Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T08:58:36.677Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Implications of present-biased preferences on inheritance taxes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  13 May 2022

Monisankar Bishnu
Affiliation:
Economics and Planning Unit, Indian Statistical Institute - Delhi Centre, 7 SJS Sansanwal Marg, New Delhi - 110016, India
Cagri S. Kumru
Affiliation:
Research School of Economics, Australian National University, Canberra, Australia, ACT, 2601
Arm Nakornthab*
Affiliation:
Faculty of Economics, Khon Kaen University, Khon Kaen, 40002, Thailand
*
*Corresponding author. Email: armeros@kku.ac.th

Abstract

We model an economy where present biased preferences affect the bequest leaving decisions. Using Bequest in the Utility (BIU) setup, we show that the optimal inheritance tax rate under present bias can be derived in terms of estimable sufficient statistics. This optimal tax rate decreases with the level of temptation and a subsidy can be optimal at some level of bequests received. We then use the Barro-Becker Dynastic (BBD) setup to derive the expression for the optimal inheritance tax rates. We observe that if the agents internalize the taxes on the amount of bequest that they leave (sensitive generations), present bias and optimal tax rates are negatively related as in BIU, that is, providing an incentive by extending subsidies or lowering taxes is recommended to subside the effects of temptation. However, if agents ignore the taxes to be paid by their descendants on the inheritance left (ignorant generations), optimal tax rates increase with the level of present bias. This is because the present bias reduces the tax base and the rationale of providing incentives does not work anymore. Our calibration exercise supports all these theoretical findings.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

The authors are grateful to the editor, an associate editor, and two anonymous referees for their excellent comments and suggestions. We also thank Joydeep Bhattacharya, Simon Grant, Rabee Tourky, and Thomas Piketty for their very helpful inputs. An earlier version of this paper was circulated under the title “Optimal inheritance tax under temptation”.

References

Alonso-Carrera, J. and Bouche, S. (2019) Capital accumulation when consumers are tempted by others’ consumption experience. Oxford Economic Papers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ameriks, J., Caplin, A., Leahy, J. and Tyler, T. (2007) Measuring self-control problems. American Economic Review 97(3), 966972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersen, T. M. and Bhattacharya, J. (2011) On myopia as rationale for social security. Economic Theory 47(1), 135158.10.1007/s00199-010-0528-zCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bishnu, M. and Wang, M. (2013) Voting under temptation. Economics Letters 118(3), 419423.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bucciol, A. (2012) Measuring self-control problems: A structural estimation. Journal of the European Economic Association 10(5), 10841115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamley, C. (1986) Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica 54(3), 607622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conesa, J. C., Kitao, S. and Krueger, D. (2009) Taxing capital? Not a bad idea after all! American Economic Review 99(1), 2548.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cremer, H. and Pestieau, P. (2006) Wealth transfer taxation: A survey of the theoretical literature. Handbook of the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity 2(2), 11071134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeJong, D. N. and Ripoll, M. (2007) Do self-control preferences help explain the puzzling behavior of asset prices? Journal of Monetary Economics 54(4), 10351050.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2006.03.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farhi, E. and Werning, I. (2010) Progressive estate taxation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 125(2), 635673.10.1162/qjec.2010.125.2.635CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farhi, E. and Werning, I. (2014) Bequest taxations and r − g. Mimeo: MIT/Harvard.Google Scholar
Gul, F. and Pesendorfer, W. (2004) Self control and theory of consumption. Econometrica 72, 119158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gul, F. and Pesendorfer, W. (2007) Harmful addiction. The Review of Economic Studies 74(1), 147172.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, K. X. D., Liu, Z. and Zhu, J. Q. (2015) Temptation and self-control: Some evidence and applications. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 47, 581615.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imrohoroglu, A., Imrohoroglu, S. and Joines, D. H. (2003) Time inconsistent preferences and social security. Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 745784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, K. (1985) Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics 28(1), 5983.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kopczuk, W. and Lupton, J. P. (2007) To leave or not to leave: The distribution of bequest motives. The Review of Economic Studies 74(1), 207235.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kovacks, A., Low, H. and Moran, P. (2021) Estimating temptation and commitment over the life-cycle. International Economic Review 62(1), 101139.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kovacs, A., Low, H. and Moran, P. (2019) Estimating temptation and commitment over the life-cycle. Working Paper.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, P. L., Kuruscu, B. and Smith, A. A. (2010) Temptation and taxation. Econometrica 78(6), 20632084.Google Scholar
Kumru, C. S. and Thanopoulos, A. (2011) Social security reform with self-control preferences. Journal of Public Economics 95(7–8), 886899.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2011.03.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kumru, C. S. and Thanopoulos, A. C. (2008) Social security and self-control preferences. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32(3), 757778.10.1016/j.jedc.2007.02.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laibson, D. (1997) Hyperbolic discounting and golden eggs. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112(2), 443477.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lockwood, B. and Taubinsky, D. (2017) Regressive sin taxes. NBER Working Paper 23085.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lockwood, L. M. (2018) Incidental bequests and the choice to self-insure late-life risks. American Economic Review 108(9), 25132550.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Moser, C. and Olea de Souza e Silva, P. O. (2019) Optimal paternalistic savings policies. Columbia Business School Research Paper, 17-51 .10.21034/iwp.17CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Donoghue, T. and Rabin, M. (2006) Optimal sin taxes. Journal of Public Economics 90, 18251849.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pavoni, N. and Yazici, H. (2016) Intergenerational disagreement and optimal taxation of parental transfers. The Review of Economic Studies 84(3), 12641305.Google Scholar
Pavoni, N. and Yazici, H. (2017) Optimal life-cycle capital taxation under self-control problems. The Economic Journal 127(602), 11881216.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, T. (2011) On the long-run evolution of inheritance: France 1820 $-$ 2050. Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(3), 10711131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, T. (2018) Capital in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, T. and Saez, E. (2013) A theory of optimal inheritance taxation. Econometrica 81(5), 18511886.Google Scholar
Saez, E. and Stantcheva, S. (2018) A simpler theory of optimal capital taxation. Journal of Public Economics 162(6), 120142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Straub, L. and Werning, I. (2020) Positive long-run capital taxation: Chamley-judd revisited. American Economic Review 110(1), 86119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. and Shefrin, H. (02 1981) An economic theory of self-control. Journal of Political Economy 89(2), 392406. doi: 10.1086/260971.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yu, P. C. (2021) Optimal retirement policies with Present-Biased agents. Journal of the European Economic Association 19(4), 20852130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar