Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-vfjqv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T06:37:21.533Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Use-Based Welfare: Property Experiments in Chicago, 1895–1935

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2019

Get access
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Use-based welfare achieves redistribution by reallocating rights to use and benefit from idle resources, rather than through tax and transfer. How and why has this form of welfare provision emerged as an urban institution, and what affects whether it endures? This article compares projects to grant poor and unemployed Chicagoans access to land for gardens and small farms between 1895 and 1935, explaining how this form of social support came about through experiments with rules, norms, and forms of property. While social policy is typically understood as emerging through the realization of rights to public support, use-based welfare turns instead on efforts to create a legal privilege for the needy to use idle resources. During the Progressive Era and the Great Depression, this form of relief was pitched as both an alternative and a complement to welfare based on tax and transfer. Yet efforts to establish it as a permanent institution repeatedly failed, due to implementation challenges, opposition from people committed to treating land and food as commodities, and the nonemergence of a social movement to defend land access. Recognizing the historical dynamics of use-based welfare offers a new perspective on the contemporary resurgence of urban farming as a strategy for addressing unemployment and poverty.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© Social Science History Association, 2019 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Over the past decade, farms and gardens have been cropping up around Chicago. In Englewood, a South Side neighborhood where work has disappeared and vacant lots are abundant, the city has created an urban agriculture district. Farms offer job training to the unemployed and summer work for “at-risk” youth. They sit on land leased by the parks district, and vacant lots that the city has transferred to an urban agriculture land trust. City plans call for a system of public open spaces for large-scale food production, where entrepreneurial growers in high-poverty neighborhoods can earn “supplemental income” by farming (City of Chicago 2013: 17–18; 2014: 30–32).

What accounts for this move back to the land? Chicago’s embrace of farms and gardens might be seen as a response to consumer demand—from residents of so-called food deserts (Gallagher Reference Gallagher2006), restaurant patrons hungry for hyper-local food, or people willing to pay a premium to live near a community garden (Voicu and Been Reference Voicu and Been2008). This article proposes an alternate explanation. As welfare programs have been cut, and benefits made contingent on work requirements, the turn to urban agriculture also signals the reemergence of a type of redistributive social policy common before the creation of the modern welfare state. Rather than redistributing through tax and transfer, this form of social policy, which I refer to as use-based welfare, does so by reallocating rights to use and benefit from idle resources.

This article explains how and why social reformers have repeatedly experimented with land use as a basis for supporting the needy. I examine and compare how this longstanding form of redistribution figured in welfare provision in Chicago during the Progressive Era and the Great Depression. Who supported it, and who opposed it? How did it relate to other forms of welfare provision? And in contrast to those other forms, why has use-based welfare periodically emerged and then disappeared?

I explore these questions by comparing how social reformers and municipal officials—from residents of the Hull House social settlement and wartime garden campaigners to Depression-era relief workers—worked to grant poor and unemployed Chicagoans the ability to grow food on vacant pieces of land. This sheds light on how reformers developed organizational, institutional, and discursive strategies to use idle land to alleviate poverty and unemployment. And it helps account for why use-based welfare has not become a permanent urban institution. Urban farms and gardens have periodically emerged as reformers have brokered rights to use land; the reluctance of these brokers to act as organizers has, in turn, hampered the creation of movements that could defend and entrench use-based welfare.

By identifying connections between land use and social policy, the article offers a new perspective on urban agriculture. Social scientists have generally seen urban growing as part of a movement for just, sustainable, and local food systems (Allen Reference Allen2008; White Reference White2011). This centers attention on dynamics and contradictions of movement organizing (Lyson Reference Lyson2014; McClintock Reference McClintock2013). This study focuses instead on the property rules that define the conditions of possibility for urban growing, revealing how urban agriculture relates to urban institutions and social policy. In the process, it points to possible stumbling blocks for movements to make farms and gardens a permanent feature of urban landscapes.

It is tempting to read the history that emerges as one of a path not taken. A century ago, giving the unemployed poor access to vacant urban land was a common strategy for social support in America’s cities. Yet since the rise of the modern welfare state, making idle resources available for use by the poor and unemployed has largely fallen off the social policy agenda. When social reformers, state officials, and sociologists think of welfare provision, it is usually in terms of income supports or social services. When we think of land use, it is not usually in terms of social policy. Recognizing how the two are connected requires effort. Retracing how such connections have played out in the past offers a new perspective on the institutional landscapes of our cities, and suggests parallels between past and present. Use-based welfare may not be just a historical artifact—it may also be a form of redistribution once again on the rise.

Welfare Provision: A Fourth Way

Studies of social policy have focused on three types of welfare provision. These can be categorized by reference to the means of resource distribution, and the type of right granted to beneficiaries. Redistribution often results from tax-and-transfer policies, but can also be achieved by altering property laws to grant beneficiaries a claim to a resource. Whichever the mode of redistribution, beneficiaries may acquire full ownership rights to a resource, or simply the rights to use and enjoy it. Conceptualizing welfare provision according to these distinctions yields four ideal types (table 1).

TABLE 1. Four modes of welfare provision

Note: Typology by the author. Asset-based welfare may involve redistribution through either tax-and-transfer subsidies (such as matching funds for Individual Development Accounts) or adjustments to property relations (such as land reform). AFDC refers to Aid to Families with Dependent Children; SNAP refers to the Supplemental Nutrition Assistance Program (formerly and commonly known as the Food Stamp Program).

Use-based welfare differs from the forms of social policy with which we are most familiar. It does not redistribute through tax and transfer. Nor does it grant full ownership rights to a resource. Instead, it simply reallocates the rights to use and benefit from a resource. To understand how and why people mobilize to bring about this form of redistribution—and how institutions of use-based welfare emerge, stabilize, and disappear—I ask how the dynamics of this type of welfare provision may parallel, or differ from, more familiar forms of social policy.

Explanations for the emergence and entrenchment of income supports have varied. Some scholars have focused on demands made against the state, whether by social movements (Piven and Cloward Reference Piven and Cloward1977), labor movements (Esping-Anderson Reference Esping-Anderson1990), or reformers seeking disaster relief (Dauber Reference Dauber2013). Others have argued that, once in place, redistributive programs have a “ratchet effect” as beneficiaries enjoy new benefits and resist cutbacks (Huber and Stephens Reference Huber and Stephens2001: 28–29), and create the basis for alternative alliances that defend new institutions of social policy (Weir et al. Reference Weir, Orloff, Skocpol, Weir, Orloff and Skocpol1988: 17).

Since the 1990s, welfare supports have increasingly taken the form of services provided by nonprofit organizations (Salamon Reference Salamon1995; Smith and Lipsky Reference Smith and Lipsky1995). Here, beneficiaries receive the benefit of using services funded by taxes, rather than a claim to a share of tax revenues. This shift toward service-based welfare has been explained as a product of community-based organizations brokering access to resources, while mobilizing beneficiaries as political constituents to lobby the state for increased funding (Marwell Reference Marwell2004; Small Reference Small2006).

Meanwhile, policy entrepreneurs have promoted asset-based welfare as a “third-way” alternative to income supports and service provision (Ackerman and Alstott Reference Ackerman and Alstott2000; Sherraden Reference Sherraden1991). One version of asset-based welfare uses tax revenues to subsidize ownership rather than (or in addition to) income supports.Footnote 1 Another redistributes by reforming property law so as to broaden the ownership of assets. In the Global South, this has included land titling for urban squatters (de Soto Reference de Soto2000) and land reforms for the rural poor (Wolford Reference Wolford2007). Proponents cite “asset effects” as evidence that the value of ownership is not only economic (Bynner and Paxton Reference Bynner and Paxton2001) but also increases self-sufficiency and well-being (Bynner and Despotidou Reference Bynner and Despotidou2001; Cho Reference Cho1999).

There is also a fourth way: supporting the poor by sharing the use and benefits of idle resources. This practice has a long history, particularly when the resource in question is land. Passages in Leviticus (19:9–10) and Deuteronomy (24:19) instruct farmers not to harvest the corners of their fields to allow gleaning by the poor (Singer Reference Singer2001). From the late 1600s through the 1800s, European social thinkers and reformers proposed ways to restore use rights to the unemployed poor, who had been dispossessed of customary rights to common lands. These ranged from the Diggers’ occupation and collective cultivation of common land (Winstanley Reference Winstanley1649) and Locke’s (Reference Locke and Macpherson1980 [1690]) proposal that surplus private property revert to the commons, to projects to keep England’s rural poor off parish lists by letting them use waste lands (Young Reference Young1801) and to Marx’s (Reference Marx1975 [1842]) defense of customary rights to gather wood from Germany’s forests. During a visit to France, Thomas Jefferson (Reference Jefferson, Kurland and Lerner1986 [1785]) reasoned that “Whenever there is in any country, uncultivated lands and unemployed poor, it is clear that the laws of property have been so far extended as to violate natural right.” When landless people cannot find work, he argued, “the fundamental right to labour the earth returns to the unemployed.” Yet he deemed it too soon in the United States “to say that every man who cannot find employment but who can find uncultivated land, shall be at liberty to cultivate it, paying a moderate rent.”

In Europe, however, gardens cropped up as a form of social provision. In England, allotment gardens emerged in the 1700s and were written into legislation during the 1800s (Burchardt Reference Burchardt2002). In France and Germany, the Red Cross and private firms used garden programs to support the poor during the nineteenth century (Nilsen Reference Nilsen2014). As we will see, Americans followed suit following the Panic of 1893.

Unlike other forms of welfare provision, which have become entrenched institutional features of the modern state, use-based welfare has come and gone. What accounts for this cycle of emergence and disappearance? How do advocates renegotiate use rights, at least temporarily, so that the unemployed and poor can use vacant land? And what hampers efforts to establish organizations and institutions of use-based welfare as ongoing features of an urban landscape?

Part of the story, the Chicago case study suggests, involves how use-based welfare has straddled the blurry lines between private and public in how cities have administered welfare supports (Katz Reference Katz1996: 43–47). Private charity and public relief have long coexisted, along with different conditions for helping the needy. Proponents of private charity (understood as a gift) have long critiqued the supposed potential for public outdoor relief (understood as a right) to promote indolence and dependency (Fox Reference Fox2010; Katz Reference Katz1996). In Chicago, use-based welfare projects began as privately coordinated programs, but soon migrated to include public land and public coordination. In the process, they ran counter to general trends. Cities like Chicago, with a large proportion of immigrants from Europe, tended to support the poor through public relief (Fox Reference Fox2010). Garden projects, however, targeted European immigrants with a form of private charity hoped to prevent dependence on public relief. As garden projects expanded from private and corporate programs to become a form of publicly coordinated projects, the built-in work requirement also became part of public welfare supports. As we will see, the expectation that growers would work in return for receiving land was met with ambivalence among some gardeners, even as public projects met opposition from landowners and commercial growers.

Explaining the dynamics of use-based welfare also requires appreciating its distinctiveness. Scholars often understand social policy as a set of rights created in response to social movement pressure (O’Connor et al. Reference O’Connor, Orloff and Shaver1999; Piven and Cloward Reference Piven and Cloward1977).Footnote 2 These rights correspond to duties the state owes to citizens. The study of the emergence and institutionalization of social policy has focused on how mobilization in different political and social contexts has resulted in different bundles of rights across jurisdictions, creating a “ratchet effect” as benefits become taken for granted (Esping-Anderson Reference Esping-Anderson1990; Huber and Stephens Reference Huber and Stephens2001; Weir et al. Reference Weir, Orloff, Skocpol, Weir, Orloff and Skocpol1988).

Use-based welfare involves a different legal relation. Property owners generally have the right to exclude nonowners. Rather than grant beneficiaries a right, use-based welfare creates a privilege to use a resource—which corresponds to an owner’s lack of right to exclude nonowners (Hohfeld Reference Hohfeld1913: 32–33). In practice, experiments with used-based welfare have approximated this ideal type.

If proponents of cash transfers or service provision respond to poverty by devising and justifying schemes to tax and transfer income or wealth, advocates of use-based welfare face a different challenge. Here, the puzzle is how to reallocate the bundle of rights that structure property relations (Commons Reference Commons1893: 92) so that the needy may use idle resources. This can require solving a matching problem (Mortensen Reference Mortensen1988) to pair resources with potential users. In a manner akin to social service providers (Small Reference Small2006), providers of use-based welfare broker access to resources. But rather than brokering access to subsidized services, they facilitate exchanges between owners of idle resources and potential users. These deals arguably improve economic efficiency.Footnote 3 But they also pose a puzzle that implicates equity. How might owners be convinced to help the needy by conceding a “basic feature” of private property (Smith Reference Smith2012: 1709)—their right to exclude?

The challenge of institutionalizing use-based welfare involves converting temporary legal and moral claims to use idle resources into something more durable. From what we know of other forms of welfare, we might expect to see efforts to mobilize the power of labor or social movements to entrench use rights. We might also ask if schemes initially devised as temporary have a ratchet effect, creating policy feedbacks by transforming beneficiaries’ preferences and political possibilities. Flipping these explanations, in turn, yields hypotheses concerning why use-based welfare might disappear. Reformers may fail to mobilize political pressure in favor of use rights. Programs conceived as temporary fixes, or developed as private forms of relief, may fail to produce a policy ratchet effect.

To explain the emergence and noninstitutionalization of use-based welfare I also draw on insights from urban and legal sociology. Experiments with remaking property relations intervene in an urban political economy defined by treating both land and food as commodities (Cronon Reference Cronon1991; Logan and Molotch Reference Logan and Molotch1987). Promoters of land access for urban growing have acted as norm entrepreneurs (Sunstein Reference Sunstein1996), claiming that property owners have an obligation to help the needy (Alexander Reference Alexander2009) and advocating new property rules. To justify these changes, reformers have appealed to “use effects”—akin to the “asset effects” claimed by promoters of asset-based welfare. These claims highlight how “problems of welfare economics must ultimately dissolve into a study of aesthetics and morals” (Coase Reference Coase1960: 43). By asserting the value of deals they broker with landowners, promoters of use-based welfare have sought to bring about new urban property institutions (Allard and Small Reference Allard and Small2013; Bartley Reference Bartley2007)—and reshape what it means to live and labor in the city.

Methods and Data

To explain how and why use-based welfare has emerged and disappeared as an urban institution, I compare how people brought about such programs in Chicago between the 1890s and 1935. This reveals patterns and differences between how reformers developed organizational and institutional responses to poverty and unemployment. It also helps identify how their strategies drew on lessons taken from problem solving in earlier periods (Haydu Reference Haydu1998).

Chicago, the site of this case study, is not claimed to be representative of all cities. Chicago’s unique history of intense industrial development, racial segregation, and deindustrialization (Cronon Reference Cronon1991; Satter Reference Satter2009; Walley Reference Walley2013) has produced a “surprising preponderance of empty spaces, vacant lots and desolate streets” that distinguishes it from other cities (Small Reference Small2007: 413). This is a study of an extreme case, which by “activat[ing] more actors and more basic mechanisms in the situation studied” can yield greater insight than a typical case (Flyvberg Reference Flyvberg2006: 229). The primary comparative approach is diachronic, analyzing how the relationship between land and social policy has changed over time.

I examine how people have experimented with the institutions of property and land use that define the urban landscape. Following the institutional ethnography of Dorothy Smith (Reference Smith2005), I map how reformers seek to change the rules and relationships that define land use in particular places. This double mapping—institutional and physical—focuses on sites in the urban landscape that have served as laboratories for tinkering with norms, rules, and forms of property. By taking property as structuring social relations, I ground recent calls for a relational sociology (Emirbayer Reference Emirbayer1997) in a century-old insight of legal realists—that property law implicates relations between people, rather than simply between people and things (Hale Reference Hale1923; Hohfeld Reference Hohfeld1913; Singer Reference Singer, Geisler and Daneker2000).

I draw on documents produced by Chicago’s settlement house reformers, Progressive Era firms, and city agencies. I also rely on newspaper articles, which raises the possibility of selection or description bias (Earl et al. Reference Earl, Martin, McCarthy and Soule2004). Because newspaper articles serve to trace the progression of events, as well as reveal the positions that authors and editors took toward gardening projects, their potential for description bias provides insight into both how social reformers framed their claims and how an influential segment of Chicago’s elite viewed and amplified those claims.

Vacant Lot Gardening, 1895–1920

Following the Panic of 1893, social reformers and municipal officials sought to ease the suffering of the poor in America’s industrializing cities. In Detroit, Mayor Hazen Pingree launched a program to let the unemployed use land offered by private owners; the project turned 430 acres of vacant lots into gardens. Pingree promised this blend of public coordination and private charity would reduce the tax burden, ordering the poor commission to strike from its rolls anyone who did not apply for a garden (Cialdella Reference Cialdella2014: 62–63). Word of “Pingree’s Potato Patches” spread quickly, and vacant lot cultivation associations sprung up in New York, Philadelphia, and beyond. Reformers hailed how gardens let the unemployed help themselves (Fels Reference Fels1920; Hall Reference Hall1908; Lawson Reference Lawson2005). As cities and local agencies scrambled to respond to unprecedented economic distress, the programs aligned with a general skepticism of public outdoor relief (Katz Reference Katz1996: 37–59, 152–53).

In 1895, the Chicago Tribune solicited an article from Pingree, describing Detroit’s garden programs (Pingree Reference Pingree1895). The Chicago Bureau of Charities launched a project to let the poor garden in vacant lots (Bureau of Associated Charities 1898: 16–17). Growers formed a club that met at the Hull House social settlement (Pelham Reference Pelham1909: 423). The project withered after a few seasons, but the landless gardeners kept gathering (“The People’s Friendly Club” 1905–6).

Hull House did not have its own garden, but its residents were curious about the possibilities. In 1901, the famous anarchist geographer Peter Kropotkin visited and spoke on Fields, Factories, and Workshops (Reference Kropotkin1912 [1898]). The book envisioned urban workers rotating between agriculture, industry, and craft workshops (“World improves, says Kropotkin” 1901). Jane Addams praised the book as “remarkable” (Avrich Reference Avrich1980: 27). Settlement leaders and welfare workers from Chicago’s manufacturing firms also discussed gardening during private meetings. During one, a visitor from Ohio explained how his factory had assigned garden plots to “idle and disorderly” neighborhood boys (Conference on Welfare Work, May 1, 1906). In another, New York City’s buildings inspector argued worker productivity turned on access to pure air, water, and food (Conference on Welfare Work, June 12, 1906). Welfare agents at International Harvester, a Chicago-based farm machine company, reported back directly to the company’s president.

In 1909, Hull House resident Laura Dainty Pelham founded the City Gardens Association (CGA) to make land available to members of the People’s Friendly Club. She appealed for land and money, and received offers of lots scattered around Chicago (Pelham Reference Pelham1909). Harvester offered 90 acres, and the association chose to use 20 acres next to its factory. Families lined up at Hull House, paying $1.50—roughly $40 in 2018 dollars (Williamson Reference Williamson2018)—to claim an eighth-acre plot. The CGA acted as a broker, offering licenses to use Harvester’s land. “The gardener virtually possesses a ‘deed’ to the land,” the association reported, “but must keep its condition up to a required standard.” Gardeners were “subject to dispossession when the owner wants to use the land” (“‘Back to the soil’ cure” 1910).

The program fit with Harvester’s approach to corporate welfare. The company had long opposed labor organizing. In 1886, a lockout outside its factory led to the Haymarket Square massacre (Green Reference Green2006: 162–73). Managers eventually began experimenting with other ways of discouraging unionization. In 1901, Harvester created a welfare bureau (Mandell Reference Mandell2002). The company welfare secretary, who joined the CGA board, argued that the “social and recreative life of the people [were] one of the first needs to provide for” because the “character of the employees, and conditions in neighborhoods in which they live, determine largely what an employer may do” (Price Reference Price1907).

Harvester lost little by offering use of its land. The parcel sat next to a fork of the Chicago River rendered a stagnant swamp when a shipping canal had opened a few years earlier. Because the fork was still considered a navigable waterway, it could neither be dredged nor filled until Congress changed its status. The question was tied up in committee, leaving the future of the river, and Harvester’s land, uncertain (Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce 1921–22: 109–11; Sanitary District of Chicago 1906: 11347–48).

The experiment at the Harvester Garden set a model that migrated from private to public land. In 1910, the Western Electric company offered up land; in 1912, the CGA gained access to ten acres of a family estate (“‘Back to the soil’ cure” 1910; “Toilers to farm” 1912). That May, the Tribune published a letter from an out-of-state subscriber, offering up vacant lots. Pelham used the letter to launch a campaign to recruit more land (“City ‘farms’ for the poor” 1912). By 1913, city agencies joined the effort. The directors of Chicago’s park districts discussed creating demonstration gardens. Pelham hoped these would “encourage the general utilization of waste spaces for growing vegetables” (Hyde Reference Hyde1913). In 1915, the city’s Department of Welfare made the CGA responsible for cataloging offers of land. During a recession that year, the Sanitary District offered 3,500 acres, some of which were allotted for small farms (Hyde Reference Hyde1915a). Noting the successful experience of small farms near European cities, the Chicago Tribune donated money for the experiment (Hyde Reference Hyde1915b).

Advocates claimed that using idle land for gardens created economic value. The Tribune routinely reported the value of harvests and of gardeners’ sales of surplus produce (Evans Reference Evans1915; “Gardens for the poor lesson to women” 1909). In the fall of 1909, for example, each family received enough vegetables to support itself, plus $30 in sales; the CGA invested just $6 per family (“A use for vacant lots” 1909). Such figures, together with the promise that gardening could reduce the costs of private charity and public relief, convinced Tribune editors that the project should be expanded. In Philadelphia and New York, poor families farmed “thousands of acres” with “splendid results,” the paper observed; the “necessity for bread lines and other forms of charity have been greatly lessened.” In Chicago “there are hundreds of acres,” the paper noted, “which might be used for this purpose if the owners would let the association have them for a term of years” (ibid.; “Gardening in the garden city” 1910).

Pelham, meanwhile, hoped to increase workers’ leverage. Companies “know a line of laborers stand waiting, forced by their necessities to accept anything,” she wrote in a letter, “and this condition is held as a club over the heads of unskilled workmen” (Carroll Reference Carroll1912: 219). She saw the problem of the unemployed as “a menace,” arguing that companies would be less likely to lock out employees, cut wages, or fail to recognize unions “if the army of unemployed were diverted away from the congested labor centers.” Publicly, Pelham reported that the Harvester Garden offered growers “a real taste of farm life, and almost without exception they have preferred it to work in the streets and factories. Many of these have taken to the open air and started larger farms in the country” (“Uses small farm” 1910). In later years, she dropped this claim. If enticing the unemployed away from Chicago was the aim, it never bore much fruit.

Proponents also claimed that using land for gardens cultivated moral values. Landowners were initially skeptical of Pelham’s appeals, thinking “it would be impossible to start a garden because of the proclivities for ‘lifting’ among the boys of the neighborhood” (“City ‘farms’ for the poor” 1912). Pelham reported, however, that letting people use vacant land increased respect for property. Even without fences, “nothing is ever pilfered or damaged by hoodlums,” she noted (“Gardens given to the poor” 1910). Officials from the prison across the street reported “a great change in the attitude of the residents toward other people’s property since we started the gardens” (“Toilers to farm” 1912). Others saw similar effects. “In the worst neighborhoods, where small boys are encouraged to work at raising vegetables,” Chicago’s former commissioner of public health noted, “there is less pilfering, less stealing and less crime” (Evans Reference Evans1913).

Promoters also asserted that gardens increased “industry, thrift, self-respect, self-confidence, and honesty” (“‘Back to the soil’ cure” 1910). Reformers were eager to instill these values in immigrant women. The “laziness of the housewife,” Thomas and Znaniecki wrote in The Polish Peasant (Reference Thomas and Znaniecki1920: 211), “seems to be brought about by the changes in the nature and bearing of housework.” Such work in Chicago was less varied than in Poland, where it involved tending a garden. By gardening, women could “positively contribute[] to the income and property of the family” (ibid.). The Tribune noted approvingly that gardens were “almost like the early days, when women worked in the fields,” giving them “a spirit of independence” (“A use for vacant lots” 1909; “Poor of city get 90 acres to till” 1909).

Finally, gardens were claimed to improve health and aesthetics. The “mentally and physically unable,” the CGA asserted, were improved “morally, mentally, and physically without pauperizing them” (“‘Back to the soil’ cure” 1910). Thanks to the Harvester Garden’s fresh air and “soft, spongy earth,” a boy reportedly gained ten pounds in a single summer (“Gardens for poor lesson to women” 1909). These benefits came as the association turned “waste places … into beautiful gardens” (“‘Back to the soil’ cure” 1910). One article described the Harvester Garden’s “pastoral scene” as “an artistic asset for the city … [that] fits in with the scheme of the ‘City Beautiful’” (Gilbert Reference Gilbert1914).

These claims built a case for making this form of redistribution an ongoing feature of Chicago’s landscape. If letting the poor use vacant lots cultivates economic and moral value, then it follows that letting land lay idle is inefficient and unjust. Season by season, through deals with landowners, newspaper coverage, and presentations to civic groups, Pelham and others worked as norm entrepreneurs (Sunstein Reference Sunstein1996), asserting that landowners owe a social obligation to the needy (Alexander Reference Alexander2009), who have a moral claim to use idle land.

By 1915, people began to imagine use-based welfare becoming permanent. If farms on sanitary district land were successful, the Tribune argued, “there is no reason why the plan cannot be carried out on a great scale in future years” (“Sanitary body quick to vote small farms” 1915). One superintendent at a Harvester factory hoped “to see every available foot of tillable soil in Chicago made available to laborers’ families throughout the city without special reference to IHC families” (Reider Reference Reider1915).

Then, in March 1917, the United States entered the war in Europe. Mayor Thompson assembled business and civic leaders to build support for a citywide gardening campaign, then created a city gardens bureau in his city hall office (“Mass meeting gives gardens a big boost” 1917). Newspapers reported widespread support among business leaders. Harvester’s agricultural extension director, Perry Holden, declared that gardens could feed half the city, and was named to lead the campaign. City agencies identified vacant lots for public and private landowners to contribute. Police on motorcycles took soil samples. The high cost of living and threat of food shortages and riots loomed (“Business men aid garden idea” 1917; “Gardens get mayor’s room” 1917; Holden Reference Holden1917; “Mayor asks city heads to be farmers” 1917; “Motorcycles to aid gardens” 1917; “Predicts riots” 1917; “US facing famine” 1917).

By April, officials worried that land donations were not meeting demand from gardeners, or what would be needed to avoid food shortages (“Demand very great for gardening space” 1917). A garden bureau employee, Leroy Boughner, proposed that leaving land idle be treated as a crime, even in peacetime. The city should seize vacant lots, he argued, and allow gardeners to use them without owners’ permission, requiring compensation if owners destroyed gardeners’ crops (“City urged to conscript lots” 1917).

Boughner’s proposal resonated with longstanding theories of property. The notion that people gain rights by mixing their labor with things taken from nature was rooted in Locke’s labor theory, which had previously been deployed to justify expropriating people—native Americans—who failed to put land into cultivation (Armitage Reference Armitage and Muthu2012; Cronon Reference Cronon1983: 56–57). The idea that users had a moral claim to idle property also aligned with the Protestant ethic, which Weber (Reference Weber2001 [1930]: 104) described as opposed to “relaxation in the security of possession [and] the enjoyment of wealth with the consequence of idleness.”

Boughner likely drew on his experience running a prewar beautification campaign in Minneapolis. There, gardeners simply

took possession of the lots and settled with the owners afterward. As it turned out, a very small percentage of the owners objected to this use of their idle property, which improved it rather than otherwise, and it cost the club less to straighten it out with the few who objected, and to reimburse the gardeners for their loss, than it would have cost to go to all the trouble looking up the owners and securing permission in advance. (“A city full of gardens” 1916)

Given the wartime urgency, Boughner likely hoped his proposed rule would speed the matching of land with growers.

The opposite seems to have happened. Boughner’s proposal to make gardening someone else’s land a legal privilege (Hohfeld Reference Hohfeld1913: 30)—thereby limiting owners’ right to exclude—went nowhere. Business support for a city-run garden bureau evaporated. Within a week, the Chicago Association of Commerce and Industry moved the bureau out of city hall, and into its own offices. The new director wondered if Chicagoans would “understand that we refer to each of them individually and to their own yards and lawns when we say, ‘Grow a garden.’” (“Association of commerce as garden chief” 1917 [emphasis added]). By early June, the campaign was shuttered, ostensibly for lack of funding (“Garden bureau closed by commerce board” 1917). Holden, however, noted that money was in fact raised and seeds purchased.Footnote 4

A renewed attempt to make gardens a permanent feature of Chicago’s landscape came soon after the war. In 1918, the commissioners of Chicago’s West Park District asked landscape architect Jens Jensen to develop a plan for expanding the city’s parks. Jensen had designed the Harvester Garden and sat on the CGA board. He drew up a plan for a network of parks, including a municipal farm and a dozen market gardens (West Chicago Park Commissioners 1920). Jensen modeled these on the Harvester Garden, which he relabeled an “existing municipal garden.” He called for taking private land using eminent domain, creating public land for gardeners to use.

At a meeting to approve Jensen’s plan, one commissioner promised the cost would be “surprisingly low” because the land plotted out included few obstacles (“Chicago to be just one park after another” 1919). Yet Jensen simply hadn’t made obstacles apparent. He had, for example, included a photo of Harvester’s property, captioned simply as vacant land “to be condemned for parks.” Within months, Jensen and the entire board of commissioners had been fired. Jensen (Reference Jensen1990 [1939]: 94) later reflected that “Chicago was once called a garden city,” asking, “What has become of the gardens?” He explained: “What has happened in Chicago has happened in many other large cities where speculation has been the guiding force.”

The moral and legal principles behind Boughner and Jensen’s proposals had deep roots, but ran up against something more powerful. These attempts to make land use for gardens a permanent urban institution—whether by formalizing a social obligation norm or through eminent domain—were swiftly and decisively blocked by people interested in preserving the exchange value of land (Logan and Molotch Reference Logan and Molotch1987). Newspapers had long promoted garden programs, but when business leaders moved to close the garden bureau, there were neither editorials protesting the move nor reports of protests by would-be gardeners. Despite settlement movement leaders’ support for Jensen’s plan, there do not seem to have been protests when it was blocked. This could, of course, reflect either a lack of social movement pressure for continued access to land, or a willingness among newspaper editors to drop a cause that they had previously championed. In either case, it appears that when promoters of reallocating rights to use Chicago’s vacant lots met resistance from landowners and the business community, the practice they developed on a temporary basis failed to generate alliances or coalitions that might have mobilized to defend it as a lasting institution.

Relief Gardens, 1931–1935

Faced with an economic crisis in the fall of 1929, companies and government officials around the country again turned to gardens to support the unemployed (Lawson Reference Lawson2005). Gardening was not a major form of relief the following summer, but by the spring of 1931 firms and government agencies in Chicago and elsewhere had launched programs (Colcord and Johnston Reference Colcord and Johnston1933: 9). Promoters realized they were reviving a bygone practice.Footnote 5 “It was during the period of the World War,” one Harvester employee (incorrectly) recalled, that “the garden project as applied to industrial workers and the non-farming population first attracted attention.” As he saw it, the return to gardening reflected a renewed “need for the elemental sustaining products of the soil” (Hawkins Reference Hawkinsn.d.).

With the CGA no longer in existence, Chicago’s firms and government officials experimented with new ways to match growers with land.Footnote 6 They made three main changes. First, they brokered land access themselves, rather than partnering with community-based organizations. Second, firms provided gardens for their own laid-off workers, rather than residents generally. Third, government agencies framed this form of welfare provision as a temporary measure, rather than the beginning of a more permanent reworking of property and economic relations.

Harvester emerged as a leader in company gardening, both in Chicago and nationwide (US Department of Commerce 1932). In February 1931, the company coordinated discussions of gardens during work-council meetings in all its factories. A garden committee at Chicago’s McCormick Works plant surveyed active and laid-off employees, and looked for suitable land (ibid.). Harvester rented several fields around the city, which it plowed, fertilized, divided into plots, and allotted to workers’ families. By 1932, it had made available 1,000 acres for gardens in and around Chicago and another 1,200 acres elsewhere throughout the country (“Harvester’s relief and garden plans” 1932).

Harvester maintained tight oversight. Its extension department distributed seed packets and plans for planting; only crops that could be canned were permitted. People on public cash relief received seeds for free, but people receiving Harvester’s unemployment relief loans were charged. Gardening gave a worker “an outlet for his latent activity” and helped Harvester keep him integrated into its management hierarchy (Hawkins Reference Hawkinsn.d.). Organizers assigned gardeners to fields supervised by the foremen under whom they had previously worked. Foremen enforced the extension department’s instructions. “Each gardener must care for his plot in a way satisfactory to those in charge,” an article in the company magazine noted. “Neglect is not tolerated” (“Harvester’s relief and garden plans” 1932).

For Harvester, the gardens created economic benefits. An internal memo noted that by supplementing other unemployment relief, gardens reduced the direct burdens of relief upon both the company and employees. Before they could receive loans or allowances from the Harvester relief fund, employees had to apply for a garden (“Confidential memorandum” 1932). Income supports were made contingent on use-based welfare.

Harvester’s magazine and internal memos stressed the gardens’ noneconomic value. The need for employee gardens “goes deeper than the mere monetary value of the foodstuffs raised,” one memo observed. “It reaches down to supply an equally real need in the mental and moral life of the worker, namely that of furnishing a healthful activity to take the place of the vacuum created by his lack of work in the factory” (“Industrial relations policies” n.d.). Gardens helped prevent “the despair and discouragement that is particularly dangerous to the morale of not only the workers and their families but also of the community as a whole” (ibid.). Together with other company welfare programs, the hope was that gardens would reinforce “the basic elements of harmony and cooperation in industry” (“Confidential memorandum” 1932).

For Cyrus McCormick Jr. (Reference McCormick1932: 64), Harvester’s past president, the gardens inspired visions of a new alliance between labor and capital. If gardens became permanent, employees could “work on the land for food as well as at their jobs for wages.” A Harvester plant manager, however, was more realistic. “Most of them couldn’t be turned into part-time truck gardeners, even if you gave them the tools and the land free,” he noted. “Let them get back to the regular pay envelope and they won’t ever look at a hoe again” (Miller Reference Miller1932).

Harvester’s experiments fed into broader thinking about social policy and possible alternative alliances. After the garden’s first season, Harvester’s president joined a committee of industry and labor leaders to discuss unemployment relief and report to President Hoover. They met in Chicago, immediately after the Illinois Manufacturers Association released a report declaring voluntary, company-run relief projects to be preferable to state-mandated unemployment insurance (“Job committee named by Hoover” 1931). According to the committee chairman, the goal was “jobs, not the dole”; industry would address the economic crisis as “a matter of enlightened self-interest” (Kinsley Reference Kinsley1931). This approach played to President Hoover, who was keen to promote self-help and reluctant to involve the federal government in welfare provision (Katz Reference Katz1996: 222). The committee report to Hoover called for “a special emergency measure”—surveying “the possibility for transfer of surplus labor from cities to farms, on a work-for-keep and/or other basis, with a view to … relieve pressure upon urban relief agencies” (President’s Organization on Unemployment Relief 1931).

The next spring, Harvester began advising officials in Chicago on how to set up public relief gardens (“Plan gardens for jobless” 1932; “Start plowing 3,000 acres” 1932). The Cook County Subsistence Garden Service took the lead. Public agencies and private owners donated land on the city’s outskirts. Harvester provided five tractors. In 1932, the service made available 1,121 plots; by 1935, this had increased to nearly 9,000 (Cook County Subsistence Garden Service 1935; Gardener Reference Gardener1935). The county also ran a farm where men from Chicago’s shelters grew food for their shelters’ kitchens.

Allotting land to gardeners was not costless. Finding gardeners created a burden for relief agencies, so the garden service shifted its own staff from preparing plots to recruiting relief recipients. For use of a plot, people had nine dollars deducted from their relief allowance; in 1935 this was cut to four dollars. Getting people to the gardens became the single biggest expense: the service paid for transit fare and arranged vehicles to take growers from the end of rail lines to the fields. Yet even as the garden service reduced barriers, growers still “defaulted” on their plots, failing to complete planting.

Nevertheless, the service saw the gardens as a good investment. Officials meticulously tallied their value. For 1934, they estimated that the total value of garden produce, at wholesale prices, was $69,799.22—or about $1.25 million, in 2018 dollars (Cook County Subsistence Garden Service 1935: 25; Williamson Reference Williamson2018). Each dollar invested produced $2.74 worth of food.

The service focused on how gardens boosted morale. In the 1934 annual report, economic figures were buried at the back. The report opened with stories of hope and joy: a widow who “forgot myself and my troubles”; a “colored man” who said it was hard at first, “but the ha’vest in fall made it wo’th wo’king fo’”; and a German gardener who exclaimed “it was so good to work in the soil.” The report proposed opening more farms to “aid in solving the morale problem” of the thousands living in shelters.

As before, the gardens fed hopes that unemployed workers might be inspired to leave the city. As president-elect, Franklin Roosevelt observed that a migration of millions of the urban unemployed to the country might be needed to end the economic crisis (“City idle must go to country” 1933). In response, Chicago’s civic leaders pitched grand plans. One proposed that tax-delinquent rural farmers cede title to ten or twenty acres, which the state could allot to urban workers on a rent-to-own basis (Kinsley Reference Kinsley1933). Another argued for resettling some of Cook County’s 800,000 relief recipients to homesteads just outside the city, allowing them to still seek part-time or full-time work (“Chicago considers land colonization plan” 1933). William Dodd (Reference Dodd1933), a prominent University of Chicago history professor, observed in the Tribune that “free lands” had repeatedly been the solution to mass unemployment before 1900, when the frontier was closed. The state could effectively create a new frontier, he noted, and allow the unemployed to again leave cities for the country.

These plans drew critics. An agricultural economist argued in the Tribune that competition from homesteaders would bankrupt commercial growers, turning them into peasants (Hibbard Reference Hibbard1933). Another letter to the editor agreed: homesteaders on ten acres “would be reduced to working by hand,” marking “the first step toward American peasantry” (Davis Reference Davis1933). Yet with the creation in 1934 of the federal subsistence homesteading program, it appeared, at least briefly, that allotting gardens to unemployed Chicagoans might help spark a migration to the country. “For the successful relief gardener,” the county garden service (Cook County Subsistence Garden Service 1934: 44) noted, a plot “may well become the proving ground for him to take a subsistence homestead.”

Even as new alliances and visions were emerging to use gardens as a stepping stone to shift the unemployed out of the city, they faced opposition from rural growers. The garden service’s 1934 report opened with a letter from US Agriculture Secretary Henry Wallace to the Vegetable Growers Association of America. Wallace explained that although vegetable farmers faced surpluses, several million families were out of work, out of money, and suffering for lack of food. Wallace assured commercial growers that relief gardeners did not have much purchasing power. “What few fresh vegetables they can raise in their free time,” he wrote, “help out their food problem without affecting the market for your growers practically at all.” Moreover, the government prohibited sales of garden produce. “This whole movement is to be viewed as an emergency proposition,” he concluded; “when the emergency is over, most of these families will probably go out of the gardening and will be buyers of more fresh vegetables than before.” The past offered a guide: “That was the way it worked out after the war, and that is doubtless the way it will work this time” (ibid. 43).

In 1935, Cook County’s gardens drew more growers than ever. The Depression’s worst years had passed, but unemployment rates remained dire. Nationally, unemployment had fallen to around 20 percent in 1935, from a peak of nearly 25 percent a few years earlier (Lebergott Reference Lebergott1948). In Chicago, African American unemployment remained particularly bad. Nearly half of African American domestic servants, one-third of semiskilled workers, and one-quarter of the unskilled remained jobless in 1935 (Drake and Caton Reference Drake and Caton2015 [1945]: 217).

Nevertheless, state officials abruptly canceled garden projects. Early in 1935, Congress had appropriated money for a federal relief program, and President Roosevelt created the Works Progress Administration (WPA). This would replace the Federal Emergency Relief Agency, which had provided federal aid for state and local gardening programs. The WPA had grand plans for Chicago: spending $32 million to build 1,000 miles of road thus creating jobs for 108,000 people on county relief rolls (“Order WPA staff geared up” 1935). In September, the Illinois Emergency Relief Committee met and eliminated subsistence garden programs, “in view of the employment program of the WPA” (“Relief economy shakeup” 1935).

The end of public support for relief gardens reflected broader trends. Under Roosevelt, the federal government was taking a rapidly expanding role in funding and coordinating relief (Katz Reference Katz1996: 224–28). This included the creation of federally funded relief jobs, which made locally coordinated use-based welfare projects appear unnecessary. Rather than give the unemployed access to land, local governments would instead contribute land for federally funded infrastructure projects. Moreover, federal agencies had begun experimenting with using surplus agricultural commodities as welfare supports (Finegold Reference Finegold, Weir, Orloff and Skocpol1988). This helped both rural producers and urban consumers who might otherwise oppose higher food prices. In 1937, when the program that would become known as food stamps was created, all remaining federal funding for relief gardens was cut (Lawson Reference Lawson2005: 160). Use-based welfare had reemerged and blossomed under Hoover. But with Roosevelt’s creation of federally funded income supports, this local form of social provision once again dried up and disappeared.

Discussion

When both land and laborers are laying idle, conditions are ripe for efforts to bring them together. Use-based welfare has emerged when social reformers created programs to broker land access, granting the poor the ability to use vacant land. This has required gaining the cooperation of property owners—often through assurances that such schemes will be voluntary, temporary, and cost saving.

The Chicago case illustrates how use-based welfare has been posed as both a complement to and a substitute for income supports. Promoters promised that by letting the needy use land, projects could reduce reliance on public relief. Although Harvester briefly conditioned eligibility for income supports on growing a garden, public garden projects in Chicago differed from other cities in that they never created such a condition. Ultimately, when the federal government expanded income supports, this was seen as a substitute for reallocating the use of land and public relief gardens disappeared from Chicago’s landscape.

The Chicago case also illustrates how a limited experiment can scale up. Successful private charity projects led to offers of land from other private owners, then to use of public land. Responsibility for coordinating garden projects migrated from private organizations to municipal agencies. In the process, the work requirement and supervision integral to use-based welfare also migrated from private and corporate relief projects—where they might be expected—to become part of public welfare programs. As the practice of sharing land use spread, promoters came to see temporary, experimental projects as first steps toward entrenching use-based welfare as a permanent social policy institution and an enduring feature of the urban landscape.

The experience in Chicago suggests reasons why use-based welfare, unlike other forms of social policy, has failed to become entrenched. Three factors stand out. First, it was challenging to implement projects that reallocated the use of land. Second, attempts to decommodify land and food met opposition. Third, reformers failed to mobilize a movement to defend land access. I address each factor in turn.

Implementation Challenges

Letting the unemployed use idle land might seem straightforward. If an owner isn’t using land, why shouldn’t others? Get permission from owners and let the needy start planting gardens. Or, as Boughner might suggest, don’t ask permission and start planting anyway.

Yet this mode of redistribution has significant costs and challenges. Even during downturns, land is scarce. Searching for available land, locating owners, and gaining permission takes time and effort. Available land might not be near potential users. It may need improvements to be suitable for agriculture. Matching land with gardeners can entail costly transportation subsidies.

Recruiting gardeners could also be challenging. This wasn’t the case for Hull House, where people lined up to claim the few hundred available gardens. But during the Depression, county officials struggled to attract thousands of gardeners to plots on Chicago’s outskirts.

Organizers couldn’t always assume people knew how to grow food. The CGA found that immigrants from Italy or Bohemia had growing skills. During the Depression, however, many prospective gardeners had to be trained. Insufficient supervision could increase the risk that investments in seeds and land would go to waste.

Requiring the needy to work the land also created challenges. Other than their focus on European immigrants (cf. Fox Reference Fox2010), the fact that private relief involved a work requirement was, for the Progressive Era, not atypical. During the Depression, a work requirement and supervision made sense for firms like International Harvester, which aimed not only to cut the costs of relief but also to keep laid-off employees in the company fold and working under foremen.

But when use-based welfare migrated to public relief projects, the work requirement created problems. The county garden service struggled to keep gardeners from abandoning their plots. Gardening was hard work, which many gardeners apparently came to see as more burden than benefit. Unlike elsewhere, in Chicago gardening was not required to be eligible for cash benefits. Gardeners could abandon their plots and only lose the fee deducted from their benefits, rather than losing cash benefits entirely.

Getting the needy to support themselves appealed to Chicago’s social reformers and relief officials. But use-based welfare proved difficult in practice. Given the costs and challenges of redistributing the use of land, one can appreciate why relief officials and policy makers might find income-based supports funded through tax and transfer more appealing.

Opposition

Use-based welfare threatens the status of land and food as commodities. During both the Progressive Era and the Great Depression, this did not initially provoke opposition—privately coordinated projects were considered experimental and temporary. This created momentary alliances between landowners and social reformers. These experiments inspired visions of how new forms of cooperation might reshape relations between firms and employees, or between landowners, the unemployed, and relief agencies. But ultimately, despite these visions—from Pelham and Tribune editors to Cyrus McCormick and Hoover’s committee of business leaders—these alternative alliances unraveled, without producing the type of policy feedback that in other contexts has produced enduring institutions (Weir et al. Reference Weir, Orloff, Skocpol, Weir, Orloff and Skocpol1988).

Instead, just when experiments began to transform into publicly coordinated relief programs, and to inspire visions of permanent use of land to support the poor, they met opposition. In part, this opposition confirms what an urban sociologist might expect. Temporary projects may be promoted as ways to avoid increased taxation, by preventing reliance on public relief. But to do this in the long term invites attempts to entrench and institutionalize use-based welfare. That means adjusting property rules, either to make some private land permanently public (as in Jensen’s plan) or to restrict all private owners’ right to exclude (as in Boughner’s proposed rule). Such proposals to decommodify land can trigger pushback from an urban growth coalition (Logan and Molotch Reference Logan and Molotch1987)—the constellation of actors, including elected officials, landowners, and newspapers, invested in increasing land values.

The experience of the Great Depression points to another source of opposition—which might be missed by focusing on cities, but overlooking their links to the country (Angelo and Wachsmuth Reference Angelo and Wachsmuth2015; Williams Reference Williams1973). Large-scale relief gardens intervene in the political economy of food. Individuals and groups representing rural growers feared Depression-era gardens would destabilize already-precarious agricultural markets, both by offering food outside the market and by inspiring plans to lure the urban unemployed to the country. During this period, opposition primarily came from rural producers, not from urban landowners and their allies. The substitution of new supports funded by tax and transfer returned urban residents to their role as consumers, shoring up the market for agricultural commodities.

Nonmobilization

Although initial experiments scaled up and inspired visions of a new, permanent form of support for the poor, no movement seems to have appeared to defend land access when plans faced opposition. Labor and social movement pressure have been key to institutionalizing other forms of social policy, helping both realize new rights and entrench existing ones by reshaping beneficiaries’ preferences and policy makers’ sense of the politically feasible. Why was the experience of use-based welfare in Chicago different?

Several factors likely hampered mobilization. First, as mentioned previously, many gardeners appear to have been ambivalent. They did not eagerly move to the country, as Pelham hoped. Managers at Harvester acknowledged that if laid-off workers could again earn a salary, they would happily leave their hoes behind. County officials struggled to keep gardeners from abandoning their plots. Ambivalence is not fertile ground for growing a social movement.

Nor did labor unions champion garden projects. Indeed, Harvester supported gardens precisely because they aligned with its corporate welfare policy—designed to preempt labor organizing (Katz Reference Katz1996: 92–97). Pelham’s dream of increasing labor power didn’t bear fruit, and she doesn’t appear to have found allies in organized labor.

Finally, the legal relationship at play in use-based welfare likely undercut the potential for mobilization. Proponents of use-based welfare acted as brokers, asking landowners to grant gardeners a license to use their property. This contrasts with mobilizing popular pressure to demand rights and resources from the state. In Chicago, the people who took on the role of broker were often elite social reformers (such as Laura Dainty Pelham) or representatives of owners (such as company welfare bureaus). The success of any particular deal turned on a landowner’s agreement to grant use of a specific parcel. This may have dissuaded brokers from acting as organizers: popular pressure to maintain land access might have made landowners skittish. Pelham, recall, had to assuage landowners’ concerns that letting the needy use land would encourage disrespect for property. During neither period did brokers appear to mobilize gardeners to lobby for continued political support for land access—a mechanism by which contemporary reformers have maintained funding for social services (Marwell Reference Marwell2004) and the poor have secured use of public land in Latin American cities (Holland Reference Holland2017).

The fact that urban gardening can be scaled up through deals brokered by well-connected social reformers, rather than through popular demands, may mean that when use-based welfare faces opposition, there is no existing movement or constituency ready to defend the privilege to use land. Compared to other forms of social policy that emerge through popular demands for rights, this could make use-based welfare less likely to have a ratchet effect, and more susceptible to retrenchment.

Taken together, the challenges of implementing use-based welfare, along with its natural opponents and stumbling blocks to mobilization, help to explain why it has repeatedly failed to become an enduring urban institution. Since the Great Depression, income supports and social services have dominated the field of social policy. We no longer conceive of access to resources, particularly land, as a form of redistributive social policy.

In parts of Chicago and other US cities, however, conditions appear ripe for the reemergence of use-based welfare. High rates of unemployment and poverty, together with an abundance of vacant lots, resemble conditions that have historically prompted a turn to this longstanding form of social policy. In Chicago’s Englewood neighborhood, for example, recent surveys suggest nearly half of households live in poverty and more than one-third of adults are unemployed (City of Chicago Data Portal 2016; Illinois Action for Children 2016). Meanwhile, the city counted some 4,500 vacant lots in the neighborhood (City of Chicago 2014: 12). In 2014, the city council designated Englewood as Chicago’s first urban agriculture district. This has focused city agencies and local foundations on finding land for farms that will offer job skills training for the unemployed, and the possibility for urban farmers to earn supplemental income.

To make land available to growers, promoters of urban agriculture are again experimenting with property. In 2011, Chicago amended its zoning code to permit large-scale commercial farming. A land trust created to protect community gardens has expanded its mission, and now leases vacant lots to nonprofit farms (Ela Reference Ela2016: 282–84). Organizers in Englewood have created a new community land trust to lease land to for-profit farmers (Urban Farm Pathways Project 2015).

History, of course, is not simply repeating itself. Projects today are cropping up in an urban terrain that has transformed radically since the Great Depression. Rather than suffering temporary setbacks due to economic recessions, neighborhoods like Englewood have lost jobs and residents for decades, as a result of deindustrialization and the flight of whites and then African Americans to the suburbs. The organizational and institutional forms emerging in this landscape—social enterprise farms, together with zoning and land trusts for urban agriculture—propose to make farms an enduring feature of neighborhoods where investment in housing, commerce, and industry has largely dried up.

This apparent return to use-based welfare, though still nascent, aligns with decades of efforts to reform and restrict the welfare state. This reform project has created work requirements for income supports and social services; sought to restrain federal funding for welfare supports; and turned on a renewed argument that reliance on welfare leads to immorality and dependence. As federal politicians seek to restrain federal support for income-based welfare, use-based welfare offers municipal reformers a means of supporting the poor and redistributing resources while making them contingent on work. The shift from federal to local supports is paired with a shift from public relief toward social support delivered by private nonprofit organizations, which receive both grants and free public land.

While the institutions and organizations of contemporary urban agriculture are new, the legal and political-economic instinct is familiar: achieve redistribution by reallocating the right to use and benefit from land, rather than through tax and transfer. The reemergence of use-based welfare frames it as a complement, rather than a substitute, to other supports. Today’s urban farms are not imagined as a means of subsistence or an alternative to income supports. Instead they are proposed as sites for summer programming for at-risk youth, and job training for the unemployed, as part of efforts to help people support themselves through employment, rather than rely on social assistance.

Is use-based welfare a social policy path not taken? One might read the shift to federally funded income supports in 1935 as a definitive shift to redistribution grounded in tax and transfer. Yet while use-based welfare has repeatedly failed to become entrenched, it has also repeatedly reemerged. It may be doing so again today, as reformers in Chicago and beyond look to use land as a support for the urban poor and unemployed. Recognizing the longstanding and ongoing interconnections between social policy and land use challenges sociologists to see beyond the horizons of disciplinary subfields. Doing so offers a new perspective on how urban institutions have supported diverse forms of redistributive social policy—and points to parallels between a longstanding practice and ongoing transformations to the landscapes of American cities.

Archival Sources

Michigan State University Archives, Perry G. Holden Papers.

The “Chicago garden campaign” scrapbook, kept by Holden and his staff, includes the newspaper articles from 1917 and 1918, listed in “Anonymous Newspaper and Magazine Articles.”

Wisconsin Historical Society, McCormick-International Harvester collection:

Conference on Welfare Work at Chicago Commons, Minutes of the Fifth Meeting, May 1, 1906. Series 2C, Box 40.

Conference on Welfare Work at Chicago Commons, Minutes of the Eleventh Meeting, June 12, 1906. Series 2C, Box 40.

Confidential memorandum concerning relief activities of the International Harvester Company, June 1, 1932. McCormick Collection, Box 714.

“Industrial relations policies of the International Harvester Company,” n.d. McCormick Collection, Box 714.

Footnotes

Versions of this paper were presented at the American Sociology Association Economic Sociology Section’s 2016 preconference workshop and at a 2017 ASA session on the welfare state. I am grateful for comments at those gatherings, as well as from participants in the Economic Sociology Workshop at the University of Wisconsin–Madison and the Boston College Environmental Sociology Working Group, and from the anonymous reviewers. Special thanks are due to Meghan Morris and Erik Olin Wright. This research has received support from the Social Science Research Council, the National Science Foundation, and the Lincoln Institute for Land Policy.

1. For example, under the 1996 Welfare Reform Act, US states had the option to fund Individual Development Accounts.

2. Meanwhile, the absence of a demand for rights has been used to explain the nonemergence of social policy (Levitsky Reference Levitsky2014).

3. Use-based welfare might seem to improve Pareto efficiency by increasing one person’s welfare without subtracting from that of others (Posner Reference Posner2014: 14). But as we will see, landowners may differ concerning whether ceding use rights negatively affects their interests.

4 Holden’s annotation appears next to the article “Lack of funds may end garden bureau,” Chicago Herald, May 15, 1917, in the “Chicago garden campaign” scrapbook, 115. Perry G. Holden Papers, Michigan State University Archives.

5 Paul Potter (Reference Potter1931) “Home gardens again favored as in war days.” CDT, May 3.

6 Pelham died in 1924; Jensen, after being fired by the park district, turned to work for private clients.

References

Anonymous Newspaper and Magazine Articles

“A city full of gardens.” Country Life in America, May 1916: 90–96, 93–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
“Association of commerce as garden chief.” Chicago Daily Tribune, May 2, 1917.Google Scholar
“A use for vacant lots.” Chicago Daily Tribune, October 21, 1909.Google Scholar
“‘Back to the soil’ cure.” Chicago Daily Tribune, June 5, 1910.Google Scholar
“Business men aid garden idea.” Chicago Herald, March 23, 1917.Google Scholar
“Chicago considers land colonization plan.” New York Times, April 9, 1933.Google Scholar
“Chicago to be just one park after another.” Chicago Daily Tribune, November 27, 1919.Google Scholar
“City ‘farms’ for the poor.” Chicago Daily Tribune, May 26, 1912.Google Scholar
“City idle must go to country: F. D. Roosevelt.” Chicago Daily Tribune, January 17, 1933.Google Scholar
“City urged to conscript lots for gardeners.” Chicago Daily Tribune, April 18, 1917Google Scholar
“Demand very great for gardening space.” Chicago Post, April 18, 1917.Google Scholar
“Gardening in the garden city.” Chicago Daily Tribune, January 4, 1910.Google Scholar
“Gardens for the poor lesson to women.” Chicago Daily Tribune, October 20, 1909.Google Scholar
“Gardens get mayor’s room.” Chicago News, March 21, 1917.Google Scholar
“Gardens given to the poor.” Chicago Daily Tribune, April 4, 1910.Google Scholar
“Harvester’s relief and garden plans.” Industrial Relations 3 (8): 398–402, August 1932.Google Scholar
“Job committee named by Hoover will meet today.” Chicago Daily Tribune, September 28, 1931.Google Scholar
“Lack of funds may end garden bureau.” Chicago Herald, May 15, 1917.Google Scholar
“Mass meeting gives gardens a big boost.” Chicago News, March 16, 1917.Google Scholar
“Mayor asks city heads to be farmers.” Chicago American, April 18, 1917.Google Scholar
“Motorcycles to aid gardens.” Chicago Journal, April 2, 1917.Google Scholar
“Order WPA staff geared up for rush of work.” Chicago Daily Tribune, September 14, 1935.Google Scholar
“Poor of city get 90 acres to till.” Chicago Daily Tribune, March 24, 1909.Google Scholar
“Plan gardens for jobless in county forests.” Chicago Daily Tribune, April 20, 1932.Google Scholar
“Predicts riots.” Chicago Daily Tribune, April 14, 1917.Google Scholar
“Sanitary body quick to vote small farms.” Chicago Daily Tribune, March 19, 1915.Google Scholar
“Start plowing 3,000 acres for relief gardens.” Chicago Daily Tribune, May 6, 1932.Google Scholar
“The People’s Friendly Club.” Hull House Bulletin VII (1): 14 (1905–6).Google Scholar
“Toilers to farm empty city lots.” Chicago Daily Tribune, April 15, 1912.Google Scholar
“Uses small farm to lure city people to country.” Chicago Daily Tribune, March 21, 1910.Google Scholar
“US facing famine, is warning.” Chicago American, April 4, 1917.Google Scholar
“World improves, says Kropotkin.” Chicago Daily Tribune, April 18, 1901.Google Scholar

References

Ackerman, Bruce, and Alstott, Anne (2000) The Stakeholder Society. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Alexander, Gregory (2009) “The social-obligation norm in American property law.” Cornell Law Review 94 (4): 745819.Google Scholar
Allard, Scott W., and Small, Mario L. (2013) “Reconsidering the urban disadvantaged: The role of systems, institutions, and organizations.” ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 647 (1): 620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Allen, Patricia (2008) “Mining for justice in the food system: Perceptions, practices, and possibilities.” Agriculture and Human Values 25 (2): 157161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angelo, Hillary, and Wachsmuth, David (2015) “Urbanizing urban political ecology: A critique of methodological cityism.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 39 (1): 1627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Armitage, David (2012) “John Locke: Theorist of empire?,” in Muthu, Sankar (ed.) Empire and Modern Political Thought. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 84111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Avrich, Paul (1980) “Kropotkin in America.” International Review of Social History 25 (1): 134.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartley, Tim (2007) “Institutional emergence in an era of globalization: The rise of transnational private regulation of labor and environmental conditions.” American Journal of Sociology 113 (2): 297351.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burchardt, Jeremy (2002) The Allotment Movement in England, 17931873. London: The Royal Historical Society.Google Scholar
Bureau of Associated Charities (1898) Fourth Annual Report.Google Scholar
Bynner, John, and Despotidou, Sofia (2001) “The effects of assets on life chances.” London: Center for Longitudinal Studies, Institute for Education.Google Scholar
Bynner, John, and Paxton, Will (2001) The Asset-Effect. London: Institute for Public Policy Research.Google Scholar
Carroll, Charles E. (1912) “Industrial peace through social justice.” Master’s thesis, University of Nebraska, Lincoln.Google Scholar
Cho, Esther Y. (1999) “The effects of assets on the economic well-being of women after marital disruption.” Center for Social Development Working Paper No. 99-6, Saint Louis, MO: Center for Social Development, Washington University in Saint Louis.Google Scholar
Cialdella, Joseph Stanhope (2014) “A landscape of ruin and repair: Parks, potatoes, and Detroit’s environmental past, 1879–1900.” Michigan Historical Review 40 (1): 4972.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
City of Chicago (2013) “A recipe for healthy places.”Google Scholar
City of Chicago (2014) “Green healthy neighborhoods.”Google Scholar
City of Chicago Data Portal (2016) “Census data: Selected socioeconomic indicators in Chicago, 2008–2012.”Google Scholar
Coase, Ronald H. (1960) “The problem of social cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colcord, Joanna C., and Johnston, Mary (1933) Community Programs for Subsistence Gardens. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Committee on Interstate and Foreign Commerce, US House of Representatives (1921–22) Hearings on H.R. 9049, H.R. 8648, and S. 3177, Declaring Portions of the Chicago River to be Non-Navigable. 67th Cong., 2d Sess., December 15, 192l; May 19, 1922; October 6 and 7, 1922.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. (1893) The Distribution of Wealth. New York: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Cook County Subsistence Garden Service (1935) Annual Report 1934. February 7.Google Scholar
Cronon, William (1983) Changes in the Land: Indians, Colonists, and the Ecology of New England. New York: Hill and Wang.Google Scholar
Cronon, William (1991) Nature’s Metropolis: Chicago and the Great West. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Dauber, Michele Landis (2013) The Sympathetic State: Disaster Relief and the Origins of the American Welfare State. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Davis, H. G. (1933) “Peasantry.” Chicago Daily Tribune, February 14.Google Scholar
de Soto, Hernando (2000) The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. London: Bantam.Google Scholar
Dodd, William E. (1933) “Back-to-the-land?,” Chicago Daily Tribune, March 19.Google Scholar
Drake, St. Clair, and Caton, Horace R. (2015 [1945]) Black Metropolis: A Study of Negro Life in a Northern City. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Earl, Jennifer, Martin, Andrew, McCarthy, John D., and Soule, Sarah A. (2004) “The use of newspaper data in the study of collective action.” Annual Review of Sociology 30: 6580.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ela, Nate (2016) “Urban commons as property experiment: Mapping Chicago’s farms and gardens.” Fordham Urban Law Journal 43 (2): 247–94.Google Scholar
Emirbayer, Mustafa (1997) “Manifesto for a relational sociology.” American Journal of Sociology 103 (2): 281317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esping-Anderson, Gosta (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Evans, W. A. (1913) “Farming in the city.” Chicago Daily Tribune, May 25.Google Scholar
Evans, W. A. (1915) “How to keep well.” Chicago Daily Tribune, May 25.Google Scholar
Fels, Mary (1920) Joseph Fels: His Life-Work. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Finegold, Kenneth (1988) “Agriculture and the politics of US social provision: Social insurance and food stamps,” in Weir, Margaret, Orloff, Ann Shola, and Skocpol, Theda (eds.) The Politics of Social Policy in the United States. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press: 88122.Google Scholar
Flyvberg, Bent (2006) “Five misunderstandings about case-study research.” Qualitative Inquiry 12 (2): 219–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fox, Cybelle (2010) “Three worlds of relief: Race, immigration, and public and private social welfare spending in American cities, 1929.” American Journal of Sociology 116 (2): 453502.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gallagher, Mari (2006) “Examining the impact of food deserts on public health in Chicago.” Chicago: Mari Gallagher Research and Consulting Group.Google Scholar
Gardener, Virginia (1935) “Speed planting in 900 acres of relief gardens.” Chicago Daily Tribune, June 1.Google Scholar
Gilbert, Paul T. (1914) “Vacant lot gardening.” Western Christian Advocate, September 16.Google Scholar
Green, James (2006) Death in the Haymarket. New York: Pantheon.Google Scholar
Hale, Robert Lee (1923) “Coercion and distribution in a supposedly non-coercive state.” Political Science Quarterly 38: 470–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Bolton (1908) A Little Land and a Living. New York: Arcadia Press.Google Scholar
Hawkins, L.A. (n.d.) “Harvester employee garden project.” Wisconsin Historical Society, McCormick-International Harvester collection, Box 738.Google Scholar
Haydu, Jeffery (1998) “Making use of the past: Time periods as cases to compare and as sequences of problem solving.” American Journal of Sociology 104 (2): 339–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hibbard, Benjamin Horace (1933) “Back to the land?,” Chicago Daily Tribune, June 18.Google Scholar
Hohfeld, Wesley (1913) “Some fundamental legal conceptions as applied in judicial reasoning.” Yale Law Journal 23 (4): 1659.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holden, P. G. (1917) “Gardens on vacant lots could feed half of city.” Chicago Examiner, March 7.Google Scholar
Holland, Alisha C. (2017) Forbearance as Redistribution: The Politics of Informal Welfare in Latin America. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, Evelyn, and Stephens, John D. (2001) Development and Crisis of the Welfare State: Parties and Policies in Global Markets. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyde, Henry M. (1913) “Sample gardens in public parks for city ‘farmer.’” Chicago Daily Tribune, October 3.Google Scholar
Hyde, Henry M. (1915a) “Plans to put idle on farms are under way.” Chicago Daily Tribune, February 18.Google Scholar
Hyde, Henry M. (1915b) “Sanitary body quick to vote small farms.” Chicago Daily Tribune, March 19.Google Scholar
Illinois Action for Children (2016) “Key indicators of need for Chicago communities,” www.actforchildren.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/04/CCA-Community-Profiles-Combined-Spring-2016.pdf (accessed July 6, 2018).Google Scholar
Jefferson, Thomas (1986 [1785]) Letter to James Madison, October 28, 1785, in Kurland, Philip B. and Lerner, Ralph (eds.) The Founders’ Constitution. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Jensen, Jens (1990 [1939]) Siftings. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Katz, Michael B. (1996) In the Shadow of the Poorhouse: A Social History of Welfare in America. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Kinsley, Philip (1931) “Jobs not dole, slogan as Hoover group debates relief measures in Chicago.” Chicago Daily Tribune, September 29.Google Scholar
Kinsley, Philip (1933) “General Bolles offers plan for retreat to land.” Chicago Daily Tribune, February 10.Google Scholar
Kropotkin, Pëtr (1912 [1898]) Fields, Factories and Workshops. London: Thomas Nelson & Sons.Google Scholar
Lawson, Laura J. (2005) City Bountiful: A Century of Community Gardening in America. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lebergott, Stanley (1948) “Labor force, employment, and unemployment 1929-39: Estimating methods.” Monthly Labor Review 67 (1): 5053.Google Scholar
Levitsky, Sandra (2014) Caring for Our Own: Why There Is No Political Demand for New American Social Welfare Rights. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Locke, John (1980 [1690]) Second Treatise of Government, Macpherson, C. B. (ed.). Indianapolis, IN: Hackett.Google Scholar
Logan, John, and Molotch, Harvey (1987) Urban Fortunes: The Political Economy of Place. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Lyson, Helena C. (2014) “Social structural location and vocabularies of participation: Fostering a collective identity in urban agriculture activism.” Rural Sociology 79 (3): 310–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mandell, Nikki (2002) The Corporation as Family: The Gendering of Corporate Welfare, 1890–1930. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Marwell, Nicole (2004) “Privatizing the welfare state: Nonprofit community-based organizations as political actors.” American Sociological Review 69 (2): 265–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marx, Karl (1975 [1842]) “Proceedings of the sixth Rhine province assembly. Third article. Debates on the law on thefts of wood,” in Karl Marx and Frederick Engels: Collected Works, Vol. 1. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
McClintock, Nathan (2013) “Radical, reformist, and garden-variety neoliberal: Coming to terms with urban agriculture’s contradictions.” Local Environment 19 (2): 147–71 doi: 10.1080/13549839.2012.752797.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCormick, Cyrus Jr (1932) “Productive gardens for the unemployed.” House and Garden 63 (6): 5253, 63–64.Google Scholar
Miller, Ronald (1932) “It’s harvest time for Chicago’s new army of city farmers.” Sunday Illustrated Times, October 9.Google Scholar
Mortensen, Dale T. (1988) “Matching: Finding a partner for life or otherwise.” American Journal of Sociology 94 (Supplement): S215S240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nilsen, Micheline (2014) The Working Man’s Green Space: Allotment Gardens in England, France, and Germany, 1870–1919. Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press.Google Scholar
O’Connor, Julia S., Orloff, Ann Shola, and Shaver, Sheila (1999) States, Markets, Families: Gender, Liberalism, and Social Policy in Australia, Canada, Great Britain, and the United States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pelham, Laura Dainty (1909) “The Chicago City Gardens Association.” The Survey: Social, Charitable, Civic 22 (1): 423–25.Google Scholar
Pingree, H. S. (1895) “Food for the poor.” Chicago Daily Tribune, April 1Google Scholar
Piven, Frances Fox, and Cloward, Richard A. (1977) Poor People’s Movements: Why They Succeed, How they Fail. New York: Vintage Books.Google Scholar
Posner, Richard A. (2014) The Economic Analysis of Law, 9th ed. New York: Aspen.Google Scholar
Potter, Paul (1931) “Home gardens again Favored as in war daysChicago Daily Tribune, May 3, p. A11.Google Scholar
President’s Organization on Unemployment Relief (1931) Press Release, October 29; reproduced in Monthly Labor Review 33 (6): 77–78.Google Scholar
Price, C. W. (1907) Outline of talk on “Opportunity for recreation and social life” at Chicago Institute of Social Science, April 15. Wisconsin Historical Society, McCormick-International Harvester collection.Google Scholar
Reider, Edith S. (1915) “With our Harvester gardeners.” Harvester World 6 (3): 23.Google Scholar
Salamon, Lester M. (1995) Partners in Public Service: Government-Nonprofit Relations in the Modern Welfare State. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Sanitary District of Chicago (1906) Proceedings of the Board of Trustees, March 14.Google Scholar
Satter, Beryl (2009) Family Properties: Race, Real Estate, and the Exploitation of Black Urban America. New York: Metropolitan.Google Scholar
Sherraden, Michael (1991) Assets and the Poor: A New American Welfare Policy. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
Singer, Joseph (2000) “Property and social relations: From title to entitlement,” in Geisler, Charles and Daneker, Gail (eds.) Property and Values: Alternatives to Public and Private Ownership. Washington, DC: Island Press: 319.Google Scholar
Singer, Joseph (2001) The Edges of the Field: Lessons on the Obligations of Ownership. Boston: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Small, Mario Luis (2006) “Neighborhood institutions as resource brokers: Childcare centers, interorganizational ties, and resource access among the poor.” Social Problems 53 (2): 274–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Small, Mario Luis (2007) “Is there such a thing as ‘the ghetto’?City 11 (3): 413–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Dorothy E. (2005) Institutional Ethnography: A Sociology for People. Lanham, MD: AltaMira Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Henry E. (2012) “Property as the law of things.” Harvard Law Review 125 (7): 16911726.Google Scholar
Smith, Steven, and Lipsky, Michael (1995) Nonprofits for Hire: The Welfare State in the Age of Contracting. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sunstein, Cass R. (1996) “Social norms and social roles.” Columbia Law Review 96 (4): 903–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thomas, William I., and Znaniecki, Florian (1920) The Polish Peasant in Europe and America, Volume V: Organization and Disorganization in America. Boston: Richard D. Badger.Google Scholar
US Department of Commerce (1932) “Subsistence Gardens.”Google Scholar
Urban Farm Pathways Project (2015) “Englewood community farms prospectus and business plan,” www.foodlandopportunity.org/downloads/Englewood_Prospectus_Business-Plan.pdf (accessed July 6, 2018).Google Scholar
Voicu, Ioan, and Been, Vicki (2008) “The effect of community gardens on neighboring property values.” Real Estate Economics 36 (2): 241–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walley, Christine J. (2013) Exit Zero: Family and Class in Postindustrial Chicago. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Weber, Max (2001 [1930]) The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Weir, Margaret, Orloff, Ann Shola, and Skocpol, Theda (1988) “Understanding American social politics,” in Weir, Margaret, Orloff, Ann Shola, and Skocpol, Theda (eds.) The Politics of Social Policy in the United States. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press: 327.Google Scholar
West Chicago Park Commissioners (1920) A Greater West Park System: After the Plans of Jens Jensen. Chicago: West Park Commission.Google Scholar
White, Monica M. (2011) “Sisters of the soil: Urban gardening as resistance in Detroit.” Race/Ethnicity: Multidisciplinary Global Contexts 5 (1): 1328.Google Scholar
Williams, Raymond (1973) The Country and the City. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Samuel H. (2018) “Seven ways to compute the relative value of a US dollar amount, 1774 to present,” www.measuringworth.com/calculators/uscompare (accessed July 3, 2018).Google Scholar
Winstanley, Gerrard (1649) “The true levellers standard advanced: Or, the state of community opened, and presented to the sons of men,” www.marxists.org/reference/archive/winstanley/1649/levellers-standard.htm (accessed July 3, 2018).Google Scholar
Wolford, Wendy (2007) “Land reform in the time of neoliberalism: A many-splendored thing.” Antipode 39 (3): 550–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, Arthur (1801) An Inquiry into the Propriety of Applying Wastes to the Better Maintenance and Support of the Poor. Angel Hill, UK: J. Rackham.Google Scholar
Figure 0

TABLE 1. Four modes of welfare provision