Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-nr4z6 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-02T14:24:40.638Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Central bank credibility and inflation expectations: a microfounded forecasting approach

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 June 2022

João Victor Issler*
Affiliation:
Brazilian School of Economics and Finance FGV EPGE, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil
Ana Flávia Soares
Affiliation:
Brazilian School of Economics and Finance FGV EPGE, Rio de Janeiro, Brazil
*
*Corresponding author. Email: joao.issler@fgv.br

Abstract

Credibility is elusive, but Blinder [(2000) American Economic Review 90, 1421–1431.] generated a consensus in the literature by arguing that “A central bank is credible if people believe it will do what it says.” To implement this idea, we first measure people’s beliefs by using survey data on inflation’s expectations. Second, we compare beliefs with explicit (or tacit) targets, taking into account the uncertainty in our estimate of beliefs (asymptotic 95% robust confidence intervals). Whenever the target falls into this interval we consider the central bank credible. We consider it not credible otherwise. We apply our approach to study the credibility of the Brazilian Central Bank (BCB) by using a world-class database—the Focus Survey of forecasts. Using monthly data from January 2007 until April 2017, we estimate people’s beliefs of inflation 12 months ahead, coupled with a robust estimate of its asymptotic 95% confidence interval. Results show that the BCB was credible 65% of the time, with the exception of a few months in the beginning of 2007 and during the interval between mid-2013 throughout mid-2016.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

*

We thank the comments and suggestions given by the Editor, William A. Barnett, an anonymous Associate Editor, two anonymous referees, Marco Bonomo, Wagner Gaglianone, Felipe Iachan, Marcelo Moreira, Cezar Santos, and participants of the SNDE Symposium held in Tokyo, Japan, the LUBRAMACRO conference held in Aveiro, Portugal, and the IAAE meeting held in Montreal, Canada. Issler thanks the Conselho Nacional de Desenvolvimento Científico e Tecnológico—CNPq, FAPERJ, INCT, and FGV for financial support on different grants. This study was financed in part by the Coordenação de Aperfeiçoamento de Pessoal de Nível Superior—Brasil (CAPES)—Finance Code 001.

References

Alesina, A. (1988) Macroeconomics and politics. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 3, 1352.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A. and Summers, L. H. (1993) Central bank independence and macroeconomic performance: Some comparative evidence. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 25(2), 151162.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andrews, D. W. (1991) Heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix estimation. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 59(3), 817858.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartlett, M. S. (1950) Periodogram analysis and continuous spectra. Biometrika 1(2), 116.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, J. and Granger, C. (1969) The combination of forecasts. Operations Research Quarterly 20, 309325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernanke, B. S. and Mishkin, F. S. (1997). Inflation targeting: A new framework for monetary policy? Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blinder, A. (2000) Central bank credibility: Why do we care? How do we build it. American Economic Review 90(5), 14211431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bomfim, A. N. and Rudebusch, G. D. (2000) Opportunistic and deliberate disinflation under imperfect credibility. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 32(4), 707721.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bordo, M. D. and Siklos, P. L. (2015) Central bank credibility before and after the crisis. Open Economies Review, 127.Google Scholar
Canzoneri, M. B. (1985) Monetary policy games and the role of private information. The American Economic Review 75(5), 10561070.Google Scholar
Capistrán, C. and Ramos-Francia, M. (2010) Does inflation targeting affect the dispersion of inflation expectations? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42(1), 113134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carriere-Swallow, Y., Gruss, B., Magud, N. E., Valencia, F. et al. (2016). Monetary policy credibility and exchange rate pass-through. Technical report, International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carvalho, F. and Minella, A. (2012) Survey forecasts in Brazil: A prismatic assessment of epidemiology, performance, and determinants. Journal of International Money and Finance 31(6), 13711391.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cecchetti, S. G. and Krause, S. (2002) Central bank structure, policy efficiency, and macroeconomic performance: Exploring empirical relationships. Review-Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis 84(4), 4760.Google Scholar
Christoffersen, P. F. and Diebold, F. X. (1997) Optimal prediction under asymmetric loss. Econometric Theory 13(6), 808817.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cukierman, A. (2008) Central bank independence and monetary policymaking institutions—Past, present and future. European Journal of Political Economy 24(4), 722736.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cukierman, A. and Meltzer, A. H. (1986) A theory of ambiguity, credibility, and inflation under discretion and asymmetric information. Econometrica 54(5), 10991128.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davies, A. and Lahiri, K. (1995) A new framework for analyzing survey forecasts using three-dimensional panel data. Journal of Econometrics 68(1), 205227.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Mendonça, H. F. and G. J., de Guimarães e Souza (2007) Credibilidade do regime de metas para inflaç ao no Brasil.Google Scholar
De Mendonça, H. F. and de Guimarães e Souza, G. J. (2009) Inflation targeting credibility and reputation: The consequences for the interest rate. Economic Modelling 26(6), 12281238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Demertzis, M., Marcellino, M. and Viegi, N. (2008). A credibility measure: Tracking us monetary developments, Technical report, CEPR Working Paper.Google Scholar
Demertzis, M., Marcellino, M., Viegi, N. et al. (2012) A credibility proxy: Tracking us monetary developments. The BE Journal of Macroeconomics 12(1), 136.Google Scholar
Dovern, J., Fritsche, U. and Slacalek, J. (2012) Disagreement among forecasters in g7 countries. Review of Economics and Statistics 94(4), 10811096.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Elliott, G., Komunjer, I. and Timmermann, A. (2008) Biases in macroeconomic forecasts: Irrationality or asymmetric loss? Journal of the European Economic Association 6(1), 122157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gaglianone, W. P., Giacomini, R., Issler, J. V. and Skreta, V. (2021) Incentive-driven inattention. Forthcoming in the Journal of Econometrics.Google Scholar
Gaglianone, W. P. and Issler, J. V. (2021) Microfounded Forecasting, Mimeo, FGV.Google Scholar
Gaglianone, W. P., Issler, J. V. and Matos, S. M. (2017) Applying a microfounded-forecasting approach to predict Brazilian inflation. Empirical Economics 53(1), 137163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Granger, C. W. (1999) Outline of forecast theory using generalized cost functions. Spanish Economic Review 1(2), 161173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grilli, V., Masciandaro, D. and Tabellini, G. (1991) Political and monetary institutions and public financial policies in the industrial countries. Economic Policy 6(13), 341392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guillén, D. and Garcia, M. (2014) Expectativas desagregadas, credibilidade do banco central e cadeias de markov. Revista Brasileira de Economia 68(2), 197223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, L. (1982) Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica 50(4), 10291054.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, L. P., Heaton, J. and Yaron, A. (1996) Finite-sample properties of some alternative gmm estimators. Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 14(3), 262280.Google Scholar
Hardouvelis, G. A. and Barnhart, S. W. (1989) The evolution of federal reserve credibility: 1978–1984. The Review of Economics and Statistics 71(3), 385393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Issler, J. and Lima, L. (2009) A panel data approach to economic forecasting: The bias-corrected average forecast. Journal of Econometrics 152(2), 153164.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ito, T. (1990) Foreign exchange rate expectations: Micro survey data. The American Economic Review 80(3), 434449.Google Scholar
Kozicki, S. and Tinsley, P. A. (2012) Effective use of survey information in estimating the evolution of expected inflation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 44(1), 145169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kydland, F. E. and Prescott, E. C. (1977) Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. Journal of Political Economy 85(3), 473491.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lahiri, K., Peng, H. and Sheng, X. S. (2021) Measuring uncertainty of a combined forecast and some tests for forecaster heterogeneity, Advances in Econometrics, forthcoming Google Scholar
Levieuge, G., Lucotte, Y. and Ringuedé, S. (2016) Central bank credibility and the expectations channel: Evidence based on a new credibility index. National Bank of Poland Working Paper No. 209.Google Scholar
Lowenkron, A., Garcia, M. and et al. (2007) Monetary policy credibility and inflation risk premium: A model with application to Brazilian data. Textos para discussao , 543.Google Scholar
Lyziak, T. and Sheng, X. S. (2018) Disagreement in consumer inflation expectations. NBP Working Paper , 278.Google Scholar
Marins, J. and Vicente, J. (2017) Do the central bank actions reduce interest rate volatility? Economic Modelling 65(2), 129137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marques, A. (2013) Central bank of brazil’s market expectations system: A tool for monetary policy. Bank for International Settlements 36, 304324.Google Scholar
Newey, W. and West, K. (1987) A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55(3), 703708.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Newey, W. K. and West, K. D. (1994) Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. The Review of Economic Studies 61(4), 631653.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palm, F. C. and Zellner, A. (1992) To combine or not to combine? Issues of combining forecasts. Journal of Forecasting 11(8), 687701.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (1993) Designing institutions for monetary stability. In: Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy , volume 39, 5384. Elsevier.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reis, R. (2021) Losing the inflation anchor, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, forthcoming Google Scholar
Rogoff, K. (1985) The optimal degree of commitment to an intermediate monetary target. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 100(4), 11691189.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, L. E. (1993). The simplest test of inflation target credibility, Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Svensson, L. E. (2000). How should monetary policy be conducted in an era of price stability? Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, J. B. (1993) Discretion versus policy rules in practice. In: Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy , volume 39, pp. 195214. Elsevier.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vereda, L., Mamede, V., Karp, D. and Lerípio, R. (2017) Expectativas de inflação, metas implícitas e a credibilidade das autoridades monetárias Brasileiras. DIMAC Seminar n. 491.Google Scholar
Walsh, C. E. (1995) Optimal contracts for central bankers. The American Economic Review, 150167.Google Scholar
White, H. (1984). Asymptotic theory for econometricians. Technical report.Google Scholar
Supplementary material: PDF

Issler and Soares supplementary material

Issler and Soares supplementary material

Download Issler and Soares supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 283.6 KB