Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-x24gv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-01T23:02:18.734Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Authority matters: propaganda and the coevolution of behaviour and attitudes

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 October 2022

Sergey Gavrilets*
Affiliation:
Department of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology, Department of Mathematics, Center for the Dynamics of Social Complexity, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996, USA
Peter J. Richerson
Affiliation:
Department of Environmental Science and Policy, University of California, Davis, CA 95616, USA
*
*Corresponding author. E-mail: sergey.6avrilets@gmail.com

Abstract

Human decision-making is controlled by various factors including material cost–benefit considerations, values and beliefs, social influences, cognitive factors and errors. Among social influences, those by external authorities (e.g. educational, cultural, religious, political, administrative, etc.) are particularly important owing to their potential reach and power. To better understand the effects of ‘soft’ power of authorities we develop a unifying theoretical framework integrating material, cognitive and social forces controlling the joint dynamics of individual actions and beliefs. We apply our approach to three different phenomena: evolution of food sharing in small-scale societies, participation in political protests and effects of priming social identity in behavioural experiments. For each of these applications, we show that our approach leads to different (or simpler) explanations of human behaviour than alternatives. We highlight the type of measurements which can be helpful in developing practical applications of our approach. We identify and explicitly characterise the degree of mismatch between individual actions and attitudes. We assert that the effects of external authorities, of changing beliefs and of differences between people must be studied empirically, included in mathematical models, and accounted for when developing different policies aiming to modify or sustain human behaviour.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2022. Published by Cambridge University Press

Social media summary. A theoretical study of the power of inculcation, propaganda and social identity in shaping human behaviour and beliefs.

… a belief constantly inculcated during the early years of life, whilst the brain is impressible, appears to acquire almost the nature of an instinct; and the very essence of an instinct is that it is followed independently of reason. (Darwin, Reference Darwin1871: 82)

What did you dream?

It's alright, we told you what to dream. (Pink Floyd, ‘Welcome to the Machine’, 1975)

…in the social jungle of human existence there is no feeling of being alive without a sense of identity. (Erikson, Reference Erikson1968: 130)

Introduction

As stressed already by Aristotle and many influential philosophers after him, humans are deeply social. The importance of social influences for human behaviour was also quite clear to Darwin, as illustrated by his quote above. Modern research shows that social learning and culture have played crucial roles in human evolution since the origin of our species (Henrich, Reference Henrich2015). In fact, social learning and cumulative culture represent some of the most distinctive features of our species (Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Gavrilets and de Waal2021).

A byproduct of our strong reliance on social learning and conformity with peers was the emergence of novel factors constraining and driving human behaviour: morality, social norms and social institutions. These forces often act against immediate biological or material interests of individuals promoting instead the interests of the society as a whole or of its powerful segments (Singh et al., Reference Singh, Wrangham and Glowacki2017). Our preferences for social learning, including learning of social norms and beliefs of others, are apparent at very early ages (Whiten, Reference Whiten2017; House et al., Reference House, Kanngiesser, Barrett, Broesch, Cebioglu, Crittenden and Silk2019). We exhibit striking levels of conformity with opinions of others (Asch, Reference Asch and Guetzkow1951; Jacobs and Campbell, Reference Jacobs and Campbell1961; Bond and Smith, Reference Bond and Smith1996; Cialdini and Goldstein, Reference Cialdini and Goldstein2004; Song et al., Reference Song, Ma, Wu and Li2012) and often over-imitate their behaviour even when it is perceivably unrelated to achieving the given goal (Hoehl et al., Reference Hoehl, Keuppc, Schleihauf, McGuigand, Buttelmanne and Whiten2019). We deeply internalise the systems of religious and political beliefs (Gómez et al., Reference Gómez, Lopez-Rodríguez, Sheikh, Ginges, Wilson, Waziri and Atran2017) and are strongly influenced by various types of propaganda, e.g. political or commercial (Jowett and O'Donnell, Reference Jowett and O'Donnell1992).

Overall, our actions, attitudes and beliefs about others are strongly affected by those of our peers as well as by authorities (educational, cultural, religious, moral, political, administrative, etc). In this paper, by ‘authority’ we mean people who have the power to influence or command thought, opinion, or behaviour of others without necessarily implying the existence of formal institutions behind their power. Peer influence largely works towards reducing variation between interacting individuals and finding consensus around the middle ground (Gavrilets et al., Reference Gavrilets, Auerbach and van Vugt2016). As a result, conformity with peers usually stabilises behaviour, making changes at the group level difficult. In contrast, an authority's influence can directionally shift actions, attitude and beliefs of a large number of individuals. This is a fact well known to politicians, religious leaders, cultural models, educators, marketing professionals and social media influencers. The resulting effects can be very positive or extremely negative both from individual and group/societal perspectives. For example, certain ‘institutional signals’ can stimulate pro-environment behaviour (Tankard and Paluck, Reference Tankard and Paluck2016) or can lead to despicable behaviours as studied in Milgram's and Zimbardo's experiments on obedience to authority (Milgram, Reference Milgram1963; Haney et al., Reference Haney, Banks and Zimbardo1973). Human history provides plenty of additional examples.

A particularly interesting and important case of an authority's influence is when it acts by persuasion only and uses ‘soft power’ via inculcation and persuasion rather than coercion, punishment and ‘hard power’ and when it promotes (directly or indirectly) actions that can be against the immediate or long-term material interests of individuals. The authority's messaging/propaganda can achieve its goals, for example, directly by modifying individuals’ attitudes towards specific actions and behaviours (Jowett and O'Donnell, Reference Jowett and O'Donnell1992; Rozenas and Stukal, Reference Rozenas and Stukal2019; Cantoni et al., Reference Cantoni, Chen, Yang, Yuchtman and Zhang2021) or indirectly by changing individuals’ beliefs about the costs and benefits of their actions (Kuran, Reference Kuran1989; Huang, Reference Huang2015) or about attitudes and beliefs of their peers (Huang and Cruz, Reference Huang and Cruz2021). The authority's messaging is particularly efficient when the authority is viewed as legitimate and its message as trustworthy (Tyler, Reference Tyler1997). The authority can be individual or collective, formal or informal, real or fictitious (e.g. stories of mythical heroes, such as characters in novels or films today, might be influential even if people do not believe they are real).

Here we use mathematical modelling to understand better how the effects of authority on human's attitudes, beliefs and behaviours interact with those of material costs and benefits and with peer influences. The effects of material payoffs on behaviour are usually studied using various flavors of game theory – classical (Fudenberg and Tirole, Reference Fudenberg and Tirole1992), evolutionary (Sandholm, Reference Sandholm2010), mean field (Tembine, Reference Tembine2017) and quantum (Piotrowski and Sladkowski, Reference Piotrowski and Sladkowski2003). In standard economic models, an individual's preferences are fixed. The effects of peers on individual preferences and opinions are analysed using social influence models focusing on the dynamics of consensus formation (or fragmentation) in social networks as a result of social learning and imitation (Rashevsky, Reference Rashevsky1949; DeGroot, Reference DeGroot1974; Watts, Reference Watts2002; Friedkin et al., Reference Friedkin, Proskurnikov, Tempo and Parsegov2016; Zino et al., Reference Zino, Ye and Cao2020; Kashima et al., Reference Kashima, Perfors, Ferdinand and Pattenden2021). There are also a few theoretical approaches which consider the joint dynamics of actions/behaviours and opinions/attitudes where the latter are usually understood within the context of personal norms (Kuran, Reference Kuran1989; Rabin, Reference Rabin1994; Kuran and Sandholm, Reference Kuran and Sandholm2008; Gavrilets and Richerson, Reference Gavrilets and Richerson2017; Calabuig et al., Reference Calabuig, Olcina and Panebianco2018; Gavrilets, Reference Gavrilets2020). Some of these models also explicitly account for certain additional psychological phenomena such as cognitive dissonance (Festinger, Reference Festinger1957), social projection (Krueger, Reference Krueger2007) and logic constraints (Friedkin et al., Reference Friedkin, Proskurnikov, Tempo and Parsegov2016). We will follow this latter tradition, enriching it by explicitly considering the effects of authority and allowing for variation between individuals in various characteristics besides their strategies/actions. Our model is an application of a general theoretical framework recently developed by Gavrilets (Reference Gavrilets2021). In the situations we consider, the authority benefits directly if people respond to its messaging while people cooperate with the authority to avoid psychological costs of non-conformity. In contrast to some approaches where people ‘imitate’ authorities and prestigious individuals (e.g. Henrich et al., Reference Henrich, Chudek and Boyd2015), in our models people listen to and adopt the views promoted by the authority.

We will apply our approach to three different phenomena which nevertheless are probably driven by similar underlying processes. The first is cooperative behaviour which has been a major focus of theoretical work in biology and social sciences over the last several decades. The mechanisms and factors that have received most attention in the literature are genetic relatedness, reciprocity, reputation, selective incentives (rewards and punishment) and cultural (group) selection (Nowak, Reference Nowak2006; McElreath and Boyd, Reference McElreath and Boyd2007; Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Baldini, Bell, Demps, Frost, Hillis and Zefferman2016). We will consider another alternative: people exhibit altruistic tendencies (in real life and in experimental economics labs) mostly because they have internalised such behaviour owing to inculcation by parents, teachers, literature, religion, mass media and other cultural forces in the society. [The ability to internalise norms has evolved because it brings both individual and group-level benefits (Henrich and Ensminger, Reference Henrich, Ensminger, Ensminger and Henrich2014; Gavrilets and Richerson, Reference Gavrilets and Richerson2017).] As a result, people expect themselves and others to behave in a cooperative way and they believe that others have similar expectations. That is, cooperation becomes an injunctive social norm (Bicchieri, Reference Bicchieri2006; Fehr and Schurtenberger, Reference Fehr and Schurtenberger2018; Gavrilets and Richerson, Reference Gavrilets and Richerson2017; Gavrilets, Reference Gavrilets2020). As an example, we will use food sharing in small-scale societies which arguably represents one of the most well studied types of cooperation evolved in our species (Marlowe Reference Marlowe2009; Gurven and Jaeggi, Reference Gurven, Jaeggi, Scott and Kosslyn2013; Jaeggi and Gurven, Reference Jaeggi, Gurven and Callan2018). We will show that food sharing can evolve by certain psychological mechanisms responding to elders and prestigious individuals (the authority) as well as other group members pressuring successful hunters to share their kill. In a sense in our model, social learning is ‘hijacked’ to benefit people in a position of authority.

The second phenomenon is the effect of an authority (e.g. a government or a revolutionary leader) on the willingness of citizens to join protests. Social protests have become a constant part of social life throughout the modern world, sometimes leading to revolutions and civil wars (Kuran, Reference Kuran1995). The importance of peer behaviour on individual willingness to engage in protests is well established (Granovetter, Reference Granovetter1978; Borna et al., Reference Borna, Akkermanb and Thommes2016). Also important are the beliefs that individuals have about the attitudes of their peers (Kuran, Reference Kuran1995). For example, even when a majority of people want political changes, political actions can be prevented owing to pluralistic ignorance (Centola et al., Reference Centola, Willer and Macy2005), that is, the situation when people mistakenly think that most other people will oppose their personal norms and beliefs. Pluralistic ignorance can lead to preference falsification (Kuran, Reference Kuran1989) when people express preferences that are different from what their true preferences are because they believe they are in minority. People's beliefs and preferences, including political, are also greatly influenced by various types of propaganda (Jowett and O'Donnell, Reference Jowett and O'Donnell1992), by biased media (Alesina and Fuchs-Schündeln, Reference Alesina and Fuchs-Schündeln2007; Rozenas and Stukal, Reference Rozenas and Stukal2019) and by education (Bowles and Gintis, Reference Bowles and Gintis1976; Cantoni et al., Reference Cantoni, Chen, Yang, Yuchtman and Zhang2021). The effects of peers on individual and group behaviour are often described using the Shelling–Granovetter model (Schelling, Reference Schelling1971; Granovetter, Reference Granovetter1978) and similar mass-action/threshold approaches (Rashevsky, Reference Rashevsky1949; Efferson et al., Reference Efferson, Vogt and Fehr2020; Gavrilets, Reference Gavrilets2020), which however assume that individual attitudes remain constant. Here we will extend these approaches by allowing the attitudes to change and by explicitly considering the effects of authority.

The third phenomenon concerns the effects of social identity on behaviour and beliefs of individuals. Social identity is ‘that part of an individual's self-concept that derives from their knowledge of their membership in a social group (or groups) together with the value and emotional significance attached to that membership’ (Tajfel, Reference Tajfel1981: 255). Social identity theory postulates that people tend to view themselves as belonging to specific (identity) groups and when they do so, they tend to behave and accept beliefs according to the perceived ‘standards’ of their group. People do so because they receive value from the status of the identity group. Examples of social groups include gender, race, political or professional affiliation; perceived membership in these groups comes with group-specific norms and beliefs. Conformity with those leads to personal pride while deviance causes embarrassment or shame (Tajfel and Turner, Reference Tajfel, Turner and Worchel1979; Tajfel, Reference Tajfel1981). Priming social identity increasing the importance of the standard of behaviour associated with that social group. When a person's social identity changes, so does that individual's views of the appropriateness of certain actions. To understand better these effects we will adopt our modelling approach by re-interpreting the ‘authority’ as a set of behavioural standards, stereotypes and beliefs associated with a particular group the individual identifies with.

Our main conclusion will be that the effects of authority can provide a simple explanation for a number of important phenomena. Consequently, they need to play much more prominent role in the discussions and empirical and theoretical studies of human social and cultural evolution.

Models and results

Modelling framework

Consider a group of individuals. Time is discrete. At each moment, each individual is characterised by an action x they take and by an attitude y towards possible actions (0 ≤ x, y ≤ 1). If there are just two possible actions, say, x = 0 and x = 1, then attitude y measures their relative subjective appropriateness with high y implying high appropriateness of choosing x = 1. If there is a continuum of possible actions, then y specifies the most appropriate action (i.e. a personal norm, Schwartz, Reference Schwartz1977) from the point of view of the individual. An example of the former case would be a decision on whether to participate or not in a mass protest. An example of the latter would a decision on a share of their endowment to donate to a recipient in the Dictator game. Variable y is related to the strength of norm internalisation in Gavrilets and Richerson (Reference Kuran2017). Our approach can also be viewed as a special case of a more general framework of Gavrilets (Reference Gavrilets2021). Below when talking about attitude y, we will occasionally refer to it as ‘belief’ or ‘preference’.

As a result of action x the individual gets material utility (i.e. payoff) π(x), which can depend on the average action $\bar{x}$ of their group, and psychological utility (i.e. normative value) V (x, y), which depends on their action x and attitude y but does not depend on their social environment. We assume the existence of an authority promoting action x = G. We are agnostic about the source of power of the authority. Rather our model captures its effects by a single parameter F measuring efficiency of its messaging which can depend, for example, on the effort or legitimacy of (or trust in) the authority. We postulate that in deciding on the action the individual attempts to maximise utility function u:

(1)$$u = \underbrace{{\pi ( x) }}_{{{\rm material\ payoff}}} + \underbrace{{V( x, \;y) }}_{{{\rm normative\ value}}}-\underbrace{{k_1{( y-x) }^2}}_{{{\rm cognitive\ dissonance}}}-\underbrace{{k_2{( \bar{x}-x) }^2}}_{{{\rm conformity\ with\ peers}}}-\underbrace{{k_3{( G-x) }^2F, \;}}_{{{\rm conformity\ with\ authority}}}$$

where k 1, k 2 and k 3 are individual-specific non-negative parameters measuring psychological costs owing to sensitivity of decision-making to the corresponding forces. These parameters can depend on specific characteristics of individuals, e.g. cognitive or cultural. For example, individuals reacting negatively to perceived attempts to restrict their freedom (that is, showing psychological reactance) would have low values of k 2 and k 3. Utility function (1) implies that material benefit π is traded off against psychological costs owing to cognitive dissonance (i.e. a mismatch between the action x and attitude y; Festinger, Reference Festinger1957) and mismatch of their action with the average action of their peers, $\bar{x}$, and action G promoted by the authority. Note also that eqn (1) implies that individuals condition their actions on the behaviour of their peers (Fischbacher and Gächter, Reference Fischbacher and Gächter2010). The conformity term is similar to those emerging in some models of coordination in economics (e.g. Brock and Durlauf, Reference Brock and Durlauf1999, Reference Brock and Durlauf2001; Kuran and Sandholm, Reference Kuran and Sandholm2008). In general, G can change, e.g. if the authority updates its messaging (Almagro and Andrés-Cerezo, Reference Almagro and Andrés-Cerezo2010), or the authority could also produce certain goods (e.g. Verdier and Zenou, Reference Verdier and Zenou2018). However for simplicity we will focus exclusively on messaging and treat G as a constant.

We will further postulate that after taking an action, the individual's attitude y can change owing to cognitive dissonance and conformity:

(2)$${y}^{\prime} = y + \underbrace{{\alpha \lpar x-y\rpar }}_{{{\rm cognitive\ dissonance}}} + \underbrace{{\beta \lpar \bar{x}-y\rpar }}_{{{\rm conformity\ with\ peers^{\prime}\ action}}}-\underbrace{{\lpar G-y\rpar F\comma \;}}_{{{\rm conformity\ with\ authority}}}$$

where α, β and γ are individual-specific non-negative parameters measuring sensitivity of attitudes to the corresponding forces. Here the cognitive dissonance term acts to align individual attitude y with a previously taken action x (Festinger, Reference Festinger1957; Rabin, Reference Rabin1994; Kuran and Sandholm, Reference Kuran and Sandholm2008; Calabuig et al., Reference Calabuig, Olcina and Panebianco2018). The two conformity terms act to align y with the average group behaviour $\bar{x}$ and the action G promoted by the authority, respectively. These terms have a simple linear form standard in models of social influence (DeGroot, Reference DeGroot1974; Watts, Reference Watts2002; Centola et al., Reference Centola, Willer and Macy2005; Friedkin et al., Reference Friedkin, Proskurnikov, Tempo and Parsegov2016) and are also related to those used in cognitive neuroscience (Olsson et al., Reference Olsson, Knapska and Lindstr¨om2020). Note that while individual actions x affect material payoffs directly, individual thoughts/beliefs y do so only indirectly via subsequent actions.

The change in attitude y described by eqn (2) leads to a change in the utility function u which in turn can cause subsequent changes in actions taken. We assume that individuals take their actions and update their attitudes synchronously. Between-individual variation in parameters k 1, k 2, k 3, α, β and γ reflects differences in psychology, culture, personal history, information received, etc. Table 1 summarizes model variables and parameters. Note that we do not study the evolutionary origins of this variation (see e.g. Gavrilets and Richerson, Reference Gavrilets and Richerson2017) but rather postulate that it is already present and then explore its consequences on relatively short time-scales of individual life spans.

Table 1. Main variables, functions, and parameters

Next we consider three different applications of this model. In the first application, the ‘authority’ will be elders and prestigious individuals in a small-scale society promoting food sharing. In the second case, the authority will be a revolutionary leader promoting mass protests against the government. The third model will consider an imaginary authority – the identity group and its stereotypical behaviour.

For these three cases, we will present analytical approximations capturing the effects of different parameters on the average characteristics of the population at equilibrium. We will use agent-based simulations to illustrate the dynamics of x and y in time and the resulting distributions of y in the population.

Food sharing in small-scale societies

Consider a group of hunter–gatherers some of whom occasionally succeed in hunting and come into possession of some food items. Other group members express a desire to get a share from successful hunters who can oblige (i.e. choose x = 1) and lose food of value c or not oblige (i.e. choose x = 0). Individuals who share get normative value vy, where v is a non-negative parameter. Within the group there is an informal authority (e.g. elders who cannot hunt anymore themselves or some other accomplished and prestigious figures) inculcating food sharing among group members (i.e. G = 1); the efficiency of inculcation is controlled by parameter F. Let p be the frequency of sharing. Individuals assume that their peers who do share will disapprove of them if they do not share. Because everybody benefits from sharers, they do not suffer any cost of disapproval. Individuals differ in their attitude y towards sharing and in their sensitivity to social influence by peers and authority. We note that in the well-studied Hadza and the Ju’/hoansi there is a lot of bickering and shaming caused by a failure to share (Marlowe, Reference Marlowe2009; Wiessner, Reference Wiessner2014), which can be interpreted as reflecting individual variation in y. This model is described by a special case of eqns (1) and (2) (see the Supplementary Material).

We show in the Supplementary Material, that the deterministic version of this model predicts evolution to a line of equilibria different in p and in the distribution of attitudes y. At each equilibrium, a proportion of individuals have relatively high values of y and share food while remaining individuals have relatively low values of y and do not share food. The average difference in attitudes between individuals who share and those who do not is equal to the average of ratio α/(α + β + γ), which measures the relative importance of cognitive dissonance in attitude updating process. There can also be equilibria where everybody or nobody shares food. In particular, the state of universal sharing (p = 1, y = α + β + γ) is stable if the joint effect of normative value, cognitive dissonance, conformity with peers and conformity with authority on decision-making is larger than the benefit lost (v + ∑ ki > c). The state of no sharing (p = 0, y = γ) is stable if the effects of authority both on actions (k 3) and attitudes (γ) are small enough. All model parameters control the location and stability of the line of equilibrium (see the Supplementary Material).

The existence of multiple equilibria in general and of lines of equilibria in particular has two important implications. First, initial conditions become very important, so one needs to study their effects in detail. Second, models with lines of equilibria are structurally unstable, so one needs to study their behaviour under some perturbations.

Below we illustrate the model's behaviour using agent-based simulations which introduce additional features aiming to make the model more realistic. First, we allow for stochasticity in decision-making and in the process of updating the attitudes. The former will be characterised by precision parameter λ (large λ mean higher precision). The latter is characterised by a standard deviation σ of a random perturbation of attitude y during the update process (see the Supplementary Material for details). In our numerical simulations, the initial frequency of sharing is set to 0 but we vary the mean $\bar{y}$ and standard deviation σ of the distribution of attitude y in the population. Second, we will assume that there is not one but a large number of relatively small groups randomly exchanging migrants at rate m (Wright, Reference Wright1931). This assumption fits many hunting and gathering societies such as the Hudza in north-central Tanzania (Hill et al., Reference Hill, Walker, Bǒzǐcević, Eder, Headland, Hewlett and Wood2011). Since our main focus is on the effects of messaging, we choose high enough dispersal rates to reduce the effects of genetic relatedness on the model behaviour.

In agent-based simulations, we set c = 1 but allow for most other parameters to differ between individuals. Specifically, for each individual values of v, k and d are drawn randomly from a ‘broken-stick’ distribution [0, 1]. Similar procedure is used for assigning individual values of parameters α, β and γ. Besides its intuitive appeal, the advantage of the ‘broken-stick’ distribution is that, similarly to the uniform distribution, it does not have any parameters.

Our simulations show that the population quickly evolves to a stochastic equilibrium where a proportion of individuals share food and have high attitudes towards it. The average attitude $\bar{y}$ towards sharing is typically smaller than the actual frequency of sharing p (because the latter is augmented by the authority's influence). Providing the efficiency of inculcation F is high enough, a large proportion of individuals will share food. At the same time, the population as a whole can exhibit a substantial variation in underlying attitudes. Figure 1 illustrates these observations. If authority weakens its messaging, the model predicts that food sharing will be maintained for some time (because it is now internalised) but then it will get weaker and eventually disappear.

Figure 1. Predictions of the food sharing model for different efficiencies F of inculcation promoting sharing (G = 1). Left: the dynamics of the average attitude y (blue curves) and the frequency of sharers p (red curves) for 10 different independent runs for each value of F. Right: the initial (white bars) and final (blue bars) distributions of attitudes for one run. The blue and red vertical lines mark the mean attitude $\bar{y}$ and the frequency p of sharers respectively. Log–normal distribution of initial values of y with mean 0.2 and standard deviation 0.1. Parameters: benefit lost to sharing c = 1, 100 groups of size n = 10, precision in decision-making λ = 10, standard deviation of error in attitude updating σ = 0.05, probability of attitude updating uy = 0.5, dispersal rate m = 0.1, probability of successful hunting s = 0.15. Individual parameters k 1, k 2, k 3 and α, β, γ are chosen from broken stick distributions on [0, 1] while parameter v is set to 1.

Political protests

Here we will adapt and extend a classical model proposed by Kuran (Reference Kuran1989) in his study of unanticipated political revolutions.

Assume that each individual can publicly express the discontent with the current government (e.g. by joining a protest), x = 1, or not, x = 0. Let y be the attitude towards joining the protest (0 ≤ y ≤ 1) and let $\bar{x}$ be the perceived frequency of people who are protesting. Kuran (Reference Kuran1989) called the variables x, y and $\bar{x}$ ‘public preference’, ‘private preference’ and ‘collective sentiment’, respectively. He ignored material payoffs (i.e. set π = 0) and normative value (i.e. set V = 0) but assumed that individuals get an ‘integrity utility’ as well as a ‘reputational utility’. The former depended on the mismatch between the attitude and the action chosen; its effect on utility function is analogous to that of the ‘cognitive dissonance’ term in our eqn (1). The latter was proportional to the frequency of people choosing the same action; its effect is analogous to that of the ‘conformity with peers’ term in our eqn (1).

Let us generalise Kuran's model by postulating the existence of an authority promoting action G and assuming that individuals pay certain psychological costs by acting against its message as specified by the last term in eqn (1). If the focal authority is the government, then G = 0. If the focal authority is the opposition, then G = 1. Parameter F measuring the efficiency of the authority's messaging (propaganda) depends on the perceived trust/legitimacy of the authority and on its effort. Kuran (1989) assumed that individual attitudes y were constant in time. In contrast, we postulate that after taking the actions and observing peer behaviour, individuals update their attitudes according to eqn (2).

This model is similar to the one describing food sharing (except that here b = 0 and that we consider a well-mixed population with individuals knowing the frequency of protesters $\bar{x}$). We illustrate its behaviour using agent-based simulations which allow for stochasticity in decision-making and in updating attitudes. Figure 2 shows that the propaganda by a revolutionary leader can change the distribution of attitudes in the population and cause, if sufficiently strong, widespread protests. In contrast if we assume that attitudes do not change, then for the initial distribution of y and parameter values used in Figure 2, the frequency of people joining the protests will remain very low for all values of propaganda efficiency F considered in spite of a significant hidden discontent. Figures S1 in the Supplementary Material shows that the system can have multiple equilibria so that the eventual outcome of the dynamics can depend on the initial distribution of attitudes.

Figure 2. Predictions of the political protests model for different intensities of propaganda F promoting protests (G = 1). Left: the dynamics of the average attitude y (blue curves) and the frequency of protesters p (red curves) for 10 different independent runs for each value of F. Right: the initial (white bars) and final (blue bars) distributions of attitudes for one run. The blue and red vertical lines mark the mean attitude $\bar{y}$ and the frequency p of protests respectively. Log–normal distribution of initial values of y with mean 0.2 and standard deviation 0.1. Parameters: population size n = 1000, precision in decision-making λ = 10, standard deviation of error in attitude updating σ = 0.05, probability of attitude updating uy = 0.5.

We can also consider the case when there are multiple alternative authorities in the society. For example, let one authority promote protests (i.e. G = 1) with efficiency F 1 and another promote acquiescence (i.e. G = 0) with efficiency F 0. This model is mathematically equivalent to that with a single authority promoting the value of G = F 1/(F 0 + F 1) with efficiency F = F 0 + F 1. Figure S2 in the Supplementary Material shows that if the propaganda efficiency of the government matches that of the opposition (i.e. F 0 = F 1 so that F = 0.5), the protests are suppressed. This may explain why even regimes capable of severe repression nonetheless devote substantial resources to persuasion.

Social identity and altruism

Numerous studies have shown that priming social identity affects human decisions and preferences. For example, making ethnic or racial identity more salient affect time and risk preferences (Benjamin et al., Reference Benjamin, Choi and Strickland2010). Making religious identity more salient decreases contributions to public goods of Catholics but increases it for Protestants, and increases agnostic/atheist risk aversion (Benjamin et al., Reference Benjamin, Choi and Fisher2016). Chang et al. (Reference Chang, Chen and Krupka2019) used a series of Dictator games described with either politically charged tax or neutrally framed language. They observed that subjects’ political identities interact with these frames, causing changes in both norms and choices. In particular, framing made Democrats prefer equalised outcomes, and Republicans reluctant to redistribute payments even when it leaves them disadvantaged. Using surveys conducted in UK and US, Pickup et al. (Reference Pickup, Kimbrough and de Rooij2021) showed that individuals were aware of the norms attached to their political identities, were knowingly choosing norm-compliance at personal cost, and that their costly expression of political identity varied with norm salience and strength.

Within our framework, the effects of social identity can be formalised as emerging from messaging of an imaginary authority – the identity group. Parameter F then can be interpreted as measuring the salience of social identity while G as a stereotypical behaviour associated with the focal social identity group. To be specific, consider the Dictator game which is often used to study cooperative and altruistic behaviour with identity considerations (e.g. Chang et al., Reference Chang, Chen and Krupka2019). Let a focal individual make a decision on a share x of their endowment b to transfer to a partner. Then the material payoff term in eqn (1) is π = b(1 −x). Note that in this model all interactions are dyadic rather than are happening in a group setting. As above, let y be the individual's attitude, i.e. the most appropriate, from their personal perspective, proportion of the benefit to be shared under given circumstances. Let us ignore the ‘conformity with peers’ terms in eqns (1) and (2) because subjects often were not informed about peer behaviour. This complete the formulation of the model.

We show in the Supplementary Material that, given y, the best response action/donation is a weighted sum of the personal norm y and the action G promoted by the authority:

(3)$$x = \displaystyle{{\varepsilon _xy + (1-\varepsilon _x)G} \over {\tilde{c} + 1}}.$$

where parameter $\tilde{c} = c/(k_1 + k_3F)$ is the strength of material payoffs relative to that of cognitive factors in the utility function and parameter ɛx = k 1/(k 1 + k 3F) measures the relative strength of the effects of cognitive dissonance on actions. Computing the derivative of x with respect to F, one can see that donation x to the partner increases with identity salience F if

$$G > \displaystyle{{k_1} \over {k_1 + c}}y$$

(that is, if stereotypical donation G is large enough relative to individual attitude y) but decreases with F otherwise. Thus, as argued by Benjamin et al. (Reference Benjamin, Choi and Strickland2010), this model predicts that priming people experiencing strong cognitive dissonance (i.e. with large v) can cause negative effect on x.

However one can also expect that personal norms y can change as a result of psychological processes. Without priming (i.e. if F = 0), eqn (2) shows that y will evolve to match x after which x will evolve to zero so that individuals will not transfer any funds to the partner. In contrast, with priming F, at equilibrium,

(4a)$$x^{\ast} = G-\displaystyle{{\tilde{c}} \over {1-\varepsilon _x\varepsilon _y}}, \;$$
(4b)$$y^{\ast} = G-\displaystyle{{\varepsilon _y\tilde{c}} \over {1-\varepsilon _x\varepsilon _y}},$$

where parameter ɛy = α/(α + γF) measures the relative strength of the effects of cognitive dissonance beliefs (see the Supplementary Material). Equations (4) show that x and y are both smaller than the group's standard G with the personal norm y being closer to G than x (so that G − y = ɛy(G − x)). Increasing the salience F of social identity decreases $\tilde{b}$, ɛx and ɛy moving x and y close to the identity standard G. Increasing the cost of expressing identity $\tilde{b}$ or the strengths of cognitive dissonance in decision-making, ɛx, and belief formation, ɛy, have opposite effects.

The derivatives of x and y with respect to F are always positive meaning that priming always has positive effects on actions and beliefs. This conclusion is different from that above for the model where beliefs were constant (also see Benjamin et al., Reference Benjamin, Choi and Strickland2010). On a short time-scale, some people with a very high personal norm y and experiencing significant cognitive dissonance (large c) may donate money to the partner even in the absence of priming (i.e. if F = 0). However on larger time scales, our model predicts that without a continuous priming y will evolve to match x and then contributions will disappear.

Discussion

Human decision-making in social interactions is clearly controlled not only by material cost–benefit considerations, but also by other factors including their values and beliefs, social influences and errors. Importantly, humans differ in various psychological characteristics and in their beliefs and values. The latter can dynamically change coevolving with their actions (Tormos, Reference Tormos2020; Szekely et al., Reference Szekely, Lipari, Antonioni, Paolucci, Sánchez, Tummolini and Andrighetto2021; Levy, Reference Levy, De Smedt and De Cruz2021; Tverskoi et al., Reference Tverskoi, Guido, Andrighetto, Sánchez and Gavrilets2022). Among various social influences those by external authorities (e.g. cultural, religious, political, moral, administrative, individual or group, formal or informal, real or fictitious, etc.) are particularly important. The messaging of external authorities affects not only individual actions but also their beliefs. While the effects of peer influences have been extensively studied and modelled in the field of cultural and social evolution, those of external authorities have not received much attention. Here we have argued here that these effects can explain certain puzzling features of humans, such as large-scale cooperation with unrelated individuals, the emergence and evolution of social norms and some other types of mass behaviour. Our argument is supported by a unifying modelling framework accounting for various factors of human decision-making and psychological differences between individuals. Most of earlier related modelling work focuses exclusively either on actions taken by individuals (using game-theoretic approaches) or on publicly expressed opinions (using models of social influence). In contrast, we used a more general approach in which actions coevolve with the degree to which individuals internalise/value particular actions (Gavrilets and Richerson, Reference Gavrilets and Richerson2017; Calabuig et al., Reference Calabuig, Olcina and Panebianco2018; Gavrilets, Reference Gavrilets2021). Our approach accounts for some psychological processes and forces affecting actions, attitudes and beliefs, such as cognitive dissonance (Festinger, Reference Festinger1957), conformity with peers (Song et al., Reference Song, Ma, Wu and Li2012), social identity (Tajfel and Turner, Reference Tajfel, Turner and Worchel1979; Tajfel, Reference Tajfel1981) and obedience to authority (Milgram, Reference Milgram1963; Haney et al., Reference Haney, Banks and Zimbardo1973). We have illustrated our approach using three different phenomena.

Food sharing

The norm of food-sharing is common in small-scale societies and represents probably one of the most ancestral type of altruistic/cooperative behaviour in humans (Marlowe, Reference Marlowe2009; Gurven and Jaeggi, Reference Gurven, Jaeggi, Scott and Kosslyn2013). Explanations of food-sharing include nepotism (i.e. sharing with kin), reciprocity (i.e. sharing is conditional on past receipt of food), costly signalling (to display the donor's desirable qualities), and tolerated scrounging (when giving up some food helps avoid potential physical or reputational costs from hoarding) (Kameda et al., Reference Kameda, Takezawa and Hastie2003; Marlowe, Reference Marlowe2009; Gurven and Jaeggi, Reference Gurven, Jaeggi, Scott and Kosslyn2013). These mechanisms have been studied using standard game-theory models comparing the long-term payoffs of different strategies (Jaeggi and Gurven, Reference Jaeggi, Gurven and Callan2018). The overall conclusion of earlier work is that all the above factors may be in play with tolerated scrounging being probably most consistent with data (Kameda et al., Reference Kameda, Takezawa and Hastie2003; Marlowe, Reference Marlowe2009; Jaeggi and Gurven, Reference Jaeggi, Gurven and Callan2018).

The logic of our approach is closely related to that of tolerated scrounging. However rather than demonstrating that food-sharing strategy can lead to higher material payoffs, we show that individuals can develop intrinsic preference for sharing to avoid psychological costs of disapproval by elders and peers. The pressure from the later to share is both ‘cheap’ and is directly motivated by a hope to receive a share of the kill. The latter means that sharing demands are not necessarily a ‘public good’, so that there is no second-order free-rider problem (Henrich and Boyd, Reference Henrich and Boyd2001; Boyd et al., Reference Boyd, Gintis, Bowles and Richerson2003) which can prevent the evolution of cooperation. That is, the norm of food-sharing can evolve without relatedness, reciprocity, reputation, or group selection once the proximate mechanisms of social influence have evolved to be sufficiently important. Here we do not model the ultimate evolutionary mechanisms that give rise to an important role for social influence, such as Darwin's idea that prosocial emotions evolved by tribal-scale selection for cooperation (Richerson et al., Reference Richerson, Baldini, Bell, Demps, Frost, Hillis and Zefferman2016). Henrich and Gil-White (Reference Henrich and Gil-White2001) argued that social influences including those of prestigious individuals are a result of psychological adaptations that evolved to improve the quality of culturally acquired information.

In small-scale societies moral inculcation takes place systematically and repeatedly starting with early age. These happen during day-to-day activities (Wiessner, Reference Wiessner2005), during certain ritual such as male initiation or the trance dance (Wiessner and Tumu, Reference Wiessner and Tumu1998), and during evening-time conversations in stories told by elders and leaders (Wiessner, Reference Wiessner2005; Smith et al., Reference Smith, Schlaepfer, Major, Dyble, Page, Thompson and Miglian2017). In small-scale societies, there are usually multiple types of authorities corresponding to different domains of everyday life, e.g. fishing, growing yams and using medicine (Henrich and Broesch, Reference Henrich and Broesch2011). Parents and older relatives play an important role in promoting helping (Clark, Reference Clark2021). Children's responsiveness to social norms (House et al., Reference House, Kanngiesser, Barrett, Broesch, Cebioglu, Crittenden and Silk2019; Hoehl et al., Reference Hoehl, Keuppc, Schleihauf, McGuigand, Buttelmanne and Whiten2019) and the beliefs (Kovács et al., Reference Kovács, Téglás and Endress2010) of others develops similarly across small-scale horticulturalists to large urban societies (House et al., Reference House, Kanngiesser, Barrett, Broesch, Cebioglu, Crittenden and Silk2019).

Cross-cultural experimental economics studies show significant differences between small-scale societies in their cooperativeness (Bowles et al., Reference Bowles, Boyd, Camerer, Fehr and Henrich2001). This variation is viewed as reflecting differences in optimal behaviour between environments (Lamba and Mace, Reference Lamba and Mace2011). However it is also possible that differences in cooperativeness reflect differences in the degrees of acceptance of an authority across societies.

Many social norms are group beneficial. Our approach applies to norms from which the authority benefits equally or more than regular group members. The cases where social norms are detrimental to the authority (e.g. individual preferences for egalitarianism in nonegalitarian societies) fall outside of our framework.

Political movements and revolutions

Many mathematical models of of political protests, riots, or revolutions are related to the classical Shelling–Granovetter model (Schelling, Reference Schelling1971; Granovetter, Reference Granovetter1978). In that model, each individual is characterised by their own conformity ‘threshold’ defined as a minimum frequency of a particular behaviour (e.g. join the riot) in the population needed for the focal individual to adopt the same behaviour. The ‘thresholds’ are constant in time, and the transition to mass protests is triggered by individuals with low thresholds with others subsequently joining in. Instead of rather abstract ‘thresholds’, later work started to use the formalism of utility functions explicitly accounting for various factors affecting decision-making (Kuran, Reference Kuran1989; Gavrilets, Reference Gavrilets2020). This is the approach we have taken here, generalising it by allowing for individual values to change (which leads to changes in the individual ‘thresholds’) and by explicitly accounting for the effects of external authorities.

Our results show that accounting for changes in individual values/beliefs leads to qualitative and quantitative changes in model predictions. In particular, the model predicts an increased stability of status quo owing to increasing alignment of beliefs with actions relative to what can be expected if beliefs do not change. In a sense, changes in beliefs lead to increasing individual ‘thresholds’, so that the revolutionary change becomes more difficult. A crucial component of Kuran's (1989, 1995) theory is the notion of ‘preference falsification’ – that is, a mismatch between personal beliefs and actual behaviour. Our model suggests a reduced proportion of individuals falsifying their preferences than what can be expected with stable attitudes. This means the society is more resistant to change. Our results further highlight the importance of messaging/propaganda by trusted/legitimate authority in changing the status quo.

Priming social identity

Identifying with a particular social group often comes with a set of behavioural standards (Tajfel, Reference Tajfel1981; Suhay, Reference Suhay2015; Smaldino, Reference Smaldino2019). Adherence to in-group norms is critical for a status among in-group peers (Suhay, Reference Suhay2015). Individuals are aware of the norms attached to their social identities (e.g. political, Pickup et al., Reference Pickup, Kimbrough and de Rooij2021). They will comply with the norms at personal cost; the extent of their compliance varies with norm salience and strength (Pickup et al., Reference Pickup, Kimbrough and de Rooij2020, 2021). Partisan identity affects not only individual actions but also their beliefs, e.g. on climate change (Doell et al., Reference Doell, P¨arnamet, Harri, Hackel and Van Bavel2021). Individuals also exhibit significant and robust differences in ‘groupiness’ across different social situations. For some individuals, just being in a group setting strongly influences their thoughts and actions (Kranton et al., Reference Kranton, Pease, Sanders and Huettel2021). One of our goal here was to capture these effects in a mathematical model and study their consequences.

Applying our approach to the settings of the Dictator game, which is often used to study the effects of social identity on cooperation, we have shown that, without priming, individuals are expected to stop transferring funds to the partner. With priming, they will value transferring some funds and will do so. Individual actions and beliefs will be controlled by three composite parameters, one of which measures the amount of material benefit relative to the strength of psychological factors ($\tilde{b}$) and two of which measure the relative effects of cognitive resonance on actions and beliefs (ɛx, ɛy). Individuals’ beliefs are always closer to the group standard G than their average action. The extent of mismatch between actions x and beliefs y is controlled by the cognitive dissonance parameter ɛy. Earlier Benjamin et al. (Reference Benjamin, Choi and Fisher2016) developed and then tested a model predicting the effects of social identity on decisions in a single round of social dilemmas. Our results show that their conclusions will probably not hold over multiple rounds.

Here we took the existence of authorities as given. The current thinking is that human groups have ‘authorities’ because of the differences in various types of knowledge and power between individuals/groups which come from the differences in their traits/characteristics. We note that leadership is also common in non-human animals where ‘leaders’ emerge for similar reasons (Smith et al., Reference Smith, Gavrilets, Mulder, Hooper, ElMouden, Nettle and Smith2016). We have also interpreted a set of behavioural standards, stereotypes and beliefs associated with a particular group the individual identifies with as an impersonal or fictitious authority. Hogg (Reference Hogg2001) and others (e.g. Haslam et al., Reference Haslam, Reicher and Platow2011) have argued that these stereotypes often influence who will most likely emerge as real authority and leaders – specifically, most prototypical group members. More prototypical leaders are also perceived to be more effective leaders. That authorities can spread certain norms is one of their emergent features.

For each of the three specific applications considered, we showed that our approach leads to different (or simpler) explanations of human behaviour than alternative models. Which mechanism better describes what is happening in reality is an empirical question. In all these models we identify and explicitly characterise the degree of mismatch between actions and attitudes which could not be done in standard models ignoring the dynamic nature of attitudes.

We have treated the efficiency of messaging in a parsimonious way by using a single parameter F. In reality, F will depend on details of the system under study. It can be weaker or stronger depending on the group size, the type of authority (distributed or concentrated), the effort put by the authority, its legitimacy, the consistency of messaging, etc. For example, in ‘Big Man’ systems, authority is partially based on the charisma of individuals who can influence followers from a kin group outwards of perhaps a few hundred individuals (Wiessner and Tumu, Reference Wiessner and Tumu1998). In conical clans, the chiefs can command thousands of individuals (Kirch, Reference Kirch1984). In modern societies the reach of, say, cultural authorities active online can potentially extend to tens of millions. We note the question of how effective different types of authorities using ‘soft’ power are is largely an open empirical question.

One practical application of our approach towards quantifying the effects of authority is to estimate parameters v, k 1, k 2, k 3, α, β and γ of our model. This can be done by fitting linear regressions describing best response actions (eqn S1 in the Supplementary Material) and attitude dynamics (eqn (2)). The data could be obtained by measuring individual actions simultaneously with eliciting their attitudes and beliefs (d'Adda et al., Reference d'Adda, Dufwenberg, Passarelli and Tabellin2020; Górges and Nosenzo, Reference Górges and Nosenzo2020; Andreozzi et al., Reference Andreozzi, Ploner and Saral2020; Szekely et al., Reference Szekely, Lipari, Antonioni, Paolucci, Sánchez, Tummolini and Andrighetto2021; Tverskoi et al., Reference Tverskoi, Guido, Andrighetto, Sánchez and Gavrilets2022). An interesting question is whether the estimated parameters k 3 and γ (representing the impact of conformity with authority) are large or small compared with the coefficients for other terms in an observed population. We expect that messaging will mostly work indirectly through changing attitudes y (as controlled by parameter γ) rather than by changing actions directly (as controlled by parameter k 3). Also it would be important to know whether the coefficients vary by population (e.g. whether they depend on its culture) or by the kind of action. Our model postulates that different terms combine additively. If this proves wrong, structural modifications to the model might be needed (e.g. with the terms combining multiplicatively).

Obviously, our approach could be too simple, and the way it breaks down would lead to more complex but more realistic models. In the models studied here, increasing messaging or priming increases the frequency of the focal behaviour. However in related models with more complex (nonlinear) payoff functions, messaging can ‘backfire’, i.e. result in the opposite effect (Gavrilets, Reference Gavrilets2021). Although our analysis focused on rather specific models, our results should be applicable more generally. For example, the payoffs in the food sharing model correspond more generally (up to rescaling) to the payoffs of, e.g. cooperators and defectors in a linear public goods game, where selfish actions dominate in the absence of additional factors. At the same time, our approach has certain limitations which need to be removed in future work. In particular, in our models, we assumed that different factors interact in an additive way. Although this assumption is a simple and natural first step, nonlinear interactions are also possible. For example, Bowles (Reference Bowles2016) describes a ‘crowding-out’ effect in a day-care centre in Israel where an introduction of fees for being late to pickup a child resulted in an increased frequency of parents violating the norm. Also, our equations for the change in personal attitude do not depend on material factors. However, individual attitudes can depend on the payoffs received, e.g. via the phenomenon of effort justification (Festinger, Reference Festinger1957; Pickup et al., Reference Pickup, Kimbrough and de Rooij2020). In our models, individuals react to the current frequency of a particular behaviour among peers. However some data show that people also react to the rate of change in the frequency of behaviour (Sparkman and Walton, Reference Sparkman and Walton2019). We assume that the authority's messaging is constant, while the authority can change it depending on the situation (Almagro and Andrés-Cerezo Reference Almagro and Andrés-Cerezo2010). On the other hand, the linearity of our model implies that its parameters can be readily estimated using e.g. behavioural economics experiments, such as those in Szekely et al. (Reference Szekely, Lipari, Antonioni, Paolucci, Sánchez, Tummolini and Andrighetto2021) and Tverskoi et al. (Reference Tverskoi, Guido, Andrighetto, Sánchez and Gavrilets2022).

Overall, our model offers insights into the complex interactions of actions and beliefs promoted by cultural authorities strengthening our intuition but also providing additional insights on the effects of parameters and changing attitudes. It demonstrates that capturing some neglected aspects of human psychology and social dynamics in the model can lead to different (or simpler) explanations of certain aspects of human behaviour. It also can serve as a guide to the kinds of information that an empirical study would need to consider to isolate the effect of authority's influence on a decision alongside other basic influences. Our results suggest that the effects of external authorities, of changing beliefs, and of differences between people must be included in mathematical models, studied empirically and accounted for when developing different policies aiming to modify or sustain human behaviour.

Acknowledgements

We thank A. Sánchez, D. Tverskoi, G. Shteynberg, A. Bentley, R. Boyd and reviewers for comments and suggestions.

Authors’ contributions

SG conceived and performed the study, and drafted the manuscript. PJR contributed to writing the manuscript.

Financial support

SG was supported by the US Army Research Office (grants W911NF-14-1-0637 and W911NF-18-1-0138), the Office of Naval Research (grant W911NF-17-1-0150) and the Air Force Office of Scientific Research (grant FA9550-21-1-0217).

Competing interests

There are no competing interests.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit https://doi.org/10.1017/ehs.2022.48.

References

Alesina, A., & Fuchs-Schündeln, N. (2007). Good-bye Lenin (or not?): The effect of communism on people’s preferences. American Economic Review, 97, 15071528.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Almagro, M., & Andrés-Cerezo, D. (2010). The construction of national identities. Theoretical Economics, 15, 763810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andreozzi, L., Ploner, M., & Saral, A. S. (2020). The stability of conditional cooperation: Beliefs alone cannot explain the decline of cooperation in social dilemmas. Scientific Reports, 10, 13610.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Asch, S. (1951). Effects of group pressure on the modification and distortion of judgments. In Guetzkow, H. (Ed.), Groups, leadership and men (pp. 177190). Carnegie Press.Google Scholar
Benjamin, D. J., Choi, J. J., & Fisher, G. (2016). Religious identity and economic behavior. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 98, 617637.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Benjamin, D. J., Choi, J. J., & Strickland, A. J. (2010). Social identity and preferences. American Economic Review, 100, 19131928.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bicchieri, C. (2006). The grammar of society. The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bond, R., & Smith, P. B. (1996). Culture and conformity: A meta-analysis of studies using Asch’s (1952b, 1956) line judgment task. Psychological Bulletin, 119, 111137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borna, M., Akkermanb, A., & Thommes, K. (2016). Peer influence on protest participation: Communication and trust between co-workers as inhibitors or facilitators of mobilization. Social Science Research, 56, 5872.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowles, S. (2016). The moral economy: Why good incentives are no substitute for good citizens. Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Bowles, S., Boyd, R., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., & Henrich, J. (2001). Cooperation, reciprocity and punishment in fifteen small-scale societies. Technical report.Google Scholar
Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (1976). Schooling in capitalist America: Educational reform and the contradictions of economic life. Routledge.Google Scholar
Boyd, R., Gintis, H., Bowles, S., & Richerson, P. J. (2003). The evolution of altruistic punishment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 100(6), 35313535.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Brock, W. A., & Durlauf, S. N. (1999). A formal model of theory choice in science. Economic Theory, 14, 113130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brock, W. A., & Durlauf, S. N. (2001). Discrete choice with social interactions. Review of Economic Studies, 68, 235260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calabuig, V., Olcina, G., & Panebianco, F. (2018). Culture and team production. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 149, 3245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cantoni, D., Chen, Y., Yang, D. Y., Yuchtman, N., & Zhang, Y. J. (2021). Curriculum and ideology. Journal of Political Economy, 125, https://doi.org/10.1086/690951.Google Scholar
Centola, D., Willer, R., & Macy, M. (2005). The Prisoner's dilemma: A computational model of self-enforcing norms. American Journal of Sociology, 110, 10091040.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, D., Chen, R., & Krupka, E. (2019). Rhetoric matters: A social norms explanation for the anomaly of framing. Games and Economic Behavior, 116, 158178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cialdini, R. B., & Goldstein, N. J. (2004). Social influence: Compliance and conformity. Annual Reviews in Psychology, 55, 591621.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Clark, K. J. (2021). Cultural traditions and fitness interdependence. Evolutionary Behavioral Sciences, https://doi.org/10.1037/ebs0000268.Google Scholar
d'Adda, G., Dufwenberg, M., Passarelli, F., & Tabellin, G. (2020). Social norms with private values: Theory and experiments. Games and Economic Behavior, 124, 288304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Darwin, C. (1871). The descent of man, and selection in relation to sex. John Murray.Google Scholar
DeGroot, M. (1974). Reaching a consensus. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 69, 118121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Doell, K. C., P¨arnamet, P., Harri, E. A., Hackel, L. M., & Van Bavel, J. J. (2021). Understanding the effects of partisan identity on climate change. Current Opinion in Behavioral Sciences, 42, 5459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Efferson, C., Vogt, S., & Fehr, E. (2020). The promise and the peril of using social influence to reverse harmful traditions. Nature Human Behavior, 4, 5568.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Erikson, E. H. (1968). Identity: Youth and crisis. W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Fehr, E., & Schurtenberger, I. (2018). Normative foundations of human cooperation. Nature Human Behaviour, 2, 458468.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Festinger, L. (1957). A theory of cognitive dissonance. Stanford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2010). Social preferences, beliefs, and the dynamics of free riding in public goods experiments. American Economics Reviews, 100, 541556.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedkin, N. E., Proskurnikov, A. V., Tempo, R., & Parsegov, S. E. (2016). Network science on belief system dynamics under logic constraints. Science, 354, 321326.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1992). Game theory. The MIT Press.Google Scholar
Gavrilets, S. (2020). The dynamics of injunctive social norms. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 2, e60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gavrilets, S. (2021). Coevolution of actions, personal norms, and beliefs about others in social dilemmas. Evolutionary Human Sciences, 3, e44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gavrilets, S., Auerbach, J., & van Vugt, M. (2016). Convergence to consensus in heterogeneous groups and the emergence of informal leadership. Scientific Reports, 6, 29704.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gavrilets, S., & Richerson, P. J. (2017). Collective action and the evolution of social norm internalization. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 114, 60686073.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gómez, A., Lopez-Rodríguez, L., Sheikh, H., Ginges, J., Wilson, L., Waziri, H., … Atran, S. (2017). The devoted actor’s will to fight and the spiritual dimension of human conflict. Nature Human Behaviour, 1, 673–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Górges, L., & Nosenzo, D. (2020). Measuring social norms in economics: Why it is important and how it is done. Analyse & Kritik, 42, 285311.Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. (1978). Threshold models of collective behavior. American Journal of Sociology, 83, 14201443.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gurven, M., & Jaeggi, A. V. (2013). Food sharing. In Scott, R. and Kosslyn, S. (Eds.), Emerging trends in the social and behavioral sciences. John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Haney, C., Banks, C., & Zimbardo, P. (1973). Interpersonal dynamics in a simulated prison. International Journal of Criminology and Penology, 1, 6997.Google Scholar
Haslam, S. A., Reicher, S. D., & Platow, M. J. (2011). The new psychology of leadership: Identity, influence and power. Psychology Press.Google Scholar
Henrich, J. (2015). The secret of our success. Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., & Boyd, R. (2001). Why people punish defectors: Weak conformist transmission can stabilize costly enforcement of norms in cooperative dilemmas. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 208(1), 7989.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Henrich, J., & Broesch, J. (2011). On the nature of cultural transmission networks: Evidence from Fijian villages for adaptive learning biases. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society London B, 366, 11391148.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Henrich, J., Chudek, M., & Boyd, R. (2015). The Big Man mechanism: How prestige fosters cooperation and creates prosocial leaders. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society London B, 370, 20150013.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henrich, J., & Ensminger, J. (2014). Theoretical foundations: the coevolution of social norms, intrinsic motivation, markets, and the institutions of complex societies. In Ensminger, J. and Henrich, J. (Eds.), Experimenting with social norms: Fairness and punishment in cross-cultural perspective (pp. 1944). Russel Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Henrich, J., & Gil-White, F. J. (2001). The evolution of prestige. Freely conferred deference as a mechanism for enhancing the benefits of cultural transmission. Evolution and Human Behavior, 22, 165196.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hill, K. R., Walker, R. S., Bǒzǐcević, M., Eder, J., Headland, T., Hewlett, B., … Wood, B. (2011). Coresidence patterns in hunter-gatherer societies show unique human social structure. Science, 331, 12861289.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Hoehl, S., Keuppc, S., Schleihauf, H., McGuigand, N., Buttelmanne, D., & Whiten, A. (2019). ‘Over-imitation’: A review and appraisal of a decade of research. Developmental Review, 51, 90108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hogg, M. A. (2001). A social identity theory of leadership. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 5, 184200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
House, B. R., Kanngiesser, P., Barrett, H. C., Broesch, T., Cebioglu, S., Crittenden, A. N., … Silk, J. B. (2019). Universal norm psychology leads to society diversity in prosocial behaviour and development. Nature Human Behaviour, 4, 19.Google ScholarPubMed
Huang, H. (2015). Propaganda as signaling. Comparative Politics, 47, 419444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huang, H., & Cruz, N. (2021). Propaganda, presumed influence, and collective protest. Political Behavior, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-021-09683-0.Google Scholar
Jacobs, R. C., & Campbell, D. T. (1961). The perpetuation of an arbitrary tradition through several generations of laboratory microculture. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 62, 649–568.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jaeggi, A. V., & Gurven, M. (2018). Food-sharing models. In Callan, H. (Ed.), The international encyclopedia of anthropology. John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Jowett, G. S., & O'Donnell, V. (1992). Propaganda and persuasion (2nd ed.). Sage.Google Scholar
Kameda, T., Takezawa, M., & Hastie, R. (2003). The logic of social sharing: An evolutionary game analysis of adaptive norm developmen. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 7, 219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kashima, Y., Perfors, A., Ferdinand, V., & Pattenden, E. (2021). Ideology, communication and polarization. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society London B, 376, 20200133.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kirch, P. V. (1984). The evolution of the Polynesian chiefdom. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kovács, A. M., Téglás, E., & Endress, A. D. (2010). The social sense: Susceptibility to others’ beliefs in human infants and adults. Science, 330, 18301834.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Kranton, R., Pease, M., Sanders, S., & Huettel, S. (2021). Deconstructing bias in social preferences reveals groupy and not-groupy behavior. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 117, 2118521193.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krueger, J. I. (2007). From social projection to social behaviour. European Review of Social Psychology, 18, 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, T. (1989). Sparks and prairie fires: A theory of unanticipated political revolution. Public Choice, 61, 4174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, T. (1995). Private truths, public lies. Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kuran, T., & Sandholm, W. H. (2008). Cultural integration and its discontents. Review of Economic Studies, 75(1), 201228.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lamba, S., & Mace, R. (2011). Demography and ecology drive variation incooperation across human populations. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 108, 1442614430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, N. (2021). Not so hypocritical after all: Belief revision is adaptive and often unnoticed. In De Smedt, J. and De Cruz, H. (Eds.), Empirically engaged evolutionary ethics (pp. 4161). Springer Nature.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marlowe, F. W. (2009). Hadza cooperation. Human Nature, 20, 417430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McElreath, R., & Boyd, R. (2007). Mathematical models of social evolution. A guide for the perplexed. Chicago University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgram, S. (1963). Behavioral study of obedience. Journal of Abnormal and Social Psychology, 67, 371378.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Nowak, M. (2006). Evolutionary dynamics. Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Olsson, A., Knapska, E., & Lindstr¨om, B. (2020). The neural and computational systems of social learning. Nature Review Neuroscience, 21, 197212.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Pickup, M., Kimbrough, E. O., & de Rooij, E. A. (2020). Identity and the self-reinforcing effects of norm compliance. Southern Economic Journal, 86, 12221240.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pickup, M., Kimbrough, E. O., & de Rooij, E. A. (2021). Expressive politics as (costly) norm following. Political Behavior, https://doi.org/10.1007/s11109-020-09667-6.Google Scholar
Piotrowski, E. W., & Sladkowski, J. (2003). An invitation to quantum game theory. International Journal of Theoretical Physics, 42, 10891099.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rabin, M. (1994). Cognitive dissonance and social change. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 24, 177194.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rashevsky, N. (1949). Mathematical biology of social behavior. Bulletin of Mathematical Biology, 11, 255271.Google ScholarPubMed
Richerson, P., Baldini, R., Bell, A. V., Demps, K., Frost, K., Hillis, V., … Zefferman, M. (2016). Cultural group selection plays an essential role in explaining human cooperation: A sketch of the evidence. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 39, article number UNSP e30.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Richerson, P. J., Gavrilets, S., & de Waal, F. B. M. (2021). Modern theories of human evolution foreshadowed by Darwin’s Descent of Man. Science, 372, eaba3776.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rozenas, A., & Stukal, D. (2019). How autocrats manipulate economic news: Evidence from Russia’s state-controlled television. Journal of Politics, 81, 982996.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sandholm, W. H. (2010). Population games and evolutionary dynamics. MIT Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, T. (1971). Dynamic models of segregation. Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 1, 143186.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schwartz, S. H. (1977). Normative influences on altruism. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 10, 221279.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Singh, M., Wrangham, R., & Glowacki, L. (2017). Self-interest and the design of rules. Human Nature, 28, 457480.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Smaldino, P. E. (2019). Social identity and cooperation in cultural evolution. Behavioural Processes, 161, 108116.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Smith, D., Schlaepfer, P., Major, K., Dyble, M., Page, A. E., Thompson, J., … Miglian, A. B. (2017). Cooperation and the evolution of hunter-gatherer storytelling. Nature Communications, 8, 1853.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Smith, J. E., Gavrilets, S., Mulder, M. B., Hooper, P. L., ElMouden, C., Nettle, D., … Smith, E. A. (2016). Leadership in mammalian societies: Emergence, distribution, power, and payoff. Trends in Ecology and Evolution, 31, 5466.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Song, G., Ma, Q., Wu, F., & Li, L. (2012). The psychological explanation of conformity. Social Behavior and Personality, 40, 13651372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sparkman, G., & Walton, G. M. (2019). Witnessing change: Dynamic norms help resolve diverse barriers to personal change. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 82, 238252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Suhay, E. (2015). Explaining group influence: The role of identity and emotion in political conformity and polarization. Political Behavior, 37, 221251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Szekely, A., Lipari, F., Antonioni, A., Paolucci, M., Sánchez, A., Tummolini, L., & Andrighetto, G. (2021). Collective risks change social norms and promote cooperation: Evidence from a long-term experiment. Nature Communications, 12, 5452.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tajfel, H. (1981). Human groups and social categories: Studies in social psychology. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tajfel, H., & Turner, J. C. (1979). An integrative theory of intergroup conflict. In W. G. A. & Worchel, S. (Ed.), The social psychology of intergroup relation (pp. 3347). Brooks/Cole.Google Scholar
Tankard, M. E., & Paluck, E. L. (2016). Norm perception as a vehicle for social change. Social Issues and Policy Review, 10, 181211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tembine, H. (2017). Mean-field-type games. AIMS Mathematics, 2, 706735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tormos, R. (2020). The rhythm of modernization. How values change over time. Brill.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tverskoi, D., Guido, A., Andrighetto, G., Sánchez, A., & Gavrilets, S. (2022). Disentangling material, social, and cognitive determinants of human behavior and beliefs. Evolutionary Human Science.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyler, T. R. (1997). The psychology of legitimacy: A relational perspective on voluntary deference to authorities. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 1, 323345.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Verdier, T., & Zenou, Y. (2018). Cultural leader and the dynamics of assimilation. Journal of Economic Theory, 175, 374414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Watts, D. J. (2002). A simple model of global cascades on random networks. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 99, 57665771.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Whiten, A. (2017). Social learning and culture in child and chimpanzee. Annual Review of Psychology, 68, 129154.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wiessner, P. (2005). Norm enforcement among the Ju/’hoansi Bushmen. A case of strong reciprocity? Human Nature, 16, 115145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiessner, P., & Tumu, A. (1998). Historical vines: Enga networks of exchange, ritual, and warfare in Papua New Guinea. Smithsonian Institution Press.Google Scholar
Wiessner, P. W. (2014). Embers of society: Firelight talk among the Ju/’hoansi bushmen. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences USA, 111, 1402714935.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Wright, S. (1931). Evolution in mendelian populations. Genetics, 16, 97159.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Zino, L., Ye, M., & Cao, M. (2020). A two-layer model for coevolving opinion dynamics and collective decision-making in complex social systems. Chaos, 20, 083107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Main variables, functions, and parameters

Figure 1

Figure 1. Predictions of the food sharing model for different efficiencies F of inculcation promoting sharing (G = 1). Left: the dynamics of the average attitude y (blue curves) and the frequency of sharers p (red curves) for 10 different independent runs for each value of F. Right: the initial (white bars) and final (blue bars) distributions of attitudes for one run. The blue and red vertical lines mark the mean attitude $\bar{y}$ and the frequency p of sharers respectively. Log–normal distribution of initial values of y with mean 0.2 and standard deviation 0.1. Parameters: benefit lost to sharing c = 1, 100 groups of size n = 10, precision in decision-making λ = 10, standard deviation of error in attitude updating σ = 0.05, probability of attitude updating uy = 0.5, dispersal rate m = 0.1, probability of successful hunting s = 0.15. Individual parameters k1, k2, k3 and α, β, γ are chosen from broken stick distributions on [0, 1] while parameter v is set to 1.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Predictions of the political protests model for different intensities of propaganda F promoting protests (G = 1). Left: the dynamics of the average attitude y (blue curves) and the frequency of protesters p (red curves) for 10 different independent runs for each value of F. Right: the initial (white bars) and final (blue bars) distributions of attitudes for one run. The blue and red vertical lines mark the mean attitude $\bar{y}$ and the frequency p of protests respectively. Log–normal distribution of initial values of y with mean 0.2 and standard deviation 0.1. Parameters: population size n = 1000, precision in decision-making λ = 10, standard deviation of error in attitude updating σ = 0.05, probability of attitude updating uy = 0.5.

Supplementary material: PDF

Gavrilets and Richerson supplementary material

Gavrilets and Richerson supplementary material

Download Gavrilets and Richerson supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 500 KB