Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T06:13:15.763Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

An Explicit Formula for the Optimal Gain in the Full-Information Problem of Owning a Relatively Best Object

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 July 2016

Vladimir V. Mazalov*
Affiliation:
Karelian Research Center of the Russian Academy of Science
Mitsushi Tamaki*
Affiliation:
Aichi University
*
Postal address: Institute of Applied Mathematical Research, Karelian Research Center of the Russian Academy of Science, 11 Pushkinskaya Street, Petrozavodsk, 185610, Russia. Email address: vmazalov@trc.karelia.ru
∗∗ Postal address: Department of Business Administration, Aichi University, Nagoya Campus, 370 Kurozasa, Miyoshi, Nishikamo, Aichi 470-0296, Japan. Email address: tamaki@vega.aichi-u.ac.jp
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

A full-information version of the secretary problem in which the objective is to maximize the time of possession of a relatively best object is considered both in the case in which only the most recently observed object may be chosen and in the case in which any of the previously observed objects may be chosen. The main purpose of this paper is to obtain, under an optimal rule, both the asymptotic proportional durations when the number of objects tends to infinity, and the expected durations when the number of objects remains finite. The integral expressions for these asymptotic values are derived in both cases: the approximate numerical values are 0.435 in the former (no-recall) case and 0.449 in the latter (recall) case, indicating a surprisingly small difference. The expected values of the optimal stopping times are also obtained from the planar Poisson process analysis.

Type
Research Papers
Copyright
© Applied Probability Trust 2006 

References

Bruss, F. T. (1984). A unified approach to a class of best choice problems with an unknown number of options. Ann. Prob. 12, 882889.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruss, F. T. and Delbaen, F. (2001). Optimal rules for the sequential selection of monotone subsequences of maximum expected length. Stoch. Process. Appl. 96, 313342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferguson, T. S., Hardwick, J. P. and Tamaki, M. (1992). Maximizing the duration of owning a relatively best object. In Strategies for Sequential Search and Selection in Real Time (Amherst, MA, 1990; Contemp. Math. 125), American Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, pp. 3557.Google Scholar
Gilbert, J. P. and Mosteller, F. (1966). Recognizing the maximum of a sequence. J. Amer. Statist. Assoc. 61, 3573.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gnedin, A. V. (1996). On the full information best-choice problem. J. Appl. Prob. 33, 678687.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gnedin, A. V. (2004). Best choice from the planar Poisson process. Stoch. Process. Appl. 111, 317354.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gnedin, A. V. (2005). Objectives in the best-choice problems. Sequent. Anal. 24, 177188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gnedin, A. V. and Sakaguchi, M. (1992). On a best choice problem related to the Poisson process. In Strategies for Sequential Search and Selection in Real Time (Amherst, MA, 1990; Contemp. Math. 125), American Mathematical Society, Providence, RI, pp. 5964.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mazalov, V. V. and Tamaki, M. (2003). Explicit solutions to the duration problem. Aichi Keiei Ronsyu 147, 6992.Google Scholar
Petruccelli, J. D. (1980). On a best choice problem with partial information. Ann. Statist. 8, 11711174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petruccelli, J. D. (1982). Full-information best-choice problems with recall of observations and uncertainty of selection depending on the observation. Adv. Appl. Prob. 14, 340358.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porosiński, Z. (1987). The full-information best choice problem with a random number of observations. Stoch. Process. Appl. 24, 293307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Porosiński, Z. (2002). On best choice problems having similar solutions. Statist. Prob. Lett. 56, 321327.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Presman, E. L. and Sonin, I. M. (1972). The best choice problem for a random number of objects. Theory Prob. Appl. 17, 657668.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rocha, A. L. (1993). The infinite secretary problem with recall. Ann. Prob. 21, 898916.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, S. M. (1971). Infinitesimal look-ahead stopping rules. Ann. Math. Statist. 42, 297303.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuels, S. M. (1991). Secretary problems. In Handbook of Sequential Analysis, eds Ghosh, B. K. and Sen, P. K., Marcel Dekker, New York, pp. 381405.Google Scholar
Samuels, S. M. (2004). Why do these quite different best-choice problems have the same solutions? Adv. Appl. Prob. 36, 398416.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, M. H. and Deely, J. J. (1975). A secretary problem with finite memory. J. Amer. Statist. Assoc. 70, 357361.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tamaki, M. (1986). A full-information best-choice problem with finite memory. J. Appl. Prob. 23, 718735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yang, M. C. K. (1974). Recognizing the maximum of a random sequence based on relative rank with backward solicitation. J. Appl. Prob. 11, 504512.CrossRefGoogle Scholar