Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-qsmjn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T00:45:45.175Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Behavioral economics and policy evaluation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  17 April 2015

Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract:

Core share and HTML view are not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the ‘Save PDF’ action button.

Behavioral economics posits a number of cognitive biases and limitations, which raises questions as to whether revealed willingness to pay equals true willingness to pay. If so, benefit-cost analysis, with a number of methodological advantages, would need to be replaced. Prior analyses of the issue by Sunstein, Sugden, and Bernheim and Rangel fail to offer guidance that would avoid substituting centralized judgments for decentralized information on benefits and costs. Alternatives including using post-implementation valuations, libertarian paternalism, and direct democracy on policy issues also have conceptual or practical limitations. A tentative suggestion is democratic delegation, somewhat appealing because it is already applied to cope with bounded rationality and non-efficiency values. Viewing benefit-cost analysis as a market analogue, and restricting the domain of behavioral economics to uninformed consumers, may be useful guides. The most important guidance may be to require very strong evidence of substantial choice failure before abandoning benefit-cost analysis.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Society for Benefit-Cost Analysis 2014

References

Bernheim, D., & Rangel, A. (2009). Beyond revealed preference: choice-theoretic foundations for behavioral welfare economics. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 124, 51104.Google Scholar
Brennan, T. (2006). ‘Green’ preferences as policy instrument. Ecological Economics, 56, 144154.Google Scholar
Brennan, T. (2007). Consumer preference not to choose: methodological and policy implications. Energy Policy, 35, 16161627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brennan, T. (2010). Optimal energy efficiency policies and regulatory demand-side management tests: how well do they match? Energy Policy, 38, 38743885.Google Scholar
Carson, R., & Hanneman, M. (2005). Contingent valuation. In: Mäler, K. -G. & Vincent, J. R. (Eds.), Handbook of Environmental Economics 2 (pp. 821935). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Choi, J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B., & Metrick, A. (2002). defined contribution pensions: plan rules, participant decisions, and the path of least resistance. In: Poterba, J. (Ed.), Tax Policy and the Economy, 2 (pp. 67114). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Cooper, J., & Kovacic, W. (2012). Behavioral economics: implications for regulatory behavior. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 41, 4158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dworkin, R. (1980). Why efficiency? Hofstra Law Review, 8, 563590.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1979). Ulysses and the sirens. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Elster, J. (1985). Weakness of will and the free rider problem. Economics and Philosophy, 1, 231265.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Enkvist, P.-A., Nauclér, T., & Rosander, J. (2007). A cost curve for greenhouse gas reduction. The McKinsey Quarterly, 1, 3545.Google Scholar
Farrell, J., & Saloner, G. (1985). Standardization, compatibility, and innovation. Rand Journal of Economics, 16, 7083.Google Scholar
Fishkin, J. (2009). When the people speak: deliberative democracy and public consultation. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Horowitz, J., & McConnell, K. (2002). A review of WTA/WTP studies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 44, 426447.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., & Thaler, R. (1991). Anomalies: the endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5, 193206.Google Scholar
Knetsch, J. (1989). The endowment effect and evidence of nonreversible indifference curves. American Economic Review, 79, 12771284.Google Scholar
Liebowitz, S., & Margolis, S. (1995). Path dependence, lock-in, and history. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 11, 205226.Google Scholar
List, J. (2006). The behavioralist meets the market: measuring social preferences and reputation effects in actual transactions. Journal of Political Economy, 114, 137.Google Scholar
Mullainathan, S., & Thaler, R. (2001). Behavioral economics. In: Smelser, N. and Baltes, P. (Eds.). International Encyclopedia of the Social and Behavioral Sciences, (pp. 10941100). Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Olson, M. (1971). The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Revesz, R., & Livermore, M. (2008). Retaking rationality: how cost-benefit analysis can better protect the environment and our health. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. (1984). Self-command in practice, in policy, and in a theory of rational choice. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 74, 111.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (2005). Coping with preference anomalies in cost-benefit analysis: a market simulation approach. Environmental and Resource Economics, 32, 129160.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sugden, R. (2008). Why incoherent preferences do not justify paternalism. Constitutional Political Economy, 19, 226248.Google Scholar
Sunstein, C. (2000). Cognition and cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Legal Studies, 29, 10591103.Google Scholar
Thaler, R., & Sunstein, C. (2003). Libertarian paternalism. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 93, 175179.Google Scholar
Thaler, R., & Sunstein, C. (2009). Nudge: improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Young, H. P. (1993). Equity: in theory and practice. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar