
Trautmann, S., & van de Kuilen, G. (2014). Process fairness, outcome fairness, and dynamic consistency: Experimental evidence, mimeo.Google Scholar
Trautmann, S, & Wakker, P (2010). Process fairness and dynamic consistency. Economics Letters, 109(3), 187189. 10.1016/j.econlet.2010.08.031CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trautmann, ST (2009). A tractable model of process fairness under risk. Journal of Economic Psychology, 30(5), 803813. 10.1016/j.joep.2009.07.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyler, TR (2006). Why people obey the law, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woolridge, JM (2002). Introductory econometrics: A modern approach, Cincinnati, OH: South-Western College Publishing.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Grimalda et al. supplementary material

ELECTRONIC SUPPLEMENTARY MATERIAL FOR THE PAPER “Procedural Fairness in Lotteries Assigning Initial Roles in a Dynamic Setting”
Download Grimalda et al. supplementary material(File)
File 1.3 MB