Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-wq2xx Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-18T02:51:01.569Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Inequality over the business cycle: the role of distributive shocks

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 November 2021

Marius Clemens*
Affiliation:
DIW Berlin, Mohrenstr. 58, 10117 Berlin
Ulrich Eydam
Affiliation:
University of Potsdam, August-Bebel-Str. 89, 14482 Potsdam
Maik Heinemann
Affiliation:
University of Potsdam, August-Bebel-Str. 89, 14482 Potsdam
*
*Corresponding author: Marius Clemens. Email: mclemens@diw.de

Abstract

This paper examines how wealth and income inequality dynamics are related to fluctuations in the functional income distribution over the business cycle. In a panel estimation for OECD countries between 1970 and 2016, although inequality is, on average countercyclical and significantly associated with the capital share, one-third of the countries display a pro- or noncyclical relationship. To analyze the observed pattern, we incorporate distributive shocks into an RBC model, where agents are ex ante heterogeneous with respect to wealth and ability. We find that whether wealth and income inequality behave countercyclically or not depends on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution and the persistence of shocks. We match the model to quarterly US data using Bayesian techniques. The parameter estimates point toward a non-monotonic relationship between productivity and inequality fluctuations. On impact, inequality increases in response to TFP shocks but subsequently declines. Furthermore, TFP shocks explain 17% of inequality fluctuations.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2021. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, D. (2003) Labor- and capital-augmenting technical change. Journal of the European Economic Association 1(1), 137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ahn, S., Kaplan, G., Moll, B., Winberry, T. and Wolf, C. (2017) When inequality matters for macro and macro matters for inequality. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2017, vol. 32, pp. 1–75, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc, NBER Chapters.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvaredo, F., Chancel, L., Piketty, T., Saez, E. and Zucman, G. (2017) Global inequality dynamics: New findings from WID.world. American Economic Review 107(5), 404409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B. (2009) Factor shares: The principal problem of political economy? Oxford Review of Economic Policy 25(1), 316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. J. (2000) Inequality and growth in a panel of countries, Journal of Economic Growth 5(1), 532.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartscher, A. K., Kuhn, M., Schularick, M. and Steins, U. (2020) Modigliani meets Minsky: Inequality, debt, and financial fragility in America, 1950–2016, CESifo Working Paper Series 8273, CESifo.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayer, C., Born, B. and Luetticke, R. (2020) Shocks, frictions, and inequality in US business cycles, CEPR Discussion Papers 14364, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cantore, C., Ferroni, F. and Leon-Ledesma, M. A. (2018) The missing link: Monetary policy and the labor share, Discussion Papers 1829, Centre for Macroeconomics (CFM).Google Scholar
Caselli, F. and Ventura, J. (2000) A representative consumer theory of distribution. American Economic Review 90(4), 909926.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Challe, E., Matheron, J., Ragot, X. and Rubio-Ramirez, J. F. (2017) Precautionary saving and aggregate demand, Quantitative Economics 8(2), 435478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Charpe, M., Brdiji, S. and McAdam, P. (2020) Labor share and growth in the long run. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 24(7), 17201757.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chatterjee, S. (1994) Transitional dynamics and the distribution of wealth in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economics 54(1), 97119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Debortoli, D. and Galí, J. (2017) Monetary policy with heterogeneous agents: Insights from TANK models, Economics Working Papers 1686, Department of Economics and Business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra.Google Scholar
Diaz-Gimenez, J., Quadrini, V. and Rios-Rull, J.-V. (1997) Dimensions of inequality: facts on the U.S. distributions of earnings, income, and wealth. Quarterly Review 21, 321.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dimelis, S. and Livada, A. (1999) Inequality and business cycles in the U.S. and European Union countries. International Advances in Economic Research 5(3), 321338.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feenstra, R. C., Inklaar, R. and Timmer, M. P. (2015) The next generation of the Penn World Table, American Economic Review 105(10), 31503182.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galí, J., López-Salido, J. D. and Vallés, J. (2007) Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 5(1), 227270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garcia-Milà, T., Marcet, A. and Ventura, E. (2010) Supply side interventions and redistribution, Economic Journal 120(543), 105130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Growiec, J., McAdam, P. and Mućk, J. (2018) Endogenous labor share cycles: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 87(C), 7493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iacoviello, M. (2005) House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. American Economic Review 95(3), 739764.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, G., Moll, B. and Violante, G. L. (2018) Monetary policy according to HANK. American Economic Review 108(3), 697743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, G. and Violante, G. L. (2018) Microeconomic heterogeneity and macroeconomic shocks, Journal of Economic Perspectives 32(3), 167194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, I.-M. and Loungani, P. (1992) The role of energy in business cycle models. Journal of Monetary Economics 29(2), 173189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuhn, M., Schularick, M. and Steins, U. (2019) Wealth and income inequality in America, 1949–2016. Journal of Political Economy, forthcoming.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lansing, K. J. (2015) Asset pricing with concentrated ownership of capital and distribution shocks, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7(4), 67103.Google Scholar
Leduc, S. and Sill, K. (2007) Monetary policy, oil shocks, and TFP: Accounting for the decline in US volatility. Review of Economic Dynamics 10(4), 595614.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
List, J. A. and Gallet, C. A. (1999) The Kuznets curve: What happens after the inverted-U? Review of Development Economics 3(2), 200206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maliar, L. and Maliar, S. (2001) Heterogeneity in capital and skills in a neoclassical stochastic growth model, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 25(5), 13671397.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maliar, L., Maliar, S. and Mora, J. (2005) Income and wealth distributions along the business cycle: Implications from the neoclassical growth model, Topics in Macroeconomics 5(1).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mangin, S. and Sedláček, P. (2018) Unemployment and the labor share. Journal of Monetary Economics 94(C), 4159.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montoro, C. (2012) Oil shocks and optimal monetary policy, Macroeconomic Dynamics 16(2), 240277.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moro, A. (2012) Biased technical change, intermediate goods, and total factor productivity, Macroeconomic Dynamics 16(2), 184203.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pothier, D. and Puy, D. (2014) Demand composition and income distribution. IMF Working Papers 14/224, International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García-Peñalosa, C. and Turnovsky, S. J. (2010) Income inequality, mobility, and the accumulation of capital. Macroeconomic Dynamics 19(6), 13321357.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ragot, X. and Grand, F. L. (2017) Optimal fiscal policy with heterogeneous agents and aggregate shocks. 2017 Meeting Papers 969, Society for Economic Dynamics.Google Scholar
Ríos-Rull, J.-V. and Santaeulàlia-Llopis, R. (2010) Redistributive shocks and productivity shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics 57(8), 931948.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, A. and Segal, D. (2015) The effects of economic growth on income inequality in the US. Journal of Macroeconomics 45, 258273.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seok, B. H. and You, H. M. (2019) Explaining the evolution of the U.S. housing market. Macroeconomic Dynamics 23(2), 568589.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smets, F. and Wouters, R. (2007) Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: A Bayesian DSGE approach. American Economic Review 97(3), 586606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, A. (2004) Labor’s share fluctuations, biased technical change, and the business cycle. Review of Economic Dynamics 7(4), 916931.CrossRefGoogle Scholar