Hostname: page-component-5b777bbd6c-5mwv9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-06-19T23:46:10.022Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Inflation, inequality, and welfare in a competitive search model

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  26 May 2025

Timothy Kam*
Affiliation:
Research School of Economics, The Australian National University, Canberra, Australia
Tina Kao
Affiliation:
Research School of Economics, The Australian National University, Canberra, Australia
Junsang Lee
Affiliation:
Department of Economics, Sungkyunkwan University, Seoul, Republic of Korea
*
Corresponding author: Timothy Kam; Email: tcy.kam@gmail.com

Abstract

We study long-run inflation in a competitive-search model with heterogeneous agents. Under competitive search, individuals’ matching-probability (extensive) margins trade off against quantity (intensive) margins. With money and unfettered market participation, these trade-offs depend on inflation and individuals’ heterogeneous money holdings. We find that welfare falls as inflation increases. However, money-holdings inequality is not monotonic in inflation. As inflation rises, liquid-wealth inequality first falls. For sufficiently high inflation, the overall extensive-margin effect dominates the intensive margin, and liquid-wealth inequality rises. The model also poses a new computational challenge to which we propose a novel solution method.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

References

Acemoglu, D. and Shimer, R. (1999) Efficient unemployment insurance. Journal of Political Economy 107(5), 893928.10.1086/250084CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akyol, A. (2004) Optimal monetary policy in an economy with incomplete markets and idiosyncratic risk. Journal of Monetary Economics 51(6), 12451269.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2003.09.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alvarez, F., Atkeson, A. and Kehoe, P. J. (2002) Money, interest rates, and exchange rates with endogenously segmented markets. Journal of Political Economy 110(1), 73112.10.1086/324389CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berge, C. (1963) Topological Spaces. Edinburgh, UK: Oliver and Boyd. Google Scholar
Bethune, Z. and Rocheteau, G. (2023) Unemployment and the distribution of liquidity. Journal of Political Economy Macroeconomics 1(4), 742787.10.1086/727797CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boel, P. and Camera, G. (2009) Financial sophistication and the distribution of the welfare cost of inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics 56(7), 968978.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009.09.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burdett, K., Shi, S. and Wright, R. (2001) Pricing and matching with frictions. Journal of Political Economy 109(5), 10601085.10.1086/322835CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bustamante, C. (2023) The long-run redistributive effects of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 140, 106123.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2023.08.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Camera, G. and Chien, Y. (2014) Understanding the distributional impact of long-run inflation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46(6), 11371170.10.1111/jmcb.12136CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiu, J. and Molico, M. (2010) Liquidity, redistribution, and the welfare cost of inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics 57(4), 428438.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.03.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chiu, J. and Molico, M. (2021) Short-run dynamics in a search-theoretic model of monetary exchange. Review of Economic Dynamics, October 42, 133155.10.1016/j.red.2020.10.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clementi, G. L. and Hopenhayn, H. A. (2006) A theory of financing constraints and firm dynamics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 121(1), 229265.Google Scholar
Cox, D. R. and Miller, H. D. (1965) The Theory of Stochastic Processes. London: Methuen.Google Scholar
den, H., Wouter, J., Ramey, G. and Watson, J. (2000) Job destruction and propagation of shocks. American Economic Review 90(3), 482498.10.1257/aer.90.3.482CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Erosa, A. and Ventura, G. (2002) On inflation as a regressive consumption tax. Journal of Monetary Economics 49(4), 761795.10.1016/S0304-3932(02)00115-0CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Garriga, C. and Hedlund, A. (2020) Mortgage debt, consumption, and illiquid housing markets in the great recession. American Economic Review 110(6), 16031634.10.1257/aer.20170772CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hagedorn, M. and Manovskii, I. (2008) The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies revisited. American Economic Review 98(4), 16921706.10.1257/aer.98.4.1692CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hedlund, A. (2016) Illiquidity and its discontents: trading delays and foreclosures in the housing market. Journal of Monetary Economics 83, 113.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2016.08.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopenhayn, H. A. and Prescott, E. C. (1992) Stochastic monotonicity and stationary distributions for dynamic economies. Econometrica 60(6), 13871406.10.2307/2951526CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Imrohoroğlu, A. and Prescott, E. C. (1991a) Evaluating the welfare effects of alternative monetary arrangements. Quarterly Review 15(3), 310. Google Scholar
Imrohoroğlu, A. and Prescott, E. C. (1991b) Seigniorage as a tax: a quantitative evaluation. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 23(3), 462475.10.2307/1992681CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ireland, P. N. (2009) On the welfare cost of inflation and the recent behavior of money demand. American Economic Review 99(3), 10401052.10.1257/aer.99.3.1040CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jin, G. and Zhu, T. (2022) Heterogeneity, decentralized trade, and the long-run real effects of inflation. Journal of Economic Theory 201, 105439.10.1016/j.jet.2022.105439CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judd, K. L., Yeltekin, S. and Conklin, J. (2003) Computing supergame equilibria. Econometrica 71(4), 12391254.10.1111/1468-0262.t01-1-00445CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Julien, B., Kennes, J. and King, I. (2008) Bidding for money. Journal of Economic Theory 142(1), 196217.10.1016/j.jet.2006.10.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kam, T. and Stauber, R. (2016) Solving dynamic public insurance games with endogenous agent distributions: theory and computational approximation. Journal of Mathematical Economics 64, 7798.10.1016/j.jmateco.2016.03.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kamihigashi, T. and Stachurski, J. (2014) Stochastic stability in monotone economies. Theoretical Economics 9(2), 383407.10.3982/TE1367CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, G. and Menzio, G. (2015) The morphology of price dispersion. International Economic Review, November 56(4), 11651206.10.1111/iere.12134CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaplan, G., Menzio, G., Moll, B. and Violante, G. L. (2018) Monetary policy according to HANK. American Economic Review 108(3), 697743.10.1257/aer.20160042CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kocherlakota, N. R. (2005) Optimal monetary policy: what we know and what we don’t know. International Economic Review 46(2), 715729.10.1111/j.1468-2354.2005.00343.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, P. and A A.Smith, Jr. (1998) Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. Journal of Political Economy 106(5), 867896.10.1086/250034CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lagos, R. and Rocheteau, G. (2005) Inflation, output, and welfare. International Economic Review 46(2), 495522.10.1111/j.1468-2354.2005.00331.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lagos, R. and Wright, R. (2005) A unified framework for monetary theory and policy analysis. Journal of Political Economy 113(3), 463484.10.1086/429804CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lagos, R., Rocheteau, G. and Wright, R. (2017) Liquidity: a new monetarist perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 55(2), 371440.10.1257/jel.20141195CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R. E. (2000) Inflation and welfare. Econometrica 68(2), 247274.10.1111/1468-0262.00109CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R. E. and Nicolini, J. P. (2015) On the stability of money demand. Journal of Monetary Economics 73(C), 4865.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2015.03.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meh, C. A., Ríos-Rull, J.-V. and Terajima, Y. (2010) Aggregate and welfare effects of redistribution of wealth under inflation and price-level targeting. Journal of Monetary Economics 57(6), 637652.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2010.05.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Menzio, G., Shi, S. and Sun, H. (2013) A monetary theory with non-degenerate distributions. Journal of Economic Theory 148(6), 22662312.10.1016/j.jet.2013.07.020CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, B. D. and Sullivan, J. X. (2023) Consumption and income inequality in the United states since the 1960s. Journal of Political Economy 131(2), 247284.10.1086/721702CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moen, E. R. (1997) Competitive search equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy 105(2), 385411.10.1086/262077CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Molico, M. (2006) The distribution of money and prices in search equilibrium. International Economic Review 47(3), 701722.10.1111/j.1468-2354.2006.00393.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, M. (1991) Ex ante price offers in matching games non-steady states. Econometrica 59(5), 14251454.10.2307/2938374CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, M. (1984) Bertrand equilibrium with capacity constraints and restricted mobility. Econometrica 52(5), 11171127.10.2307/1910990CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Petrosky-Nadeau, N. and Zhang, L. (2017) Solving the diamond-mortensen-pissarides model accurately. Quantitative Economics 8(2), 611650.10.3982/QE452CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phelan, C. and Stacchetti, E. (2001) Sequential equilibria in a ramsey tax model. Econometrica 69(6), 14911518.10.1111/1468-0262.00255CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ravn, M. O. and Sterk, V. (2020) Macroeconomic fluctuations with HANK and SAM: an analytical approach. Journal of the European Economic Association 19(2), 11621202.10.1093/jeea/jvaa028CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rocheteau, G. and Wright, R. (2005) Money in search equilibrium, in competitive equilibrium, and in competitive search equilibrium. Econometrica 73(1), 175202.10.1111/j.1468-0262.2005.00568.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rocheteau, G. and Wright, R. (2009) Inflation and Welfare in Models with Trading Frictions. In: Rocheteau, G. and Wright, R.. (eds.), Monetary Policy in Low Inflation Economies, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Google Scholar
Rocheteau, G. and Weill, P.-O., Wong, T.-N. (2018) A tractable model of monetary exchange with ex-post heterogeneity. Theoretical Economics 13(3), 13691423.10.3982/TE2821CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rocheteau, G., Weill, P.-O. and Wong, T.-N. (2021) An heterogeneous-agent new-monetarist model with an application to unemployment. Journal of Monetary Economics 117, 6490.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2019.11.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rockafellar, R. T. (1970) Convex Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400873173CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shi, S. (1995) Money and prices: a model of search and bargaining. Journal of Economic Theory 67(2), 467496.10.1006/jeth.1995.1081CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shi, S. (2008) Search theory (new perspectives). In: Shi, S. (eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Stevens, M. (2007) New microfoundations for the aggregate matching function. International Economic Review 48(3), 847868.10.1111/j.1468-2354.2007.00447.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stokey, N. L. and Lucas, R. E. (1989). Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Mass, 1989. With Edward C. Prescott.10.2307/j.ctvjnrt76CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sun, H. and Zhou, C. (2018) Monetary and fiscal policies in a heterogeneous-agent economy. Canadian Journal of Economics 51(3), 747783.10.1111/caje.12337CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Topkis, D. M. (1978) Minimizing a submodular function on a lattice. Operations Research 26(2), 305321.10.1287/opre.26.2.305CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Topkis, D. M. (1998) Supermodularity and Complementarity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Google Scholar
Trejos, A. and Wright, R. (1995) Search, bargaining, money, and prices. Journal of Political Economy 103(1), 118141.10.1086/261978CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, N. (2007) An equilibrium model of wealth distribution. Journal of Monetary Economics 54(7), 18821904.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2006.11.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wen, Y. (2015) Money, liquidity and welfare. European Economic Review 76, 124.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2015.01.012CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, S. and Wright, R. (2010) Chapter 2 - New Monetarist Economics: Models. In: Williamson, S. and Wright, R.. (eds.), Handbook of Monetary Economics, vol. 3, pp. 2596, Amsterdam, Netherlands: Elsevier. Google Scholar
Wright, R., Kircher, P., Julien, B. and Guerrieri, V. (2021) Directed search and competitive search equilibrium: a guided tour. Journal of Economic Literature 59(1), 90148.10.1257/jel.20191505CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Supplementary material: File

Kam et al. supplementary material 1

Kam et al. supplementary material
Download Kam et al. supplementary material 1(File)
File 903 KB
Supplementary material: File

Kam et al. supplementary material 2

Kam et al. supplementary material
Download Kam et al. supplementary material 2(File)
File 702 Bytes