Skip to main content
×
Home
    • Aa
    • Aa

Agenda Constrained Legislator Ideal Points and the Spatial Voting Model

  • Joshua D. Clinton (a1) and Adam Meirowitz (a2) (a3)
Abstract

Existing preference estimation procedures do not incorporate the full structure of the spatial model of voting, as they fail to use the sequential nature of the agenda. In the maximum likelihood framework, the consequences of this omission may be far-reaching. First, information useful for the identification of the model is neglected. Specifically, information that identifies the proposal locations is ignored. Second, the dimensionality of the policy space may be incorrectly estimated. Third, preference and proposal location estimates are incorrect and difficult to interpret in terms of the spatial model. We also show that the Bayesian simulation approach to ideal point estimation (Clinton et al. 2000; Jackman 2000) may be improved through the use of information about the legislative agenda. This point is illustrated by comparing several preference estimators of the first U.S. House (1789–1791).

Copyright
Linked references
Hide All

This list contains references from the content that can be linked to their source. For a full set of references and notes please see the PDF or HTML where available.

Kenneth R. Bowling 1971. “Dinner at Jefferson's: A Note on Jacob E. Cooke's ‘The Compromise of 1790.’William and Mary Quarterly 28: 629648.

Jacob E. Cooke 1970. “The Compromise of 1790.” William and Mary Quarterly 27: 523545.

Wayne DeSarbo , and Jaewun Cho . 1989. “A Stochastic Multidimensional Scaling Vector Threshold Model for the Spatial Representation of Pick Any/N Data.” Psychometrika 54: 105129.

Richard Durrett . 1995. Probability: Theory and Examples, 2nd ed. Belmont, CA: Duxbury Press.

S. J. Haberman 1977. “Maximum Likelihood Estimates in Exponential Response Models.” Annals of Statistics 5: 815841.

James Heckman , and James Snyder . 1997. “Linear Probability Models of the Demand for Attributes with and Empirical Application to Estimating the Preferences of Legislators.” Rand Journal of Economics 28: 142189.

Simon Jackman . 2000. “Estimation and Inference Are Missing Data Problems: Unifying Social Science Statistics via Bayesian Simulation.” Political Analysis 8: 307322.

J. Kiefer , and J. Wolfowitz 1956. “Consistency of the Maximum Likelihood Estimator in the Presence of Infinitely Many Incidental Parameters.” Annals of Mathematical Statistics 27: 887896.

Keith Krehbiel , and Doug Rivers . 1988. “An Analysis of Committee Power: An Application to Senate Voting on the Minimum Wage.” American Journal of Political Science 32: 11511174.

John Londregan . 2000a. “Estimating Legislator's Preferred Points.” Political Analysis 8: 3556.

John Londregan . 2000b. Legislative Institutions and Ideology in Chile. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Margaret M. O’Dwyer 1964. “A French Diplomat's View of Congress 1790.” William and Mary Quarterly 21: 408444.

Keith T. Poole 2000. “Nonparametric Unfolding of Binary Choice Data.” Political Analysis 8: 211237.

Norman K. Risjord 1976. “The Compromise of 1790: New Evidence on the Dinner Table Bargain.” William and Mary Quarterly 33: 309314.

A. Wald 1948. “Estimation of a Parameter When the Number of Unknown Parameters Increases Indefinitely with the Number of Observations.” Annals of Mathematic Statistics 19: 220227.

Recommend this journal

Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this journal to your organisation's collection.

Political Analysis
  • ISSN: 1047-1987
  • EISSN: 1476-4989
  • URL: /core/journals/political-analysis
Please enter your name
Please enter a valid email address
Who would you like to send this to? *
×
MathJax

Metrics

Full text views

Total number of HTML views: 0
Total number of PDF views: 3 *
Loading metrics...

Abstract views

Total abstract views: 20 *
Loading metrics...

* Views captured on Cambridge Core between 4th January 2017 - 21st September 2017. This data will be updated every 24 hours.