Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-jr42d Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-24T01:15:46.344Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

HEALTH INVESTMENT OVER THE LIFE-CYCLE

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 July 2017

Timothy J. Halliday
Affiliation:
University of Hawai'i, IZA and University of Hawai'i Economic Research Organization
Hui He*
Affiliation:
Shanghai University of Finance and Economics and International Monetary Fund
Lei Ning
Affiliation:
Shanghai University of Finance and Economics
Hao Zhang
Affiliation:
Renmin University of China
*
Address correspondence to: Hui He, Institute for Capacity Development, International Monetary Fund, 700 19th Street NW, Washington, DC 20431, USA; e-mail: hhe@imf.org.

Abstract

We quantify what drives the rise in medical expenditures over the life-cycle using a stochastic dynamic overlapping generations model of health investment. Three motives for health investment are considered. First, health delivers a flow of utility each period (the consumption motive). Second, better health enables people to allocate more time to productive or pleasurable activities (the investment motive). Third, better health improves survival prospects (the survival motive). We find that, overall, the consumption motive plays a dominant role, whereas the investment motive is more important than the consumption and survival motives until the forties. The survival motive is quantitatively less important when compared to the other two motives. We also conduct a series of counter-factual policy experiments to investigate how government policies impacting health insurance coverage, Social Security, and health care technological progress affect the behavior of medical expenditures, and social welfare.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2017 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Footnotes

We thank Carl Bonham, Michele Boldrin, Toni Braun, Kaiji Chen, Sumner La Croix, Kevin Huang, Selo Imrohoroglu, Sagiri Kitao, Nobu Kiyotaki, Dirk Krueger, Zheng Liu, Andy Mason, Makoto Nakajima, Michael Palumbo, Richard Rogerson, Richard Suen, Motohiro Yogo, Kai Zhao, seminar participants at the Chinese University of Hong Kong, the Federal Reserve Board, George Washington University, Hong Kong University of Science and Technology, Peking University, Shanghai University of Finance and Economics, University of Hawai'i at Mānoa, Utah State University, and conference participants at the 2009 Midwest Macroeconomics Meeting, 2009 QSPS Summer Workshop, 2009 Western Economic Association International (WEAI) Meeting, 15th International Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance in Sydney, 2010 Tsinghua Workshop in Macroeconomics, and 2010 SED Annual Meeting for helpful feedback. We thank Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde for providing us consumption data. Financial support from the College of Social Sciences at the University of Hawai'i at Manoa is gratefully acknowledged. Hui He thanks research support sponsored by Shanghai Pujiang Program (No. 2013140026) and the Program for Professor of Special Appointment (Eastern Scholar) at Shanghai Institutions of Higher Learning (No. 2013140034). Lei Ning thanks research support from the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (SUFE) (2017110133) and China Postdoctoral Science Foundation (Grant No. 2017M611515). Most of the work related to the paper was done when Hui He was a faculty member at Shanghai University of Finance and Economics (SHUFE). Therefore, the views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or IMF management.

References

REFERENCES

Attanasio, Orazio, Kitao, Sagiri and Violante, Giovanni L. (2010) Financing medicare: A general equilibrium analysis. In Demography and the Economy, pp. 333366. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Baker, Michael, Stabile, Mark and Deri, Catherine (2004) What do self-reported, objective, measures of health measure? Journal of Human Resources 39, 10671093.Google Scholar
Bloom, David E., Canning, David and Sevilla, J. (2005) Health and Economic Growth: Reconciling the Micro and Macro Evidence. Center on Democracy, Development and the Rule of Law working papers 42.Google Scholar
Bound, John (1991) Self-reported versus objective measures of health in retirement models. Journal of Human Resources 26, 106138.Google Scholar
Bullard, James and Feigenbaum, James (2007) A leisurely reading of the life-cycle consumption data. Journal of Monetary Economics 54, 23052320.Google Scholar
Cagetti, Marco and De Nardi, Mariacristina (2008) Wealth inequality: Data and models. Macroeconomic Dynamics 12, 285313.Google Scholar
Cagetti, Marco and De Nardi, Mariacristina (2009) Estate taxation, entrepreneurship, and wealth. American Economic Review 99, 85111.Google Scholar
Carroll, Christopher D. (1997) Buffer-stock saving and the life cycle/permanent income hypothesis. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 155.Google Scholar
Conesa, Juan Carlos, Kitao, Sagiri and Krueger, Dirk (2009) Taxing capital? Not a bad idea after all! American Economic Review 99, 2548.Google Scholar
De Nardi, Mariacristina, French, Eric and Jones, John Bailey (2010) Why Do the Elderly Save? The Role of Medical Expenses. Journal of Political Economy 118, 3975.Google Scholar
De Nardi, Mariacristina, French, Eric, Jones, John Bailey and Jeremy, McCauley (2015) Medical spending on the U.S. elderly. National Bureau of Economic Research, working paper 21270.Google Scholar
Deaton, Angus (1992) Understanding Consumption. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fehr, Hans, Kallweit, Manuel and Kindermann, Fabian (2013) Should pensions be progressive. European Economic Review 63, 94116.Google Scholar
Feng, Zhigang (2012). Macroeconomic consequences of alternative reforms to the health insurance system in the US. doi:10.2139/ssrn.2037058.Google Scholar
Fernandez-Villaverde, Jesus and Krueger, Dirk (2007) Consumption over the life cycle: Facts from consumer expenditure survey data. Review of Economics and Statistics 89, 552565.Google Scholar
Fernandez-Villaverde, Jesus and Krueger, Dirk (2011) Consumption and saving over the life cycle: How important are consumer durables? Macroeconomic Dynamics 15, 725770.Google Scholar
Finkelstein, Amy, Luttmer, Erzo F. P. and Notowidigdo, Matthew J. (2013) What good is wealth without health? The effect of health on the marginal utility of consumption. Journal of the European Economic Association 11, 221258.Google Scholar
Fonseca, Raquel, Pierrecarl, Michaud, Titus, Galama and Arie, Kapteyn (2009). On The Rise of Health Spending and Longevity. IZA discussion paper #4622.Google Scholar
French, Eric (2005) The effects of health, wealth, and wages on labour supply and retirement behaviour. Review of Economic Studies 72, 395427.Google Scholar
Gilleskie, Donna B. (1998) A dynamic stochastic model of medical care use and work absence. Econometrica 66, 145.Google Scholar
Gourinchas, Pierre-olivier and Parker, Jonathan A. (2002) Consumption over the life-cycle. Econometrica 70, 4789.Google Scholar
Grossman, Michael (1972) On the concept of health capital and the demand for health. Journal of Political Economy 80, 223–55.Google Scholar
Hall, Robert E. and Jones, Charles I. (2007) The value of life and the rise in health spending. Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, 3972.Google Scholar
Hansen, Gary (1993) The cyclical and secular behaviour of the labour input: Comparing efficiency units and hours worked. Journal of Applied Econometrics 8, 7180.Google Scholar
He, Hui and Huang, Kevin X. D. (2013) Why do Americans Spend so Much More on Health Care than Europeans?–A General Equilibrium Macroeconomic Analysis, Vandebilt University, working paper no. 15-00003.Google Scholar
Heathcote, Jonathan, Storesletten, Kjetil and Violante, Giovanni L. (2010) The macroeconomic implications of rising wage inequality in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 118, 681722.Google Scholar
Huang, He, Imrohoroglu, Selahattin and Sargent, Thomas J. (1997) Two computations to fund social security. Macroeconomic Dynamics 1, 744.Google Scholar
Huang, Kevin X. D. and Huffman, Gregory W. (2014) Unemployment and welfare implications of the current US tax treatment of employer-provided medical insurance. Macroeconomic Dynamics 18, 15471580.Google Scholar
Hubbard, Glenn, Skinner, Jonathan S. and Zeldes, Stephen P. (1994) The importance of precautionary motives in explaining individual and aggregate saving. Journal of Monetary Economics 40, 59125.Google Scholar
Huggett, Mark (1996) Wealth distribution in life-cycle economies. Journal of Monetary Economics 38, 469494.Google Scholar
Imrohoroglu, Ayse, Imrohoroglu, Selahattin and Joines, Douglas H. (1995) A life cycle analysis of social security. Economic Theory 6, 83114.Google Scholar
Imrohoroglu, Selahattin and Kitao, Sagiri (2012) Social security reforms: Benefit claiming, labor force participation, and long-run sustainability. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4, 96127.Google Scholar
Imrohoroglu, Selahattin and Kitao, Sagiri (2009) Labor supply elasticity and social security reform. Journal of Public Economics 93, 867878.Google Scholar
Jeske, Karsten and Kitao, Sagiri (2009) U.S. tax policy and health insurance demand: Can a regressive policy improve welfare? Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 210221.Google Scholar
Jung, Juergen and Tran, Chung (2009) The macroeconomics of health savings accounts. Towson University, Department of Economics, working paper 2010-12.Google Scholar
Jung, Juergen and Tran, Chung (2010) Medical Consumption Over the Life-Cycle: Facts from a U.S. Medical Expenditure Panel Survey. doi: 10.2139/ssrn.1560484.Google Scholar
Kashihara, David and Kelly, Carper (2008) National Health Care Expenses in the US Civilian Non-Institutionalized Population, 2009. Medical Expenditure Panel Survey Statistical Brief #229.Google Scholar
Kniesner, Thomas, Viscusi, W. Kip, Woock, Christopher and Ziliak, James P (2012) The value of a statistical life: Evidence from panel data. Review of Economics and Statistics 94, 7487.Google Scholar
Kopecky, Karen A. and Tatyana, Koreshkova (2014) The impact of medical and nursing home expenses on savings. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 6, 2972.Google Scholar
Kotlikoff, Laurence J., Smetters, Kent and Walliser, Jan (1999) Privatizing social security in the United States–-comparing the options. Review of Economic Dynamics 2, 532574.Google Scholar
Lillard, Lee A. and Willis, Robert J. (1978) Dynamic aspects of earning mobility. Econometrica 46, 9851012.Google Scholar
Lovell, Vicky (2004) No Time to be Sick: Why Everyone Suffers When Workers Don't have Paid Sick Leave. IWPR Publication B242p, Institute for Women's Policy Research.Google Scholar
Meara, Ellen, White, Chapin and Cutler, David M. (2004) Trends In medical spending by age, 1963–2000. Health Affairs 23, 176183.Google Scholar
Meghir, Costas and Pistaferri, Luigi (2004) Income variance dynamics and heterogeneity. Econometrica 72, 132.Google Scholar
Ozkan, Serdar (2010) Income Differences and Health Care Expenditures Over the Life-Cycle. Unpublished mimeo.Google Scholar
Palumbo, Michael G. (1999) Uncertain medical expenses and precautionary saving near the end of the life cycle. Review of Economic Studies 66, 395421.Google Scholar
Podor, Melinda and Halliday, Timothy (2012) Health status and the allocation of time. Health Economics 21, 514527.Google Scholar
Rust, John and Phelan, Christopher (1997) How social security and Medicare affect retirement behavior in a world of incomplete markets. Econometrica 65, 781831.Google Scholar
Smith, James P. (2007) The impact of socioeconomic status on health over the life-course. The Journal of Human Resources 42, 739764.Google Scholar
Suen, Richard (2006) Technological Advance and the Growth in Health Care Spending. Unpublished mimeo.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W. Kip and Evans, William N. (1990) Utility functions that depend on health status: Estimates and economic implications. American Economic Review 80, 353374.Google Scholar
Yogo, Motohiro (2016) Portfolio choice in retirement: Health risk and the demand for annuities, housing, and risky assets. Journal of Monetary Economics 80, 1734.Google Scholar
Zhao, Kai (2014) Social security and the rise in health spending. Journal of Monetary Economics 64, 2137.Google Scholar