Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-28T03:41:29.349Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Questioning executive supremacy in an economic state of emergency

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 January 2018

Alan Greene*
Affiliation:
Durham Law School
*
Dr Alan Greene, Lecturer in Law, Durham Law School, Palatine Centre, Stockton Road, Durham DH1 3LE, UK. Email alan.greene@durham.ac.uk

Abstract

This paper compares and contrasts state emergency responses to national security crises with responses deployed in a period of economic crisis. Specifically, this paper challenges the appropriateness and legitimacy of the standard emergency response of legislative (as distinct from judicial) deference to the executive when confronting such economic crises. This will be done by questioning the significance in periods of economic crisis of the two principal factors that justify deferring to the executive during a state of emergency pertaining to national security: (i) the necessity of the action taken; and (ii) that the executive has an expertise in decision making in the specific area in question. Ultimately, this paper questions the application of the emergency paradigm to economic crises, arguing that such responses are rarely temporary and instead usher in a ‘new normalcy’.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Society of Legal Scholars 2015 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

I would like to thank Fiona de Londras, Aoife Nolan, Natasa Mavronicola and the anonymous reviewers for their comments on earlier drafts of this paper. I presented this paper at the Durham Law School Staff Seminar Series, and the IACL–AIDC World Congress of Constitutional Law in June 2014. I am grateful to the participants at these events for their feedback.

References

1. ‘Debt crisis: CBY conference as it happened – November 19, 2012’ The Daily Telegraph 19 November 2012, available at http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/debt-crisis-live/9687330/Debt-crisis-CBI-Conference-as-it-happened-November-19-2012.html (accessed 10 December 2014).

2. See J Reynolds ‘The political economy of states of emergency’ 14 Or Rev Int'l Law 85.

3. Scheuerman, WEThe economic state of emergency’ (1999-2000) 21 Cardozo L Rev 1869 at 1870–1872, 1878–1879.Google ScholarEconomic crises have also been compared to natural disasters, with the US Supreme Court drawing this equivalence in Home Building and Loan Association v Blaisdell 290 US 423.

4. N Questiaux ‘Study of the implications for human rights of recent developments concerning situations known as states of siege or emergency’ UNESC, E/CN.4/Sub2/1982/ 15 (27 July 1982) at 26.

5. Ibid. De facto emergencies are problematic from a constitutionalist perspective as they bypass the shielding effect of the emergency paradigm – quarantining exceptional measures to exceptional situations – leaving only their role as a sword; that is, as an enabler of state power. See Greene, ASeparating normalcy from emergency: the jurisprudence of Article 15 of the European Convention on Human Rights’ (2011) 12(11) German L J 1764 at 1765–1766.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

6. See eg Posner, E and Vermeule, A Terror in the Balance: Security Liberty and the Courts (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007);Google Scholar de Londras, F and Davis, FControlling the executive in times of terrorism: competing perspectives on effective oversight mechanisms’ (2010) 30 Oxford J Legal Stud 19;CrossRefGoogle Scholar Ackerman, B Before the Next Attack: Preserving Civil Liberties in the Age of Terrorism (New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, 2006);Google Scholar Fenwick, H and Phillipson, GCovert derogations and judicial deference: redefining liberty and due process rights in counterterrorism law and beyond’ (2011) 46(4) McGill L J 863; to list but a select few.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

7. Posner and Vermeule, above n 6; de Londras and Davis, above n 6; Ackerman, above n 6; Lobel, JEmergency powers and the decline of liberalism’ (1989) 98(7) Yale L J 1385 CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Tushnet, MControlling executive power in the war on terrorism’ (2005) 118 Harv L Rev 2673 Google Scholar; Rossiter, C Constitutional Dictatorship: Emergency Powers: Crisis Government in the Modern Democracies (Piscataway, NJ: Transaction Publishers, 2002)Google Scholar.

8. Rossiter, above n 7, p 306.

9. Gross, OChaos and rules: should responses to violent crises always be constitutional?’ (2000) 112 Yale L J 1011 at 1069–1096.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

10. Ibid. Oren Gross argues that the four classic degrees of separation between normalcy and emergency – us versus them, domestic versus international, spatial separation and temporal separation – are no longer tenable in modernity. Mark Neocleous argues that ‘permanent state of emergency’ has now become the dominant mantra of the left and the libertarian right. Neocleous, MThe problem with normality: taking exception to “permanent emergency” ’ (2006) 31 Alternatives 191 at 195. I have argued elsewhere that the blurring of the lines between normalcy and emergency is not wholly explainable by the objective nature of the threats that face the state but through a subjective labelling of certain threats as ‘emergency’ that would not have been labelled and treated as such in the past. See generally Greene, above n 5.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

11. Gross, O and Ní Aoláin, F Law in Times of Crisis: Emergency Powers in Theory and Practice (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2006) p 22;CrossRefGoogle Scholar Greene, AShielding the state of emergency: organised crime in Ireland and the state's response’ (2011) 62(3) N Ireland L Q 249 at 252–254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12. Thus McCormick argues that the key difference between Carl Schmitt's conception of ‘commissarial’ versus ‘sovereign’ dictatorship is that the former is temporary and reactionary, whereas the latter is permanent and transformative: McCormick, JPThe dilemmas of dictatorship: Carl Schmitt and constitutional emergency powers’ (1997) 10 Can J Law & Jur 163 at 165–167;CrossRefGoogle Scholar see also Schmitt, C Dictatorship: from the Origin of the Modern Concept of Sovereignty to Proletarian Class Struggle, tr M Hoelzl and G Ward (Cambridge, UK: Polity Press, 2014).Google Scholar

13. This is recognised be international human rights treaties such as Art 4 ICCPR and Art 15 ECHR, which allow contracting states to derogate from their ordinary human rights obligations ‘to the extent strictly required by the exigencies of the situation’.

14. Thomson, JJKilling, letting die, and the trolley problem’ (1976) 59(2) The Monist 204;CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed Thompson, JJThe trolley problem’ (1985) 94 Yale L J 1395;CrossRefGoogle Scholar Otsuka, MDouble effect, triple effect and the trolley problem: squaring the circle in looping cases’ (2008) 20(1) Utilitas 92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

15. Glazebrook, PRThe necessity plea in English criminal law’ (1972) 30 Camb L J 87 at 88. The defence of necessity in criminal law operates to justify an individual's actions.CrossRefGoogle Scholar See the judgment of LJ Brooke in Re A (Children) (Conjoined Twins: Surgical Separation) [2001] Fam 148, who held that the separation of the conjoined twins and resultant death of one twin would be justified as distinct from excused. Brooke LJ's judgment is not, however, a statement of the ratio decidendi of the case, as all judges in the Court of Appeal used different justifications for ultimately deciding that the twins should be separated.

16. See McAuley, F and McCutcheon, JP Criminal Liability: A Grammar (Dublin: Round Hall Sweet & Maxwell, 2000) pp 779801.Google Scholar

17. United States v Holmes (1842) 26 Fed Cas 360.

18. Public Committee against Torture in Israel v Israel HC 5100/94 (Israel 1999).

19. J Bybee ‘Memorandum for A. Gonzales … [Re:] Standards for conduct for interrogation under 18 USC 2340-2340A’, US Department of Justice, Office of Legal Counsel (1 August 2002).

20. See Mavronicola, NWhat is an “absolute right?” Deciphering absoluteness in the context of Article 3 of the European Convention of Human Rights’ (2012) 12(4) Hum Rts L Rev 723;Google Scholar Gross, OAre torture warrants warranted?’ (2004) 88 Minn L Rev 1481 at 1497–1500. Gross' piece is a response to Alan Dershowitz's torture warrants proposal.Google Scholar See Dershowitz, ATortured reasoning’ in Levinson, S (ed) Torture: A Collection (New York: Oxford University Press, 2004) p 257.Google Scholar

21. Gross, above n 20.

22. See text to n 130 below for a discussion of how ‘time compression theory’ is challenging liberal democracy's ability to react expeditiously to problems facing the state.

23. See eg Dyzenhaus, DSchmitt v Dicey: are states of emergency inside or outside the legal order?’ (2006) 27 Cardozo L Rev 2005.Google Scholar

24. Rossiter, above n 7, p 12.

25. Agamben, G State of Exception (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2005) pp 2930.Google Scholar

26. Ibid.

27. This can cause increased popular support for a strong response as a result of a ‘rally around the flag’ effect. See Russett, B Controlling the Sword: The Democratic Governance of National Security (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1990) p 34.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

28. See eg Krebs, RR and Jackson, PTTwisting tongues and twisting arms: the power of political rhetoric’ (2007) 13 Eur J Int'l Relations 25;Google Scholar Kahnamen, D and Tversky, AProspect theory: an analysis of decision under risk’ (1979) 47(2) Econometrica 263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

29. Ibid; Gross, O and Ní Aoláin, FThe rhetoric of war: words, conflict and categorization post-9/11’ (2014) 24 (2) Cornell J L & Pub Pol'y, Minnesota Legal Studies Research Paper no 14–47′ available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2530789 (accessed 23 February 2015) at 5–7.Google Scholar

30. Montesquieu, C The Spirit of Laws, tr T Nugent (New York: Cosimo, 2011; first published 1750);Google Scholar Locke, J Second Treatise of Government, ed MacPherson, CB (Philadelphia, PA: Hackett, 1980; first published 1689) pp 8488;Google Scholar E Barendt ‘Separation of powers and constitutional government’ [1995] Pub L 599 at 601.

31. Barendt, for example, notes Locke's endorsing of Parliament's need for a permanent body to enforce laws it had created, as Parliament often did not sit once it had passed laws. See Barendt, above n 30, at 602.

32. Locke, above n 31, pp 84-88.

33. Tushnet, above n 7, at 2679.

34. De Londras, and Davis, above n 6, at 34–37 (per de Londras).

35. Kavanagh, ADefending deference in public law and constitutional theory’ (2010) 126(2) Law Q Rev 222 at 223.Google Scholar

36. See eg F Klug ‘Judicial deference under the Human Rights Act 1998’ [2003] Eur Hum Rts L Rev 125 at 125–126; Daly, P A Theory of Deference in Administrative Law (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2012) ch 1CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

37. CCSU v Minister for Civil Service [1985] AC 374, 412 (Lord Diplock).

38. Issacharoff, SPolitical safeguards in democracies at war29 Oxford J Legal Stud 189 at 204. The defeat in Parliament of the UK government's motion to militarily intervene in Syria's civil war on 29 August 2013 corroborates Brown's assertion on this point.CrossRefGoogle ScholarSee Watt, N and Hopkins, NCameron forced to rule out British attack on Syria after MPs reject motionThe Guardian 29 August 2013, available at http://www.theguardian.com/world/2013/aug/29/cameron-british-attack-syria-mps Google Scholar (accessed 3 April 2014). One year later, in September 2014, the UK Parliament passed a government-backed proposal, authorising air strikes against targets of the so-called ‘Islamic State’ (IS) operating in parts of Iraq. See Hansard HC Deb, vol 585, cols 1255–1360, 26 September 2014.

39. This can be seen by the decline in the use of prerogative powers by the UK government in favour of statutorily conferred powers that attract democratic legitimacy. See Elliott, M, Beatson, J and Matthews, M Beatson, Matthews and Elliott's Administrative Law Text and Materials (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 4th edn, 2011) pp 116123.Google Scholar

40. De Londras, and Davis, above n 6, at 27.

41. International Transport Roth GmbH v Secretary of State for the Home Department [2003] QB 728 at [87] Laws; de Londras and Davis, above n 6, at 27.

42. Moravcsik, AIn defence of the democratic deficit’ (2002) 40(4) J Common Market Stud 603 at 613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

43. The decline of Parliament’ (1963) 34(3) Pol Q 233 at 233.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

44. See text to n 130 below.

45. See Scheuerman, WEConstitutionalism in an age of speed’ (2002) 19 Const Comment 353.Google Scholar

46. For a discussion on the evolution of the state of emergency and the corresponding reduction in the use of martial law, see Neocleous, MFrom martial law to the war on terror’ (2007) 10 New Crim L Rev 489.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

47. Ibid.

48. Rossiter, above n 7, pp 117–127.

49. Ibid.

50. Ibid, p 41.

51. Indeed, it was the primary catalyst for Hitler's ascension. See Rossiter, ibid, pp 33-60; Kennedy, E Constitutional Failure: Carl Schmitt in Weimar (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2004) ch 6;Google Scholar Dyzenhaus, D Legality and Legitimacy: Carl Schmitt, Hans Kelsen and Hermann Heller in Weimar (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1997) pp 3237 Google Scholar; Agamben, above n 26, pp 14–16.

52. BA Meyler ‘Economic emergency and the rule of law’ (2006) Cornell Law Faculty Publications, Paper 68, available at http://scholarship.law.cornell.edu/lsrp_papers/68 (accessed 17 May 2011) at 1.

53. Scheuerman, above n 3, at 1871.See also Roots, RIGovernment by permanent emergency: the forgotten history of the New Deal constitution’ (1999-2000) 33 Suffolk U L Rev 259 at 260–261. A transcript of Roosevelt's speech may be found at http://www.bartleby.com/124/pres49.html Google Scholar (accessed 29 June 2011). See para 22 for the aforementioned quote.

54. Roots, above n 53, at 262. According to Belknap, the Trading with the Enemy Act was a First World War statute that had never been repealed. Belknap, MRThe New Deal and the emergency powers doctrine’ (1983-1984) 62(1) Tex L Rev 67 at 73Google Scholar.

55. US Senate Special Committee on the Termination of the National Emergency (Church–Mathias Committee) ‘Report of the Special Committee on the Termination of the National Emergency’ (19 November 1973) at 4.

56. Moyer, RC and Lamy, REToo big to fail: rationale, consequences and alternatives’ (1992) 27(3) Bus Econ 19 at 20.Google Scholar

57. Ibid.

58. M Labonte ‘Systemically important or “too big to fail” financial institutions’ Congressional Research Service (30 July 2013) CRS 7-5700, at 1.

59. Ibid; Belknap, above n 55, at 68.

60. Church–Mathias Committee, above n 56, at 93–549, II.

61. HC Relyea ‘National emergency powers’ Congressional Research Service (GOV, updated 30 August 2007) at 98–505.

62. ‘Foreword’ in Church–Mathias Committee, above n 56.

63. Treaty on Stability, Coordination and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union (Fiscal Compact Treaty; FCT), entered into force 1 January 2013.

64. Article 122(2) TFEU.

65. Anderson, DShielding the compass’ (2013) 3 Eur Hum Rts L R 233 at 243.Google Scholar

66. ‘Richard B. Cheney delivers remarks to Republican Governors Association’ FDCH Political Transcripts (25 October 2001).

67. Bruce Ackerman, for example, describes Roosevelt's New Deal as a constitutional moment in the US. See Ackerman, B We the People: Volume 1: Foundations (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1993) p 289.Google Scholar

68. M Kelly ‘Whatever happened to Ireland? Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper Series, no 7811 at 15, available at www.cepr.org/pubs/dps/DP7811.asp (accessed 5 August 2013) at 15.

69. Ibid. The institutions to be protected by the guarantee were Allied Irish Bank (AIB), Anglo Irish Bank, Bank of Ireland, the Educational Business Society (EBS), Irish Life and Permanent TSB, and Irish Nationwide Building Society. Postbank Ireland Ltd was also included at a later date. See Department of Finance ‘List of covered institutions’ (6 November 2008), available at http://www.centralbank.ie/regulation/industry-sectors/credit-institutions/Documents/List%20of%20covered%20institutions.pdf(accessed 21 May 2014).

70. Honohan, PPolicy paper: resolving Ireland's banking crisis’ (2009) 40(2) Econ & Soc Rev 207 at 221.Google Scholar

71. Commission of Investigation into the Banking Sector in Ireland ‘Misjudging risk: causes of the systemic banking crisis in Ireland’ (March 2011) at ix, available at http://www.bankinginquiry.gov.ie/Documents/Misjuding%20Risk%20-%20Causes%20of%20the%20Systemic%20Banking%20Crisis%20in%20Ireland.pdf (accessed 12 August 2014).

72. Becht, M, Bolton, P and Röell, AWhy bank governance is different’ (2011) 27(3) Oxford Rev Econ Pol'y 437 at 442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

73. Written answer from Minister for Finance Michael Noonan TD to Joanna Tuffy TD763(2) Dáíl Debs, col 65, 26 April 2012;Google Scholar Reilly, GAfter 4 years and €64.1 billion, bank guarantee is finally scrappedThe Journal.ie 29 March 2013, available at http://businessetc.thejournal.ie/ireland-bank-guarantee-officially-ends-850021-Mar2013/ (accessed 10 August 2013). For further discussion on this issue, see text to n 94 below.Google Scholar

74. National Treasury Management Agency Annual Report and Accounts for the Year Ended 31 December 2010 (21 July 2011), available at http://www.ntma.ie/download/publications/NTMA_Annual_Report_2010_English.pdf (accessed 15 December 2014) p 8.

75. See ‘EU/IMF programme of financial support for Ireland’ (16 December 2010), available at (http://www.finance.gov.ie/documents/publications/reports/2011/euimfrevised.pdf (accessed 12 August 2013).

76. Collins, SPresident signs Bill on banks into lawIrish Times Dublin, 22 December 2010.Google Scholar

77. Part 2 (Direction Orders) and Part 3 (Special Management) CISA 2010.

78. Rabbitte, P, Dáíl Debs, vol 725, no 2 (15 December 2010).Google Scholar

79. J Burton, ibid.

80. N O'Keeffe, ibid.

81. Collins, above n 77.

82. B Lenihan, Dáil Debs, above n 79.

83. Lenihan, ibid. See also statement of Minister of State Martin Manseragh during the course of the debate, ibid.

84. 219 (11) Sen Debs (18 December 2012).

85. Directive 2014/59/EU of the European Parliament and of the Council of 15 May 2014.

86. See text to n 53 above.

87. International Transport Rother GmbH (n 42); Sinnott v Minister for Education [2001] 2 IR 545, 710 (Hardiman J). The role of the judiciary in protecting and vindicating socio-economic rights is beyond the scope of this paper. The claims made in this paper therefore are exclusively reserved to the relationship between the executive and the legislature.

88. Masterman, R and Murray, C Exploring Constitutional and Administrative Law (Harlow: Pearson, 2013) pp 240241.Google Scholar

89. Posner, E and Vermeule, ACrisis governance in the administrative state: 9/11 and the financial meltdown of 2008’ (2009) 76 U Chi L Rev 1613 at 1618.Google Scholar

90. See Fama, EFEfficient capital markets: a review of theory and empirical work’ (1970) 25 (2) J Fin 383. There are severe limitations to this theory, with behavioural economists arguing that market prices are not wholly based upon the rational evaluation of information, but that irrationality and emotion affects prices too.CrossRefGoogle Scholar See Malkiel, BGThe efficient market hypothesis and its critics’ (2003) 17(1) J Econ Perspectives 59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

91. See text to n 89 above.

92. Fama, above n 90.

93. 662 (1) Dáil Debs (30 September 2008) para 35.

94. Per Minister for Finance, above n 94.

95. 662(2) Dáil Debs (1 October 2008) para 447.

96. See above n 94.

97. Morgan Kelly appeared on Irish current affairs show ‘Prime Time’ on 30 September 2008, arguing that Irish banks were facing an insolvency, not a liquidity, crisis. A video is available at http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=11CCxv2ueiQ (accessed 4 April 2014).

98. Kelly, MHow the corner stones of our economy could go into rapid freefallThe Irish Times 28 December 2006;Google Scholar Kelly, MBanking on very shaky foundationsThe Irish Times 7 September 2007;Google Scholar M Kelly ‘On the likely extent of falls in Irish house prices’ UCD Centre for Economic Research Working Paper Series WP07/01 (February 2007). Philip Ingram, an analyst at Merrill Lynch, produced a report outlining serious problems with Ireland's banking system in March 2008; however, the report was subsequently redacted from public scrutiny. See Lewis, MWhen Irish eyes are cryingVanity Fair March 2011 Google Scholar; O'Carroll, LIreland bank collapse: the strange case of the disappearing Merrill Lynch research noteThe Guardian Online Edition 2 February 2011 Google Scholar, available at http://www.theguardian.com/business/ireland-business-blog-with-lisa-ocarroll/2011/feb/02/ireland-merrill-lynch-research-note-irish-banks (accessed 4 April 2014).

99. See text to n 17.

100. Ibid. To give another example, the US Patriot Act was passed by the House of Representatives by a margin of 357 to 66, while it passed the Senate by a resounding 99 to 1. ‘HR 3162 – USA Patriot Act of 2001 – voting record’, available at https://votesmart.org/bill/votes/8289#.U1psn1VdXAk (accessed 1 April 2014). As time wears on and the emergency recedes, the legislature and the judiciary may push back against executive supremacy and defer less. See de Londras and Davis (above n 6), with de Londras and Davis each respectively arguing that the judiciary or the legislature push back against the executive over time. Bruce Ackerman bases his ‘super-majoritarian legislative escalator’ for the renewal of a state of emergency in a presidential system on the assumption that increasing numbers of the legislator will push back over time. See Ackerman, BThe emergency constitution’ (2004) 113 Yale L J 1029 CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

101. De Londras, and Davis, above n 6; Ackerman, above n 101.

102. Simon, J Governing through Crime (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2007) ch 9.Google Scholar

103. See text to n 101.

104. Krugman, PHow the case for austerity crumbledThe New York Review of Books 6 June 2013. The EU's desire to see Eurozone Member States balance their budgets was codified in the FCT. See text to n 64.Google Scholar

105. See Fuller, LThe forms and limits of adjudication’ (1978) 92(2) Harv L Rev 353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

106. JA King ‘The pervasiveness of polycentricity’ [2008] Pub L 101 at 101–102;Fuller, above n 105, at 395.

107. ‘The choice of these [economic policies] depends upon theoretical and speculative beliefs as well as upon a wealth of concrete information, and all of this mixed with judgment and plain hunch, not to mention in actual cases prejudice and self-interest.’ Rawls, JThe justification of civil disobedience’ in Edmundson, WA (ed) The Duty to Obey the Law: Selected Philosophical Readings (Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield, 1999) pp 49, 57.Google Scholar

108. O'Connell, PLet them eat cake: socio-economic rights in an age of austerity’ in Nolan, A, O'Connell, R and Harvey, C (eds) Human Rights and Public Finance (Oxford: Hart Publishng, 2013) pp 59, 69.Google Scholar

109. See generally Fuller, LThe forms and limits of adjudication’ (1978) 92(2) Harv L Rev 353.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

110. Waldron, J Law and Disagreement (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1999) p 15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

111. Scheuerman, WE Liberal Democracy and the Social Acceleration of Time (Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press, 2004) p 39.Google Scholar

112. Thus Waldron argues that the basic argument for the legitimacy of an enacted statute is that all the alternatives had the opportunity to put their case and failed to win majority support, thus presupposing the possibility of individuals involved in the debate changing their minds. Waldron, above n 113, p 27.

113. Moravcsik, above n 43.

114. Fuller, above n 110, at 399–402.

115. Ibid.

116. Follesdal, A and Hix, SWhy there is a democratic deficit in the EU: a response to Majone and Moravcsik’ (2006) 44(3) J Common Market Stud 533 at 534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

117. Ibid, at 535.

118. Moravcsik, above n 43.

119. Ibid, at 615.

120. Chiti, E and Teixeira, PGThe constitutional implications of the European responses to the financial and public debt crisis’ (2013) 50 Common Market L Rev 683 at 690–692.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

121. Waldron, JPrinciples of legislation’ in Bauman, RW and Kahana, T (eds) The Least Examined Branch: the Role of Legislatures in the Constitutional State (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2006) pp 15, 27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

122. Tamanaha, B On the Rule of Law: History, Politics, Theory (Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 2004) p 43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

123. Ibid.

124. See Dyzenhaus, D“Now the machine runs itself”: Carl Schmitt on Hobbes and Kelsen’ (1994) 16 Cardozo L Rev 1.Google Scholar

125. Dyzenhaus, above n 52, pp 56-58.

126. Dyzenhaus, above n 125.

127. Raz, J The Authority of Law (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2nd edn, 2009) p 214;Google Scholar P Craig ‘Formal and substantive conceptions of the rule of law: an analytical framework’ [1997] Pub L 467 at 469.

128. Scheuerman, above n 3, at 1887.

129. Scheuerman, above n 46, at 355; Agnew, JThe new global economy: time–space compression, geopolitics, and global uneven development’ (2001) 7(2) J World-Systems Res 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

130. Ibid.

131. See McKie, RSwine flu H1N1: evolution of a virusThe Observer 26 April 2009.Google Scholar

132. In April 1964, speaking on the justification of the continued existence of a state of emergency dating from the Second World War in Ireland, then Taoiseach Seán Lemass stated that: ‘In view of the international situation and the speed of delivery and the destructive power of the weapons of war now available, the Government would consider it unwise to move the terminating resolution and so deprive themselves – or any future Government which foresaw an imminent war – of the protection of Article 28.3.3° [Ireland's constitutional emergency powers provision]’. See 209 Dáil Debs, cols 2–4, 21 April 1964; See also Greene, AThe historical evolution of Article 28.3.3° of the Irish Constitution’ (2012) 47(1) Irish Jurist 117 at 139.Google Scholar

133. Text to n 56 above.