Hostname: page-component-5b777bbd6c-6lqsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-06-18T11:37:13.315Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Optimizing microplastic pollution in a terrestrial environment: a case for soil-biodegradable mulches

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 May 2025

Jingze Jiang*
Affiliation:
Department of Business, Economics & Communication, Pennsylvania Western University, Edinboro, PA, USA
Thomas L. Marsh
Affiliation:
School of Economic Sciences & Paul G. Allen School for Global Animal Health, Washington State University, Pullman, WA, USA
Eric Belasco
Affiliation:
Department of Agricultural Economics and Economics, Montana State University, Bozeman, MT, USA
*
Corresponding author: Jingze Jiang; Email: jjiang@pennwest.edu
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Microplastic pollution from plastic fragments accumulating in agricultural fields threatens the world’s most productive soils and environmental sustainability. This is the first paper to address the challenge of developing a dynamic economic model to analyze the adoption of soil-biodegradable plastic mulches (BDMs) as a sustainable alternative to conventional polyethylene mulches. The model considers the trade-off between BDM degradation rates and agricultural production, seeking to balance the cost of BDMs and the cost of waste disposal. We consider both private and social perspectives under deterministic and stochastic environments. Our findings suggest that BDMs can significantly decrease long-term plastic pollution from single-use plastics in agriculture. For example, increasing landfill tipping fees incentivizes Washington State tomato growers to optimally adopt BDMs with a 61% degradation rate and to till used BDMs into the soil, reducing plastic waste accumulation in landfills. The study highlights the role of economic incentives, such as landfill fees, corrective taxes and the role of risk aversion, in promoting BDM adoption and curbing plastic pollution. The framework presented here offers valuable insights for policymakers and stakeholders seeking to foster sustainable agricultural practices and mitigate global plastic pollution.

Type
Research Article
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2025. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Northeastern Agricultural and Resource Economics Association

Introduction

The popular use of plastics in agriculture, while boosting productivity (Ingman et al Reference Ingman, Santelmann and Tilt2015; Steinmetz et al Reference Steinmetz, Wollmann, Schaefer, Buchmann, David, Tröger, Frör and Schaumann2016) and ensuring food security in the short run (Brodhagen et al Reference Brodhagen, Goldberger, Hayes, Inglis, Marsh and Miles2017; Coskun et al Reference Coskun, Britto, Shi and Kronzucker2017), has caused a pressing environmental dilemma (Rochman Reference Rochman2018). Conventional plastic products, like those made from polyethylene, have increased crop yields across the world. For example, cotton, maize, and wheat yields have increased by 30% in China (Bloomberg 2017). Polyethylene mulches (PEMs) are a prime example of beneficial plastics for food production, widely used in commercial agriculture around the world.Footnote 1 The scale of their use is substantial: U.S. farmers alone use 1 billion pounds of plastic annually, with 40% being plastic mulches (Kirkham et al Reference Kirkham, Antony and Bolan2020). In China, a staggering 1.45 million metric tons of plastic mulches covered nearly 50 million acres of farmland in 2017, representing 12% of the country’s total farmland (Bloomberg 2017).

The accumulation of microplastics, arising from the deterioration of PEMs in fields, pose a significant threat to long-term soil health (Brodhagen et al Reference Brodhagen, Goldberger, Hayes, Inglis, Marsh and Miles2017; Cao Reference Cao2011; Jiang et al Reference Jiang, Ma, Li and Zhang1998; Yan et al Reference Yan, Mei, He and Zheng2006), water quality, and the delicate balance of marine ecosystems. PEMs, a common choice, lack degradability but deteriorate under UV radiation, necessitating single season use (Miles et al Reference Miles, Wallace, Wszelaki, Martin, Cowan, Walters and Inglis2012; Wang et al Reference Wang, Ma and Ji2020). Recycling PEMs is often cost-prohibitive due to collection, sorting, cleaning, and transportation (Cameron and Dudek Reference Cameron and Dudek2009; Goldberger, et al Reference Goldberger, DeVetter and Dentzman2019; Velandia, et al Reference Velandia, DeLong, Wszelaki, Schexnayder, Clark and Jensen2020b). Additionally, burning used PEMs is typically illegal due to environmental concerns (Russo et al Reference Russo, Candura and Scarascia-Mugnozza2004). Consequently, landfill disposal remains a common practice in the U.S. (Goldberger et al Reference Goldberger, DeVetter and Dentzman2019; Madrid et al. Reference Madrid, Wortman, Hayes, DeBruyn, Miles, Flury, Marsh, Galinato, Englund, Agehara and DeVetter2022a). However, as PEMs deteriorate in landfills, microplastics are released, further contaminating terrestrial soil and water, as well as threatening fish and wildlife.

Soil-biodegradable plastic mulches (BDMs), have emerged as a promising solution, offering a more environmentally friendly approach to managing agricultural plastic mulch waste. However, to assure BDM films are an economic viable alternative, several challenges must be overcome. BDMs incur an often-higher cost compared to their conventional counterparts, PEMs, presenting a significant barrier to their widespread implementation. Furthermore, unreliable degradation rates of new BDM products during the production season can influence their efficacy in critical agricultural functions such as weed suppression and moisture retention, potentially impacting crop yields. The inherent uncertainty surrounding the degradation process and its susceptibility to environmental fluctuations further complicates the decision-making process for farmers and policymakers (Madrid et al Reference Madrid, Goldberger, Miles and DeVetter2022b).

The intricate trade-off between the environmental benefit of BDMs and their performance in agricultural production underscores the need for a more comprehensive economic evaluation. The resolution of this complex problem can help foster the adoption of sustainable agricultural practices and mitigate the global plastic pollution issue.

To capture the accumulation of plastic pollutants over time, this study utilizes a dynamic model, which offers a more complete understanding of intertemporal environmental interactions compared to static models that assume a level of pollutant unchanged by time. Dynamic models effectively capture the evolution of pollutant stocks, accounting for both the natural degradation of pollutants and the addition of new pollutants through emissions (Tietenberg Reference Tietenberg2004)Footnote 2 .

Literature review

The detrimental effects of microplastic pollution in both aquatic and terrestrial ecosystems have been extensively documented (Eriksen et al Reference Eriksen, Mason, Wilson, Box, Zellers, Edwards, Farley and Amato2013; Free et al Reference Free, Jensen, Mason, Eriksen, Williamson and Boldgiv2014; Horton et al Reference Horton, Walton, Spurgeon, Lahive and Svendsen2017; Mason et al Reference Mason, Garneau, Sutton, Chu, Ehmann, Barnes, Fink, Papazissimos and Rogers2016; Nizzetto et al. Reference Nizzetto, Futter and Langaas2016; Rochman Reference Rochman2018). Defined as plastic particles less than 5mm in diameter, microplastics pose a significant threat due to their invisibility compared to larger debris and their extremely slow degradation rate. Unlike organic matter, microplastics rarely decompose into harmless compounds like CO2 or H2O, instead accumulating persistently in the environment (Andrady Reference Andrady2011).Footnote 3 This accumulation poses a risk to aquatic and terrestrial wildlife, with documented cases of injury or mortality in birds, fish, turtles, invertebrates, and mammals through suffocation or poisoning by toxic chemicals, many of which are associated with cancer (Baldwin et al. Reference Baldwin, Corsi and Mason2016). Furthermore, Horton et al. (Reference Horton, Walton, Spurgeon, Lahive and Svendsen2017) estimate that 80% of microplastics found in oceans originate from freshwater sources, highlighting the critical role of terrestrial pollution pathways. Agricultural activities, particularly runoff and improper land management practices, contribute significantly to microplastic contamination in soil (Steinmetz et al Reference Steinmetz, Wollmann, Schaefer, Buchmann, David, Tröger, Frör and Schaumann2016), ultimately impacting the marine environment. This concern aligns with the 2000 National Water Quality Inventory by the United State Environmental Protection Agency (2000), which identified agricultural nonpoint source pollution as the leading threat to US water quality. To address the pressing issue of microplastic pollution, this study examines the trade-off between the environmental benefits of BDMs and their potentially lower performance in agricultural production, aiming to comprehensively evaluate this trade-off from an economic standpoint.

Soil-biodegradable plastics have emerged as a potentially competitive alternative to conventional plastics, offering a more sustainable solution to mitigating agricultural plastic waste and pollution. These plastics are derived from biobased feedstocks or a combination of biobased and fossil fuel sources (Miles and Ghimire Reference Miles and Ghimire2020). They degrade biologically under anaerobic or aerobic conditions, ultimately breaking down into harmless byproducts like carbon dioxide, water, and minerals (Avérous and Halley Reference Avérous and Halley2014). Recent advancements in soil-biodegradable plastics technology have improved their performance in agricultural applications (Ghimire et al Reference Ghimire, Wszelaki, Moore, Inglis and Miles2018; Mohanty et al Reference Mohanty, Misra and Hinrichsen2000; Sintim et al Reference Sintim, Bandopadhyay, English, Bary, DeBruyn, Schaeffer and Flury2019; Tofanelli & Wortman, Reference Tofanelli and Wortman2020).

Despite their environmental benefits, several challenges impede the widespread adoption of BDMs as a full replacement for PEMs in agriculture. The higher cost of BDMs compared to PEMs poses a significant economic challenge for farmers (Velandia et al Reference Velandia, Smith, Wszelaki, Galinato and Marsh2018; Velandia et al Reference Velandia, Jensen, DeLong, Wszelaki and Rihn2020 c ; Marí et al Reference Marí, Pardo, Cirujeda and Martínez2019). Additionally, the degradation rate of BDMs can influence their effectiveness in weed suppression and moisture conservation, potentially impacting crop yields (Griffin-LaHue et al Reference Griffin-LaHue, Ghimire, Yu, Scheenstra, Miles and Flury2022; Li et al Reference Li, Moore-Kucera, Miles, Leonas, Lee, Corbin and Inglis2014). The uncertainty surrounding the degradation process and its environmental dependence (e.g., the moisture and the temperature level) further complicates the decision-making process for farmers.

Previous studies on BDMs have revealed both potential benefits and challenges, directly relating to our research questions of understanding and optimizing the balance between the environmental benefits and agricultural performance of BDMs. Sintim et al. (Reference Sintim, Bandopadhyay, English, Bary, DeBruyn, Schaeffer and Flury2019) and Sintim and Flury (Reference Sintim and Flury2017) demonstrated the short-term viability of BDMs as an alternative to polyethylene in agricultural production but emphasized the need for further research on their long-term impact on soil health. This highlights the need for a comprehensive economic evaluation that considers both the immediate and long-term consequences of BDM use, as emphasized in our research question. Dentzman and Goldberger (Reference Dentzman and Goldberger2020), Goldberger et al. (Reference Goldberger, DeVetter and Dentzman2019), and Velandia et al. (Reference Velandia, Jensen, DeLong, Wszelaki and Rihn2020c) identified farmer awareness of PEM waste management costs but hesitation to adopt BDMs due to their higher price and uncertainty about their financial and soil quality benefits. Conversely, Chen et al. (Reference Chen, Galinato, Marsh, Tozer and Chouinard2020, Reference Chen, Marsh, Tozer and Galinato2019) found that growers are willing to pay a premium for BDMs if they result in higher crop prices and slower soil quality decline, and that consumers may also pay a premium for crops grown with BDMs. These findings on farmer acceptance and willingness to pay for BDMs highlight the importance of incorporating farmer preferences and economic incentives into the analysis, as the adoption of sustainable agricultural practices depends on the economic viability of BDMs for farmers. Velandia et al. (Reference Velandia, Galinato and Wszelaki2020a, Reference Velandia, Smith, Wszelaki, Galinato and Marsh2018) suggested that the high labor cost of removing and disposing of PEM waste could incentivize BDM adoption.

Despite these findings, a critical gap remains in understanding the dynamic nature and long-term economic and environmental consequences of microplastic accumulation from both conventional and biodegradable mulches. As Bishop (Reference Bishop1993) noted, understanding these consequences, efficiency in particular, is necessary for developing sustainable farming and disposal practices. This is particularly important given concerns about the potential for soil to act as a sink for microplastics (Rillig Reference Rillig2012; Rochman Reference Rochman2018), raising questions about the long-term productivity and economic viability of agricultural systems. This gap in the literature underscores the need for a comprehensive economic evaluation of the trade-off between the environmental benefits of BDMs and their performance in agricultural production, which can help foster the adoption of sustainable agricultural practices and mitigate the global plastic pollution issue.

Therefore, this paper aims to fill this gap by developing a dynamic optimal choice model that considers the trade-off between the degradation rate of plastic mulches and their functionality in agricultural production. By incorporating the costs of plastic residue and disposal, as well as the long-term impact of microplastic accumulation on soil health, this stock pollutant model will provide a comprehensive framework for evaluating the economic and environmental implications of PEMs and BDMs use. The research will also explore the influence of various factors, such as disposal costs, crop prices, BDM certification and corrective tax, on decision-making regarding BDMs adoption and use.

While static models have informed the analysis of agricultural pollution control policies, dynamic models offer a more nuanced understanding of intertemporal environmental management, particularly for pollutants that accumulate over time. Static models inherently assume a constant level of pollutants, a limitation acknowledged in previous works (Braden et al Reference Braden, Johnson, Bouzaher and Miltz1989; Griffin and Bromley Reference Griffin and Bromley1982; Innes Reference Innes2000; Jacobs and Timmons Reference Jacobs and Timmons1974). In contrast, dynamic models, exemplified by the work of Conrad and Clark (Reference Conrad and Clark1987) and applied to nitrogen control (Martínez and Albiac Reference Martínez and Albiac2004) and pesticide mitigation (Anderson et al Reference Anderson, Opaluch and Sullivan1985; Conrad and Olson Reference Conrad and Olson1992), capture the fundamental concept of pollutant stock evolution in agricultural systems. These models recognize the natural degradation of pollutant stocks over time, alongside the addition of new pollutants through emissions. This concept extends beyond agriculture, as demonstrated in studies of aggregated polluters (Germain et al Reference Germain, Toint, Tulkens, Zeeuw, Chander, Drèze, Lovell and Mintz2006; Jørgensen and Zaccour Reference Jørgensen and Zaccour2001). Our framework builds on this literature, applies an intertemporal approach to evaluate plastic mulch pollution and uses computational methodology to simulate an illustrative numerical example to understand the impact of incentives.

Dynamic models

Following previous studies in agricultural pollution control (Anderson et al Reference Anderson, Opaluch and Sullivan1985; Conrad and Olson Reference Conrad and Olson1992; Conrad and Clark Reference Conrad and Clark1987; Martínez and Albiac Reference Martínez and Albiac2004), we develop a dynamic optimal control model for a representative grower. The private grower model analyzes the optimal degradation rate of plastic mulches, plastic residue management, and disposal decisions. Next, we introduce biodegradation standards and then extend the private grower model to a social planner model with an optimal corrective tax.

Private grower optimization

Consider N identical growers who use one type of plastic mulch in growing a single crop on a homogeneous farm under an infinite planning horizon. Initially each representative grower has perfect information of the degradation rate of mulches, and each grower is indexed by i. We assume that the market can offer different types of plastic mulches characterized by an in-soil degradation rate, ${\delta _{i,t}}$ where the degradation rate parameter ${\delta _{i,t}}$ is assumed to be between 0% and 100% ( $0{ \le _{i,t}} \le 1$ ).Footnote 4 The degradation rate equal to 0% represents the PEMs that have no degradation during a crop year t. If the in-soil degradation rate is greater than 0% but no more than 100% (0 < ${\delta _{i,t}} \le $ 1), the plastic mulch is identified as a BDM. When the degradation rate is equal to 100%, it implies the completely degradable BDMs. Because of environmental differences for degradation rates in-soil as opposed to above the soil, the above-soil degradation rate is denoted as ${\xi _{i,t}}{\rm{\;}} = \theta _{i,t}^{ - 1}({\delta _{i,t}})$ . Then the function ${\delta _{i,t}} = \theta \left( {{\xi _{i,t}}} \right)$ expresses the in-soil degradation rate as a function of above-soil degradation rate. We assume the above-soil degradation rate is a monotone function of ${\delta _{i,t}}$ , and the value of $\;{\xi _{i,t}},{\rm{\;}} = $ $\theta _{i,t}^{ - 1}\left( . \right)$ is between 0% and 100% as well.Footnote 5 No matter the type of plastic mulches used by the farmer, the waste management decision on disposal of used plastic mulches will affect the plastic stock of pollution in the farmland soil. Henceforth, to focus the analysis, we assume if the farmer does not dispose of the plastic mulch waste after the growing season, then the used plastic mulches will be incorporated in the soil contributing to the plastic pollutant stock in the farmland soil, ${S_{i,t}}$ .Footnote 6

We assume the production function for each grower, i, $Q\left( {{\xi _{i,t}};{S_{i,t}}} \right) = Q\left( {{\theta ^{ - 1}}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right);{S_{i,t}}} \right),$ is a continuously differentiable strictly decreasing function of the degradation rate, ${\delta _{it}}$ and the plastic pollutant stock in the farmland soil, ${S_{i,t}}$ , ( ${Q_\delta }$ <0, $\;{Q_S}$ <0).Footnote 7 The production function $Q\left( . \right)$ is strictly concave ( ${Q_{\delta \delta }} \lt 0,\;{Q_{SS}} \lt 0,\;{Q_{S\delta }} = 0,$ ). The grower i is assumed to sell all the crops at the market price, ${P_t}$ . Hence, ${P_t}Q\left( {{\theta ^{ - 1}}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right);{S_{i,t}}} \right)$ represents the revenue of grower i’s farm at the end of the crop year. Figure 1 illustrates a grower’s decision flowchart, and box A is corresponding to the revenue.

Figure 1. Grower decision-making flow chartFootnote 9 .

The cost function has two components, the production costs and the disposal costs. The grower’s private input cost function, $C\left( {{\delta _{i,t}}} \right)$ , is a strictly increasing function of the degradation rate ( ${C_\delta } \gt 0$ ) to recognize that the cost of BDMs is higher than that of PEMs. The input cost function is non-concave ( ${C_{\delta \delta }} \ge 0).\;$ The production costs are represented by box B in Figure 1. The term $w{h_t}\left( {\theta _{it}^{ - 1}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right),{z_{it}}} \right)$ represents the plastic-mulch-waste disposal cost, where $w$ (measured in $/lb) is the disposal rate.Footnote 8 ${h_t}\left( {\theta _{it}^{ - 1}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right),{z_{it}}} \right)$ is the amount of plastic mulch waste disposed at disposal facilities (measured in pounds), where ${h_t}\left( . \right)$ is a non-decreasing function of the portion of plastic mulch waste, ${z_{it}}$ , handled by the disposal facility ( ${h_z} \ge 0)$ , but a strictly decreasing function of the degradation rate ( ${h_\delta } \lt 0$ ). It is non-concave ( ${h_{\delta \delta }} \ge 0)\;$ in the degradation rate. The disposal costs are represented by box C in Figure 1.

Following previous literature, the discount factor $0 \lt \rho \lt 1\;$ indicates that the grower values the current profit more than the future profit (Conrad and Olson Reference Conrad and Olson1992; Martínez and Albiac Reference Martínez and Albiac2004). Therefore, the grower’s objective of maximizing the discounted sum of current and future annual profits from selling a single crop is specified as

$$Max\;_\left\{ {{\delta _{it}},{z_{it}}} \right\}\;\pi \left( {{\delta _{it}},{z_{it}};{S_{it}},w} \right)$$
(1) $$= Max\;_\left\{ {{\delta _{it}},{z_{it}}} \right\}\;\mathop \sum \limits_{t = 0}^\infty {\rho ^t}\left[ {{P_t}{Q_{it}}\left( {\theta _{it}^{ - 1}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right);{S_{it}}} \right) - {C_{it}}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right) - {w}{h_t}\left( {\theta _{it}^{ - 1}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right),{z_{it}}} \right)} \right]$$

Subject to

(2) $${S_{it + 1}} = {G_{it}}\left( {{\delta _{it}},{z_{it}};{S_{it}},w,\overline {{S_{base,\;t}}} } \right)$$
(3) $$0 \le {\delta _{it}} \le 1$$
(4) $${z_{it}} = 0\;or\;1$$
(5) $${S_0} = \bar S\;and\;{h_t} \ge 0\;$$

where the grower i simultaneously chooses a mulch with degradation rate, ${\delta _{it}}$ for the local environment, and the portion of plastic mulch waste handled by the disposal facility, ${z_{it}}$ , which can have a value between 0 and 1. In practice most growers either dispose of all ( ${z_{it}} = 1$ ) or none ( ${z_{it}} = 0$ ) of the plastic mulch waste, which form individual corner solutions.Footnote 10

Equation 2 is the function of the evolution for the plastic pollutant stock in the farm soil. At the end of each crop year, the plastic pollutant stock in the farm soil, ${S_{i,t + 1}}$ , will come from two sources: the plastic pollutant stock in the farmland soil from previous crop years and the in-flow of undisposed plastic mulch residue from the current crop year. At the beginning of the crop year, the farmland soil has contained plastic pollutant stock, ${S_{it}}$ , but during the crop year, ${S_{it}}$ degrades in the soil with a degradation rate, ${\delta _{it}}$ . Therefore, ${G_{it}}\left( . \right)$ is an increasing function of the plastic pollutant stock, ${S_{it}}\left( {0 \le {G_s} \le 1} \right),$ but a decreasing function of the in-soil degradation rate, ${\delta _{it}}$ . $\overline {{S_{base,\;t}}} $ is a base level of residue from PEM (or BDM for that matter) whether the mulch goes to a landfill or stays on the property. We also assume that if the completely degradable BDMs are used, the accumulated plastic mulch pollutant stock will equal to a base level, $\overline {{S_{base,\;t}}} $ . We assume ${G_{it}}\left( . \right)$ is subject to the curvature conditions: ${G_{\delta \delta }} \ge 0,{G_{ss}} \ge 0\;and\;{G_{s\delta }} \le 0$ .

The discrete current value Hamiltonian (Shone Reference Shone2003) is

(6) $$H = {P_t}{Q_{it}}\left( . \right) - {C_{it}}\left( . \right) - w{h_t}\left( . \right) + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}\left( {{G_{it}}\left( . \right) - {S_{it}}} \right)$$

where ${\lambda _{i,t + 1}}$ can be interpreted as the shadow price whose value is negative. The shadow price measures the loss in future profit due to additional plastic pollutant stock in the farmland soil reducing the soil productivity. The Karush-Kuhn-Tucker conditions (equations 7 - 10) and the sufficient transversality condition (equation 11) are as follows:

$${{\partial H} \over {\partial \delta }} = {P_t}_\delta - {C_\delta } - w{h_\delta } + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_\delta } \gt 0\;\;yields \Rightarrow \;\;\delta _{it}^* = 1\;$$
(7) $${{\partial H} \over {\partial \delta }} = {P_t}{Q_\delta } - {C_\delta } - w{h_\delta } + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_\delta } \lt 0\;\;yields \Rightarrow \;\delta _{it}^* = 0\;$$
$${{\partial H} \over {\partial \delta }} = {P_t}{Q_\delta } - {C_\delta } - w{h_\delta } + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_\delta } = 0\;\;yields \Rightarrow \;0 \lt \delta _{it}^* \lt 1$$
(8) $${{\partial H} \over {\partial z}} = - w{h_z} + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_z} \lt 0\;\;yields \Rightarrow \;\;z_{it}^* = 0$$
$${{\partial H} \over {\partial z}} = - {h_z} + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_z} \gt 0\;\;yields \Rightarrow \;z_{it}^* = 1$$

Footnote 11

(9) $${\partial \over {\partial S}} = {P_t}{Q_S} + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}\left( {{G_S} - 1} \right) = - \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}} + {\lambda _{i,t}}$$
(10) $${{\partial H} \over {\partial \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}}} = {G_{it}}\left( {{\delta _{it}},{z_{it}};{S_{it}},w,\overline {{S_{base,\;t}}} } \right) - {S_{it}} \ge 0$$
(11) $${\rho ^t}{\lambda _{i,t}}{S_{i,t}} = 0\;$$

We use ${\lambda ^*},\;{\delta ^*},{S^*},$ and ${z^*}$ to denote the steady-state solutions. Condition (8) quantifies the differences between the marginal cost ( $ - w{h_z}$ ) and marginal benefit ( $ - \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_z}$ ) associated with the disposal decision. Both the cost and benefit of disposal are not associated with crop production function or crop price. If the marginal cost is large than the marginal benefit of disposing mulch waste, i.e., $ - w{h_z} + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_z} \lt 0$ , the grower will till all used plastic mulches into the farmland soil. This practice leads to a continuous accumulation of plastic pollutants, diminishing soil productivity and ultimately causing the grower to cease farming operations. Consequently, the model will converge towards the transversality condition (11). An increase in disposal costs and fees, $w$ , will elevate the marginal cost of disposing mulch waste, making condition $ - w{h_z} + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_z} \lt 0$ more likely to be satisfied. Therefore, the grower is more inclined to till all used plastic mulches into the soil.

However, if the marginal cost is smaller than the marginal benefit of disposing mulch waste, i.e., $\; - w{h_z} + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_z} \gt 0$ the grower will opt to send all used plastic mulches to a disposal facility. In this case, the plastic pollutant stock in the farmland soil is determined by an accumulated base level of residue from mulch even if it goes to a disposal facility.

Considering condition (7) that identifies the degradation rate decision, we first discuss the boundary solutions. Suppose that ${P_t}{Q_\delta } - {C_\delta } - w{h_\delta } + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_\delta } \gt 0,$ then the optimal in-soil degradation rate ${\delta ^*} = 1$ (the fully degradable BDMs). Therefore, if $z_{it}^*$ is equal to 0, the optimal pollutant stock in the farmland soil ${S^*}$ will only be determined by initial plastic residue in the farmland soil. Considering the case in which ${P_t}{Q_\delta } - {C_\delta } - w{h_\delta } + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}{G_\delta } \lt 0,$ we obtain that the optimal in-soil degradation rate ${\delta ^*} = 0$ , which is the conventional PEMs.

We now turn to the interior solution, where $0 \lt \delta _{it}^* \lt 1$ . We follow Schnitkey and Miranda (Reference Schnitkey and Miranda1993) to drop the time subscript t, and grower subscript i, and denote the steady state for a representative grower as ${\lambda ^*}$ , ${\delta ^*},{S^*},{z^*}$ . Therefore, the optimal degradation rate at the steady state satisfies the equation (12) (see derivation is in Appendix A)

(12) $${\delta ^*} = {\Psi ^{ - 1}}\left( {{{{C_\delta } + {\rm{w}}{h_\delta }} \over {\bar P}}} \right)$$

where ${\Psi ^{ - 1}}\left( . \right)$ is the inverse function of $\Psi \left( . \right)$ with respect to the degradation rate, and it is a strictly decreasing function of ${{({C_\delta } + w{h_\delta })} \over {\bar P}}$ . Equation (12) identifies the steady-state degradation responses relative to changes in key parameters. Consequently, when the crop price, $\bar P,$ increases, the grower is more likely to use plastic mulches with a higher degradation rate. In other words, when crop prices are higher, farmers have the financial incentive to prioritize long-term soil improvement by choosing the faster-degrading mulch with higher upfront cost. Equation (12) also predicts that for a higher the disposal rate and fee, $\;w$ , then a mulch with a higher degradation rate will be chosen by the grower.Footnote 12 If disposal fees for plastic mulch are very high in the farmer’s area, the economic benefits of faster degradation could outweigh other considerations. A higher degradation rate means less plastic to haul away and pay for at the end of the season. Essentially, the analysis of equation (12) reveals that higher crop prices or higher disposal cost incentivize growers to invest in practices that maximize long-term yield and minimize costs. Growers will weigh the benefits of faster degradation (reduced disposal costs and soil health) against the potentially higher upfront cost of BDMs. The relationship revealed in this research aligns with existing research on the private interest of farmers in maintaining or increasing soil quality. Note that Issanchou et al. (Reference Issanchou, Daniel, Dupraz and Ropars-Collet2019) reported that crop prices positively influence farmer investments in soil conservation.

Biodegradation standards

In this section, we relax the assumption of perfect information regarding degradation rate. Here, growers rely on biodegradation standards and certifications to identify biodegradable plastic mulches. Plastic producers substantiate degradability claims by adhering to national or international standards (Federal Trade Commission 2012, 2014). Several standards guide the identification of biodegradable plastics in various environments (compost, marine, etc.): ASTM D6400 and D5526-11 (US), EN 13432 and EN 17033 (Europe/Japan), and ISO 17088. These standards establish protocols, materials, and conditions for testing, as well as define degradation rate benchmarks for certified soil-biodegradable plastics. For instance, ASTM D6400 certifies a plastic as soil-biodegradable if at least 90% of its organic carbon converts to CO2 within 180 days under controlled laboratory conditions (Avérous and Halley Reference Avérous and Halley2014).

In other words, asymmetric information creates a challenge for BDMs production. When farmers lack complete knowledge of BDMs’ degradation rate, BDMs manufactures are required to produce BDMs meeting the standard, the variety of plastic mulches offered with varying degradation rates may be lower compared to a scenario with perfect information. To reflect such conditions, the constraint (3) will be modified as follows:

(13) $${\delta _{it}} = 0\;\;or\;\;0.9 \le {\delta _{it}} \le 1$$

Let ${\delta ^C}\;$ denote the optimal degradation rate under the current biodegradation certification scheme. If ${\delta ^*}$ defined in equation (13) is no smaller than 90% ( ${\delta ^*} \ge 0.9$ ), ${\delta ^C} = {\delta ^*}$ . However, if ${\delta ^*} \lt 0.9$ , then the optimal choice will depend on the general shape of a grower’s profit function.

Figure 2 depicts three plausible scenarios. Figure 2(a) depicts the scenario that the lifetime profit is larger when a grower chooses PEMs rather than BDMs meeting standards. A grower would gain a higher lifetime profit by using BDMs meeting standards with a 90% degradation rate than PEMs if the scenario represented in Figure 2(b) happened. We also can observe the situation depicted in Figure 2(c) where there is no difference between using PEMs or BDMs meeting standards with a 90% degradation rate to achieve the highest lifetime profit. Simulation methods are applied in section “Empirical model and data” to characterize the shape of a grower’s profit function so that we are able to study the grower’s optimal choice under current biodegradation standards in section “Results and discussion.”

Figure 2. Lifetime profits comparison between using PEMs and using BDMs meeting standards.a). PEMs is optimum b). BDMs meeting standards is optimum c). Both PEMs and BDMs meeting standards are optimum. Note: both point A and B achieve a local optimum. To obtain the global optimum, we need to compare the profit at point A and B, and the one having higher profit will be the global optimum.

Social planner optimization

This section expands our model to consider the social optimum and the policy implications of aligning individual grower decisions with the social planner’s choice (assuming perfect information).

While growers manage plastic mulch waste on-farm to minimize reductions in crop productivity from soil pollution, negative environmental externalities still persist. Landfilling, a common disposal method, contributes to the global plastic waste crisis, harming terrestrial (Dreyer et al Reference Dreyer, Fourie and Kok1999; Lgbokwe et al Reference Lgbokwe, Kolo and Egwu2003; Omidi et al Reference Omidi, Naeemipoor and Hosseini2012) and marine animals (Cameron and Dudek Reference Cameron and Dudek2009; Derraik Reference Derraik2002; Joyner and Frew Reference Joyner and Frew1991). Incineration releases greenhouse gases by converting petroleum-based carbon into atmospheric carbon (Ellis et al Reference Ellis, Kantner, Saab and Watson2005; Gautam Reference Gautam2009).

To mitigate negative externalities arising from pollution, social planners can employ various environmental policies. Three primary instruments exist for pollution control, aiming to achieve a socially optimal outcome (Baumol and Oates Reference Baumol and Oates1988; Kolstad Reference Kolstad2011). Command-and-control regulations directly limit pollution emissions or mandate specific technologies. While offering certainty in pollution reduction and potentially simplifying complex environmental processes, this approach can discourage innovation in pollution control methods (Kolstad Reference Kolstad2011). Pollution fees (or taxes) incentivize polluters to internalize external costs by imposing a charge on their emissions (Pigou Reference Pigou1932). Pollution permits utilize a market-based approach where a limited number of permits are issued and traded among firms. Both fees and permits are price-based incentives that require less information than command-and-control and can be cost-effective due to market-driven adjustments. However, these price-based instruments may struggle to address the complexities of environmental systems without becoming overly complicated themselves (Kolstad Reference Kolstad2011) and may face challenges in accurately measuring marginal social damage (Baumol and Oates Reference Baumol, Oates, Bohm and Kneese1971).

Consequently, many scholars advocate for a hybrid approach that combines the strengths of both quantity-based and price-based instruments (Baumol and Oates Reference Baumol, Oates, Bohm and Kneese1971; Jacobs and Timmons Reference Jacobs and Timmons1974; Moffitt et al. Reference Moffitt, Zilberman and Just1978; Schnitkey and Miranda Reference Schnitkey and Miranda1993; Holland Reference Holland2012). This typically involves setting a cap on total pollution allowed and using a market mechanism (such as a tax or a tradable permit system with a price ceiling) to ensure the cap is not exceeded. This approach allows policymakers to achieve emission reduction targets while encouraging innovation in pollution control.

Therefore, we adopt the hybrid approach in this research and assume that the social planner aims to control both plastic pollutant stock in farmland and waste disposed of in landfill facilities with a limitation. Such a limitation can be expressed as an extra constraint for the optimization problem

(14) $$\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^N {S_{it}} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^N {h_{it}} \le \overline {{D_t}} $$

where the maximum level of the plastic mulch waste is exogenously determined by the social planner as $\overline {{D_t}} $ .

The socially optimal problem is to maximize the summation of all growers’ profit in equation (15) subject to conditions (2) to (5) and constraint (14)

(15) $$W = \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^N \mathop \sum \limits_{ t= 0}^\infty {\rho ^t}\left[ {{P_t}{Q_{it}}\left( {{\theta ^{ - 1}}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right),{S_{it}}} \right) - {C_{it}}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right) - w{h_t}\left( {\theta _{it}^{ - 1}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right),{z_{it}}} \right)} \right]\;$$

Therefore, the discrete current value Hamiltonian is as follows:

(16) $$\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^N \;\left[ {{P_t}{Q_{it}}\left( . \right) - {C_{it}}\left( . \right) - w{h_t}\left( . \right) + \rho {\lambda _{i,t + 1}}\left( {{G_{it}}\left( . \right) - {S_{it}}} \right)} \right]\; - {\tau _{i,t}}\left[ {\mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^N {S_{it}} + \mathop \sum \limits_{i = 1}^N {h_{it}} - \overline {{D_t}} } \right]$$

where ${\tau _{i,t}}\;$ is the shadow price associated with the plastic mulch waste constraint (14), which represents the minimum monetary incentive the social planner has to impose on grower i so that the total amount of plastic mulch pollution in the farmland soil ( ${S_{it}})$ and the plastic waste sent to disposal facilities ( ${h_{it}})$ from all growers, N, will not be over the limit $\overline {{D_t}} $ . Therefore, ${\tau _{i,t}}$ can be considered as a corrective tax. By solving the first-order conditions of discrete current value Hamiltonian, if the constraint (14) is binding, we find that the optimal corrective tax is defined as

(17) $${\tau ^w} = {{{\rm{\bar P}}\Psi \left( . \right) - {C_\delta } - {\rm{w}}{h_\delta }} \over {{h_\delta }}}$$

Note that if the plastic mulch waste generated by all growers are less than the limit, $\mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^N {S_{it}} + \mathop \sum \nolimits_{i = 1}^N {h_{it}} \lt \overline {{D_t}} $ , the optimal corrective tax is ${\tau ^w} = 0$ . Since the models for the individual grower and social planner cannot be completely solved analytically, we turn to simulation methods to solve for the optimal solutions to the models. Figure 1, Box D illustrates that once the social planner determines the corrective tax amount, growers will incorporate the tax into their decision-making, internalizing the social cost of plastic pollution and considering both farmland and landfill impacts. The numerical methods and results are discussed in sections “Empirical model and data, Results and discussion.”

Empirical model and data

In this section, we introduce an empirical economic model of plastic residue in farmland soil, which is more likely than the theoretical model to capture the complexities intrinsic to real-world economic behavior. First, a deterministic model and then a stochastic extension of the model are presented in the Appendix C. Then, data for a case study application in tomato production in the state of Washington are discussed.

Illustrative case study: deterministic environment

Grounded in the optimization specification and Karush-Kuhn-Tucker equations (1)-(11), and following Schnitkey and Miranda (Reference Schnitkey and Miranda1993) and Miranda and Fackler (Reference Miranda and Fackler2004), we apply the functional forms:

(18) $${Q_{it}} = {\alpha _0} - {\alpha _1}{\delta _{it}} - {\alpha _2}{S_{it}} - {1 \over 2}{\alpha _{11}}\delta _{it}^2 - {1 \over 2}{\alpha _{22}}S_{it}^2$$
(19) $${h_{it}} = {\beta _1}{z_{it}} - {\beta _{12}}{\delta _{it}}{z_{it}}$$
(20) $${C_{it}} = {v_0} + {v_1}{\delta _{it}}$$
(21) $${G_{it}} = {\eta _0} - {\eta _1}{\delta _{it}} + {\eta _2}{S_{it}} - {\eta _3}{z_{it}} - {\eta _{13}}{\delta _{it}}{z_{it}} + {\eta _4}$$
(22) $$w = \tilde w*\varphi, \;\;where\;\;\varphi = {\chi _0} + {\chi _1}z_{it}^*\;$$

The well-defined functions allow us to numerically illustrate the results. ${\alpha _0}$ represents the crop production under the PEMs. The negative coefficients of the production function ${\alpha _1}$ and ${\alpha _{11}}$ captures the impact of the changes in degradation rates on crop production. Meanwhile, negative coefficients ${\alpha _2}$ and ${\alpha _{22}}$ measure the reduced crop production associated with the increased plastic residue in the farmland soil. The total amount of the plastic mulch used by grower i during period t is denoted as ${\beta _1}$ . ${v_0}$ and ${\eta _0}$ mean the production cost not associated with the plastic mulch and the amount of plastic mulch residue in the farmland soil at the very beginning of period t, respectively. ${\eta _3}$ captures the impact of disposal decisions on the dynamic accumulation of plastic pollutant in the farmland soil. ${\delta _{it}}{z_{it}}$ reflects the interaction between the grower’s disposal decision and the mulch’s degradation rate, which may in turn affect the plastic pollutant in the farmland soil. ${\eta _4}$ represents a base level of residue from PEM (or BDM for that matter) whether the mulch goes to a landfill or stays on the farmland. $w$ is the economic disposal cost, and it is determined by the disposal cost in monetary value, $\tilde w$ , and the effort coefficient $\varphi $ . $\varphi $ is a function of the portion of mulches to be removed from the farmland, $z_{it}^*$ . When near zero portion of mulches is to be removed, then the effort coefficient ${\chi _0} \gt 0$ . As the portion of mulch required to removed increases, the effort coefficient will increase with the rate of ${\chi _1} \gt 0$ . We use effort coefficient to capture the situation that as the grower seeks to remove more percentage of plastic mulch from the farmland to the landfill, the more effort they will put in, which increase the economic disposal cost.

We apply the collocation method to solve the current dynamic economic model (Bellomo et al Reference Bellomo, Lods, Revelli and Ridolfi2007; Golub and Ortega Reference Golub and Ortega1992). Under the deterministic environment, we perform sensitivity analysis to examine how changes in key parameters affect the decision maker’s optimal choice and the accumulation of plastic residue in the farmland soil. Results are presented in section “Results and discussion.”

Data

This study focuses on tomato growers due to readily available data, their extensive use of mulch, and the significance of tomato production within specialty crops.Footnote 13 Tomatoes rank among the top three vegetables in the United States by area harvested and total production, contributing over 50% of the total vegetable category in 2019 (USDA-NASS 2020). Furthermore, their economic importance is undeniable, placing them among the top three vegetables in terms of value, alongside head lettuce and onion, accounting for 32% of the total vegetable production value in 2019 (USDA-NASS 2020). Additionally, mulch plays a critical role in tomato production. To simplify analysis, we assume a one-acre tomato farm and normalize all inputs and outputs on a per-acre basis. While this study focuses on Washington State tomato growers, the particular numerical values might not be directly applicable to a specific grower, as well as other crops or regions, due to differences in crop prices, labor costs, and disposal costs. However, the modeling framework with sensitivity analyses, such as examining the impact of landfill tipping fees and the influence of crop price changes on optimal choices, offer valuable insights that can be generalized to a broader context.

In the baseline analysis, average tomato prices are $1.4/ lb, which is based on the northwestern US tomato retail price (USDA 2021).Footnote 14 The plastic waste disposal fee is assigned $0.042/lb, which is based on the surveyed landfill tipping fee in Washington in 2018 (Environmental Research and Education Foundation 2018).Footnote 15 A field survey was also conducted to characterize tomato growers’ plastic mulch choices in Washington by Mount Vernon Northwestern Washington Research and Extension Center’s Specialty Crop Research Initiative (SCRI) project team from 2010 to 2012 (Galinato et al Reference Galinato, Miles and Ponnaluru2012). All the baseline parameter values are presented in Table 1, and we assume the discount factor $\rho $ is equal to 0.9.Footnote 16 Piehl et al (Reference Piehl, Leibner, Löder, Dris, Bogner and Laforsch2018) reported about 0.1 pounds of plastic residue per acre in German agricultural land, whereas Gao et al (Reference Gao, Yan, Liu, Ding, Chen and Li2019) reported over 200 pounds of plastic residue per acre in China on lands that have had long-run exposure to plastic mulch use and its residue. Our baseline assumptions and initial conditions of plastic residue are more in line with Piehl et al (Reference Piehl, Leibner, Löder, Dris, Bogner and Laforsch2018), meaning we do not impose in the baseline that the farmland has a history of long-run buildup of plastic residue in the soil.

Table 1. Baseline coefficients of production, cost, disposal, and plastic residual evolution in a fresh-market tomato production system

1 The following values of parameters are obtained from “2011 Cost of Producing Fresh Market Field-Grown Tomatoes in Western Washington.”

${\alpha _0}$ representing the crop production under the PEMs is 30,360lb/acre.

${\beta _1}\;$ denoting the total amount of the used plastic mulch used during period t by grower i. The parameter value is obtained from Galinato et al (Reference Galinato, Miles and Ponnaluru2012).

${v_0}$ representing the production cost not associated with the plastic mulch used by grower i is equal to $25,982.92. The production cost has been adjusted based on the agricultural price paid indexes in the USDA NASS Quickstats database. Machinery cost in 2019 is 24% higher than in 2011; and all other production items (commodities, services, interest, tax, wage rates) in 2019 is 10.5% higher than in 2011.

2 Values are calibrated based on Galinato et al (Reference Galinato, Miles and Ponnaluru2012) and Jiang et al (Reference Jiang, Ma, Li and Zhang1998). The elasticity of soil plastic residue in affecting production is less than -0.028% when plastic pollutant levels are 3.2 lb. Following their work, we assume parameter values, ${\alpha _1},{\alpha _2},{\alpha _{11}},{\alpha _{22}}$ that result in an elasticity of less than 0.028%. While there is no study quantifying the relationship between mulch degradation rate and cost, we assume parameter values, ${v_1},$ and conduct sensitivity analysis to check the robustness of the results.

3 The remaining parameter values are assumed to satisfy the first-order conditions and the functional form assumptions in section “Private grower optimization.” Due to the lack of empirical studies providing values for these parameters, we conduct sensitivity analysis using different parameter values to check the robustness of the results. This paper presents sensitivity analysis for key parameters; a complete sensitivity analysis is available upon request.

Results and discussion

In this section, we derive economic insights from an illustrative empirical model of this economic system. The results are then examined through four lenses: optimal grower behavior under deterministic and stochastic environments, the impact of a corrective tax, the effectiveness of current BDM standards and the impact of growers’ risk preferences. It is crucial to acknowledge that the model’s findings presented below are contingent upon the underlying assumptions, data, and parameters employed. As such, they may not be universally applicable across all agricultural scenarios. Nonetheless, the derived outcomes, along with a selection of sensitivity analyses, offer valuable contributions to our understanding of economic behavior within this system and inform potential policy recommendations.

Optimal choice of a representative grower

We first discuss the optimal selection of a representative grower when offered a range of plastic mulches with varying degradation rates under deterministic environment, assuming the grower has perfect knowledge of these rates. Table 2 summarizes the findings for the baseline scenario and several sensitivity analyses (increased crop prices, production costs, and yield impact from plastic residue). The baseline results in Table 2 indicate that growers will choose PEMs and dispose of all waste at a landfill facility. This approach leads to a long-term equilibrium of 0.06 lb plastic residue remaining in farmland soil, while plastic waste accumulates continuously at the landfill. However, the outcomes in Table 2 from increasing crop prices, production costs, and the negative impact of plastic residue on yield do not influence the growers’ optimal choice from the baseline scenario. This aligns with our theoretical finding that altering parameters related to the production function or crop price does not directly influence growers’ optimal disposal method choices (Equation (8)). As growers currently dispose of used mulch waste in landfills, plastic pollutants do not accumulate and harm farmland soil quality. Consequently, growers lack the incentive to adopt more expensive BDMs, leading to ongoing plastic waste accumulation at landfills.

Table 2. Optimal steady-state disposal method, degradation rate and accumulated plastic pollutant in the farmland soilFootnote 17

1 Gao et al. (Reference Gao, Yan, Liu, Ding, Chen and Li2019) reported that when the residual plastic mulch is over 214lb per acre, then the crop yield would have a significant decrease. To incorporate the results from this study, in our comparative statistics analysis, we rescaled the coefficient ${\alpha _2}$ to -500 in order to have a production function that will have significant yield decreases at 214 lb of mulch residue.

Next, in Table 3, we examine the responses in the optimal choices and the accumulation of plastic waste to increases in landfill tipping fees.

Table 3. Analysis of the impact of landfill tipping fee

Rising landfill tipping fees in the U.S. (Environmental Research and Education Foundation 2018; Repa Reference Repa2005) incentivize grower adoption of BDMs. Projecting a 4.7% average annual growth rate from a baseline of $0.042/lb, Washington State’s tipping fee could reach $0.052/lb ($104.98/ton) in five years, $0.066/lb ($132.08/ton) in ten years, and $0.105/lb ($209.08/ton) in twenty years. As demonstrated in section “Biodegradation standards,” growers are more likely to till used mulch into farmland when disposal costs become sufficiently high. Our empirical model predicts a tipping point of $0.055/lb. Above this threshold, growers financially benefit from leaving used plastic mulches on-site or tilling them into the soil.

A comparative statics analysis (Table 3) reveals that if the tipping fee reaches $0.066/lb, $0.105/lb within ten years and twenty years respectively, growers transition from PEMs to BDMs with a 61% degradation rate (interior solution, condition 7), maximizing profit by favoring on-site decomposition (The alternative analysis based on dynamic path analysis is in Appendix B). Consequently, BDM waste in farmland soil reaches an equilibrium of 3.27 lb, and plastic waste contributions to landfills are eliminated. Furthermore, with a higher tipping fee ($0.105/lb in 20 years) and more severe crop damage (Gao et al. Reference Gao, Yan, Liu, Ding, Chen and Li2019), growers adopt BDMs with a 100% degradation rate (boundary solution, condition 7). This incentivizes BDM adoption by discouraging landfill disposal, preventing soil quality reduction, and minimizing plastic pollution. Similar to Bueno and Valente (Reference Bueno and Valente2019) and Fullerton and Kinnaman (Reference Fullerton and Kinnaman1996), who found monetary incentives effective in inducing behavioral changes in household waste generation, we observe analogous results for growers facing rising landfill tipping fees.

Increased crop prices also incentivize faster BDM adoption. As Table 3 shows, a 7% crop price rise leads growers to adopt BDMs with faster degradation rates, prioritizing long-term soil improvement (condition 7). This aligns with our theoretical analysis, indicating that higher crop prices encourage the use of faster-degrading mulch despite higher upfront costs.

Even though this study focuses on Washington State tomato growers, the modeling framework with sensitivity analyses provide insights that can be generalized to a broader context. For example, the finding that increasing landfill tipping fees can incentivize the adoption of BDMs is relevant for policymakers in other regions seeking to promote sustainable agricultural practices. Similarly, the analysis of how crop price fluctuations affect BDM adoption decisions can inform growers and policymakers across different crops and regions.

Optimal choice of a representative grower with BDMs meeting standards

Table 4 presents the empirical results of optimal grower choice when the market offers either PEMs or BDMs meeting a minimum 90% degradation standard. Our analysis, constrained by a minimum 90% biodegradability requirement (Equation (13)), shows that growers maximize profit by choosing either PEMs or BDMs that meet this standard (Figure 2, Panels a and b). This is because a strictly interior optimum degradation rate is not achievable. To determine the best overall choice (global optimum), we compare profits across these two options, as presented in Table 4. While factors like tomato price do not change these optimal choices, they do affect the profitability of each, influencing the global optimum. We further examine the impact of rising tomato prices on this choice, with results detailed in Table 4.

Table 4. Profit comparison between using PEMs and using BDMs meeting standards

1 It is an unstable steady state, and once it reaches 3.61 lb, a grower will stop farming, due to the reduction of production related to the mulch residual in farmland soil.

2 The higher profit that is achieved by one of two local optima, and the corresponding local optimum is the global optimum.

3 Low Disposal Fee used $0.04/lb

4 High Disposal Fee used $0.6/lb.

Although Table 4 (illustrated in Figure 2c, Section “Dynamic models,” points A and B) suggests minimal profit differences between PEMs and BDMs meeting the standard (less than 0.1%), it reveals important dynamics. Growers with low disposal costs tend to favor PEMs due to slightly higher profits. However, as disposal costs rise, on-site disposal becomes more appealing, making BDMs more competitive. For example, at a tomato price of $3/lb, growers using BDMs meeting the 90% degradation standard earn $117 more profit than those using PEMsFootnote 18 . This highlights the complex interplay between BDM certification, grower choices, and plastic accumulation.

Our analysis also shows that choosing BDMs with a 90% degradation rate caps total plastic mulch waste on farmland and in landfills at 3.06 lb/farm. In contrast, continued use of PEMs leads to either the continual buildup of plastic waste in landfills or the complete abandonment of farming due to the soil contamination (converging towards the transversality condition 11).

However, the economic incentive for adopting certified BDMs (with even higher degradation rates) is limited. Our analysis reveals that BDMs with a 90% degradation rate represent only a global profit maximum in 2 out of 6 scenarios. Therefore, certified BDMs with higher degradation rates, while environmentally preferable, may be less appealing to profit-driven growers. This finding aligns with research on other certification programs, such as organic certification and Fair-Trade coffee certification (Seufert et al., Reference Seufert, Ramankutty and Foley2012; Dragusanu et al., Reference Dragusanu, Giovannucci and Nunn2014), which also highlight the potential trade-offs between achieving standards and maximizing profit.

Corrective tax

Besides the increasing landfill tipping fee in the long term, a corrective tax is another approach to reduce plastic mulch waste in both farmland soil and landfills. The results for the numerical analysis of a corrective tax (Equation 17) are represented in Table 5. The corrective tax, derived from the shadow price of the plastic waste constraint (Equation 14), internalizes the social cost of plastic pollution, incentivizing growers to adopt BDMs and reduce landfill disposal. This encourages a shift towards the socially optimal outcome with lower plastic waste in both farmland and landfills. The tax level is influenced by crop prices, production cost and waste management cost, balancing environmental goals with each grower’s profit maximization goal.

Table 5. Optimal steady-state disposal method, under the corrective tax

We assume that the policy limiting plastic pollutants, $\;{{\bf{\it{D}}}_t}$ is 400 lbs. for a total of 130 one-acre-farm growers.Footnote 19 In contrast to the grower optimum in baseline presented in Table 2, Table 5 demonstrates that a corrective tax scheme targeting farm-discharged used mulch waste incentivizes growers to reduce total mulch waste pollution. This reduction is achieved through various means, including innovation in waste management practices. As Endres (Reference Endres2011) observed, firms may redesign production processes to mitigate pollution and avoid corrective taxes. Similarly, our findings indicate that growers, faced with a corrective tax, opt to retain mulch waste on the farm and transition from PEMs to BDMs with a 96% degradation rate. Within the model’s assumptions, this choice leads to a long-term steady state with 3.08 lbs/farm of plastic pollutants remaining in the farmland soil and no plastic waste deposited in landfills. This finding complements those in section “Optimal choice of a representative grower,” indicating that a corrective tax effectively encourages the adoption of BDMs that meet biodegradable standards.

Table 5 further illustrates that while decreased crop prices and increased production costs impose financial burdens on growers, the corrective tax increases in both scenarios. As shown in Table 5, the optimal tax is $1.39/lb per grower per growing season. However, this value requires adjustment to $8.03/lb and $11.05/lb, respectively, to account for a 50% decrease in tomato price or a 50% increase in the production cost coefficient associated with the degradation rate. This observation is consistent with studies demonstrating that firms facing financial distress are more likely to violate environmental regulations or forgo investments in cleaner technologies (Xu and Kim Reference Xu and Kim2022; Atkinson Reference Atkinson2023; Oestreich and Tsiakas Reference Oestreich and Tsiakas2024). Therefore, social planners may need to implement stricter environmental policies, such as higher taxes, to align grower behavior with socially optimal outcomes. Further research is needed to fully understand the interplay between corrective taxes and the financial challenges faced by growers.

Although we found that corrective taxes can incentivize BDMs adoption, potential unintended consequences such as farmer resistance (Carattini et al Reference Carattini, Carvalho and Fankhauser2018), logistical challenges in implementation (Cai et al Reference Cai, Bai and Davey2022) and the impact of limited factor mobility, corruption, and imperfect competition on the distribution effect of taxes (Fullerton and Muehlegger Reference Fullerton and Muehlegger2019) need to be considered. Exploring alternative policy instruments, such as subsidies for BDM adoption (Velandia et al Reference Velandia, Jensen, DeLong, Wszelaki and Rihn2020 c) or educational programs (Dentzman and Goldberger Reference Dentzman and Goldberger2020), could enhance the effectiveness of promoting sustainable agricultural practices and mitigating plastic pollution in future research.

Stochastic environment

We extend the analysis of plastic mulch degradation by incorporating uncertainty into the model (see Appendix C). Recognizing that factors like weather and climate can significantly impact the degradation of plastic pollutants in farmland soil, a stochastic element is introduced to the model. This allows for the examination of how variability in degradation rates, potentially influenced by factors like temperature, rainfall, and soil conditions, affects growers’ decisions regarding biodegradable mulch adoption.

The stochastic analysis reveals that while short-term weather fluctuations may not significantly impact the average degradation rate or long-term plastic accumulation, consistent slowdowns in degradation, potentially linked to climate change, incentivize growers to adopt faster-degrading biodegradable mulches. Farmers are more likely to embrace innovation when facing climate challenges (Rising and Devineni, Reference Rising and Devineni2020). Furthermore, Feder et al. (Reference Feder, Just and Zilberman1985) provide a comprehensive overview of the uncertainties influencing technology adoption in agriculture. Our work builds upon their findings by demonstrating that increased variability in plastic pollutant stock can negatively affect expected grower profits and amplify profit uncertainty. This underscores the importance of considering uncertainty in degradation processes when making decisions about plastic mulch management and highlights the potential economic benefits of adopting biodegradable options, particularly in the context of a changing climate.

Grower risk aversion analysis

Since the use of BDMs introduces profit uncertainty due to weather and climate variability, it is important to understand if a grower’s risk preference impacts the optimal choice of mulch adoption. Relaxing the assumption of a risk-neutral grower with a linear utility function of lifetime profit, we assume a constant absolute risk aversion exponential utility function (Pratt Reference Pratt1964; Phelps Reference Phelps2024) as shown in Equation 23, where r is the Arrow-Pratt coefficient of absolute risk aversion (Mas-Colell et al Reference Mas-Colell, Whinston and Green1995).

(23) $$U\left( {{\pi _i}} \right) = {{1 - {e^{ - r{\pi _i}}}} \over r}$$

Given the profit uncertainties associated with BDMs, the expected utility of using mulches is given by Equation 24. We assume that lifetime profit, ${\pi _i}$ , follows a normal distribution with mean ${\mu _\pi }$ and standard deviation ${\sigma _\pi }$ .

(24) $$EU\left( {{\pi _i}} \right) = {{1 - {e^{ - r{\mu _\pi } + {{{{\left( {r{\sigma _\pi }} \right)}^2}} \over 2}}}} \over r}$$

To understand how grower risk preference influences mulch adoption, we examine the difference in expected utility between using BDMs with profit uncertainty and using PEMs with profit certainty. We use the stochastic baseline scenario in Table C1 (Appendix) to illustrate our findings. Under the risk-neutral assumption, the landfill cost is high enough that growers choose BDMs, earning a profit of $136,740.37, which is $800 more than using PEMsFootnote 20 . However, the standard deviation of BDM profit is $25.30.

We consider three scenarios for the grower’s constant absolute risk aversion utility function: risk-neutral (r = 0.001), moderate risk aversion (r = 0.01), and high-risk aversion (r = 0.1). Figure 3 shows that as the grower becomes more risk-averse, the difference in expected utility between using BDMs and PEMs decreases. When the grower is risk-neutral (Point A in Figure 3) or moderately risk-averse (Point B in Figure 3), they gain more utility from using BDMs. However, when the grower is highly risk-averse (Point C in Figure 3), they do not gain more utility by switching from PEMs to BDMs.

Figure 3. Difference in expected utility between using BDMs and PEMs under different coefficients of absolute risk aversion.

Our findings reveal that while risk-neutral and moderately risk-averse growers are more likely to adopt BDMs due to the increased expected utility of profit, high-risk-averse growers tend to avert BDM adoption despite the financial benefits. This highlights the importance of considering grower risk preferences when designing policies and incentives aimed at promoting BDM adoption.

Furthermore, this analysis complements and extends our previous findings on the impact of economic incentives, such as landfill fees and corrective taxes, on BDM adoption. While economic incentives can play a significant role in encouraging BDM adoption, the effectiveness of these incentives may be constrained by grower risk aversion. Therefore, a comprehensive approach that considers both economic and behavioral factors is crucial for promoting the widespread adoption of BDMs.

Conclusions and possible extensions

This research contributes to the existing literature by developing a dynamic economic model to analyze the complex problem facing farmers and policymakers’ trade-off between the environmental benefit of BDMs and their performance in agricultural production. The numerical solutions of the illustrative case study, generated under both deterministic and stochastic scenarios, offer valuable insights into the impact of economic incentives and policy interventions on plastic mulch choices and pollution levels.

The theoretical analysis reveals that growers prioritize long-term soil improvement and higher yields when crop prices are high, opting for faster-degrading mulches even with higher upfront costs. Similarly, higher disposal costs incentivize the adoption of faster-degrading mulches to minimize disposal volume and associated costs. Essentially, growers weigh the benefits of faster degradation (reduced disposal costs and improved soil health) against the potentially higher upfront cost of BDMs. This finding aligns with existing research on farmers’ interest in maintaining or increasing soil quality, where crop prices positively influence investments in soil conservation (Issanchou et al. Reference Issanchou, Daniel, Dupraz and Ropars-Collet2019).

Empirical analysis of tomato production in Washington State supports these theoretical findings. While growers currently favor conventional plastic mulches (PEMs) and landfill disposal due to lower costs, increasing landfill tipping fees and crop prices could drive the adoption of BDMs. However, the study also reveals that current biodegradation standards might not incentivize the use of BDMs with the fastest degradation rates due to limited economic benefits. This challenge is not unique to BDMs, as other certification programs, such as organic and Fair-Trade coffee certifications, face similar issues (Seufert et al. Reference Seufert, Ramankutty and Foley2012; Dragusanu et al. Reference Dragusanu, Giovannucci and Nunn2014).

A corrective tax on plastic waste is identified as a potential policy tool to encourage environmentally optimal behavior by promoting BDM adoption and reducing landfill disposal. However, when growers face financial distress, i.e., crop price decreases or production cost associate with mulch degradation rate increases, higher corrective taxes may be necessary to align their behavior with socially optimal outcomes. To prevent non-compliance by private decision makers during financial distress (Xu and Kim Reference Xu and Kim2022; Atkinson Reference Atkinson2023; Oestreich and Tsiakas Reference Oestreich and Tsiakas2024), a higher corrective tax may be necessary.

Finally, the study highlights the importance of considering uncertainty in degradation processes, particularly in the context of a changing climate, which can influence grower decision-making and the long-term accumulation of plastic pollutants in the environment. Furthermore, the analysis of grower risk aversion reveals that high-risk aversion can hinder BDM adoption, suggesting the need for policies that address both economic and behavioral factors.

Our findings have significant practical implications for both growers and policymakers. First, the model provides a framework for growers to evaluate the economic and environmental trade-offs of different plastic mulch choices, helping them make informed decisions that balance profitability and sustainability. Second, the study highlights the potential of economic incentives, such as landfill tipping fees and corrective taxes, to drive the adoption of BDMs and reduce plastic pollution. This information can be used by policymakers to design effective policies that promote sustainable agricultural practices.

Future research could explore several areas to further enhance our understanding of BDM adoption and plastic pollution control. First, it would be valuable to investigate farmer adoption behavior under real-world conditions, considering factors such as, information access, behavioral economics (e.g., nudging), and social norms. Second, field trials could be conducted to validate the model’s assumptions and assess the long-term impact of BDMs on soil health and crop yields. Finally, the model could be extended to analyze the potential of other policy instruments (Baumol et al 1988), such as subsidies (Velandia et al Reference Velandia, Jensen, DeLong, Wszelaki and Rihn2020 c) or extended producer responsibility schemes, to promote BDM adoption and reduce plastic pollution.

While our model is designed for the agricultural sector, its framework can be extended to analyze single-use plastic problems in the retail sector. However, this extension requires several key assumptions. First, consumers must derive utility from consuming disposable plastic products (Jiang Reference Jiang2016). Second, their utility must decrease as plastic pollution increases. Applying the model to the retail sector requires a more detailed understanding of consumer decision-making. Nevertheless, the framework presented here serves as a strong foundation for future research. Additionally, our current work focuses on a production function approach, examining the impact of plastic residue on soil yield and revenue. A future avenue of research could explore a dual cost function approach, particularly relevant when the cost of removing plastic residue becomes infinitely high as levels increase (or conversely, as plastic residue approaches zero).

Supplementary material

The supplementary material for this article can be found at https://doi.org/10.1017/age.2025.20

Data availability statement

The authors confirm that the data supporting the findings of this study are available within the article. The simulation code that support the findings of this study are available from https://github.com/YoYo-JDCE/BDMs-Jiang-Marsh-Belasco.git .

Funding statement

The authors acknowledge USDA-Specialty Crop Research Initiative (SCRI) grant project Biodegradable Mulches for Specialty Crops Produced Under Protective Covers (Ref. No: 2009-02484); USDA-SCRI grant project Performance and Adoptability of Biodegradable Plastic Mulch for Sustainable Specialty Crop Production (Ref. No. 2014-51181-22382); and USDA-SCRI Award 2022-51181-38325 from the USDA National Institute of Food and Agriculture. Any opinions, findings, conclusions, or recommendations expressed in this publication are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the view of the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Competing interests

The authors declare none.

Footnotes

1 Mulch is a layer of material for plant protection and weed control. It also enhances crop growth by optimizing soil temperature and moisture. It is spread on the top of the soil (USDA 2012).

2 Pollutants for which the environment has little or no absorptive capacity and that accumulate over time are called stock pollutants, including nonbiodegradable bottles tossed by the roadside (Tietenberg Reference Tietenberg2004).

3 It has been correctly pointed out that plastic pollution could arise from a range of large fragments to microplastics to Nano-plastics. We articulate the problem in terms of microplastic pollution for the current paper, choosing to focus on the rate of degradation from conventional plastics to biodegradable plastics. Nevertheless, we point out that the fundamental dynamic economic framework introduced in this paper to model stock pollutants remains appropriate across a range of plastic fragments.

4 Herein the term plastic mulch refers to both PEMs and BDMs with the degradation rate being the differentiating characteristic. Mathematically, and to be more formal, it is possible to bound the degradation rate away from zero. Here, we could choose some lower bound of the degradation rate, d0, that is very small and close to zero such the degradation rate is contained in a closed interval bound [d0,1] away from zero on the lower end and by 1 on the upper end, and then continue on with the optimization. Here, d0, would represent PEMs and (d0,1] represent BDMs.

5 It has been pointed out that degradation and deterioration of plastic are not identical processes. We acknowledge this, but to retain the focus of the paper, recommend it as future research.

6 Historically, across the world, farmers have tended to plow the plastic mulch back into the soil (Gao et al Reference Gao, Yan, Liu, Ding, Chen and Li2019), dispose of the used mulches in landfills, stockpile the plastic on site, bury it on side, or burn it (Sarpong et al Reference Sarpong, Adesina, DeVetter, Zhang, DeWhitt, Englund and Miles2024). Open burning it is illegal in many states, including Washington the location of the case study for this paper. Like landfills, stockpiling or burying it on site can lead to plastic residuals in the soil with long-term environmental consequences (Sarpong et al Reference Sarpong, Adesina, DeVetter, Zhang, DeWhitt, Englund and Miles2024).

7 The production function is initially specified in terms of the above-soil degradation rate, as that drives the productivity increases from plastic mulches. To facilitate the analysis and reduce dimensions of the model, we express the above-soil degradation rate in terms of the in-soil degradation rate. This leads to a more parsimonious model, while retaining the main focus of the analysis. Henceforth, the degradation rate will refer to the in-soil degradation rate unless otherwise noted. Throughout the paper, subscripts denote partial derivatives, for example, ${Q_\delta } = \partial Q\left( {{\theta ^{ - 1}}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right);{S_{i,t}}} \right)/\partial \delta \;$ , $\;{Q_S} = \partial Q\left( {{\theta ^{ - 1}}\left( {{\delta _{it}}} \right);{S_{i,t}}} \right)/\partial S$

8 w ($/lb) is equal to the used mulch disposal fee ($/lb) plus labor cost of removing used mulch ($/lb).

9 For Box D, if a social planner aims to limit plastic waste pollution from growers, they may implement taxation. Growers, in turn, account for taxes when making profit-maximizing decisions. Section “Social planner optimization” details the social planner’s problem.

10 This simplification reduces the complexity of the solution, while retaining the main features of the model that are the focus of the study. A study of fruit and vegetable growers in Tennessee, reported that 75% of the used plastic mulch went to landfills, and only 15% of the farmers used more than one disposal method (Sarpong et al Reference Sarpong, Adesina, DeVetter, Zhang, DeWhitt, Englund and Miles2024).

11 We assume that an interior solution never occurs, since we assume growers will either send all plastic waste to the disposal facility or leave all plastic waste on the farmland, which indicates corner solutions. This allows us to compare and contrast the landfill disposal scenario to the tilling in scenario across all levels of BDM degradation rates. Note that uncertainty exists in that some products labeled biodegradable do not fully degrade relative to industry standards (Brodhagen et al Reference Brodhagen, Goldberger, Hayes, Inglis, Marsh and Miles2017).

12 ${h_\delta } \lt 0$ , so when $\bar w$ increases, $({C_\delta } + w{h_\delta })/\bar P$ decreases.

13 We also performed a simulation based on strawberry production. It is available upon request.

14 In the state of Washington, tomatoes are predominately sold at farmer’s market. Hence, the prices received are retail prices.

15 $83.44/ton is equal to $0.042/lb

16 let dis denote discount rate, the discount factor is calculated through $\rho $ = 1/(1+ $dis$ .) We assume dis = 0.07, and the discount factor is approximately equal 0.9. For the past 20 years, the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) has advised federal agencies to use dis = 0.07 in policy analyses. 7 percent rate captures the return paid by private capital, reflecting effects on investment and business.

17 While our analysis applied a Monte Carlo simulation with up to 1,000 periods to identify the steady state, it converges to the steady state rapidly (see appendix for more details). Nevertheless, these results are conditional on the parameters and information applied in the current illustrative analysis, and should be updated with additional and new information in future research.

18 The $117 profit difference between BDMs and PEMs may appear small, but it is significant in the context of low initial plastic residue levels. To further explore this, we increase the initial plastic residue parameter, ${\eta _0}$ , from 3.2 lb to 40.2 lb, simulating a scenario with a history of medium-severity long-run buildup of plastic residue. With a crop price of $3/lb and a high landfill tipping fee, the profit incentive to adopt BDMs becomes substantial, with growers earning $3,135 more profit using BDMs instead of PEMs. This highlights the impact of pre-existing plastic pollution on the economic viability of BDMs.

19 We also tried different restrictions and total number of growers, and we got the similar outcome. The limitation of 400 lb. for 130 growers is equal to 3.08 lb per grower.

20 The profit from using PEMs is $135,940, while the landfill tipping fee is $0.105 per pound.

References

Anderson, G.D., Opaluch, J.J., and Sullivan, W.M.. 1985. Nonpoint Agricultural Pollution: Pesticide Contamination of Groundwater Supplies. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 67(5): 12381243. https://doi.org/10.2307/1241408 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andrady, A.L. 2011. Microplastics in the Marine Environment. Marine Pollution Bulletin 62(8): 15961605. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpolbul.2011.05.030 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Atkinson, N. 2023. Profiting from Pollution. Yale Journal on Regulation, Bulletin 41. https://www.yalejreg.com/bulletin/profiting-from-pollution/ (accessed 10 August 2024).Google Scholar
Avérous, L., and Halley, P. J.. 2014. Starch Polymers: From the Field to Industrial Products. In Starch polymers (pp. 310). Elsevier. https://doi.org/10.1016/B978-0-444-53730-0.00018-X CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baldwin, A.K., Corsi, S.R., and Mason, S.A.. 2016. Plastic Debris in 29 Great Lakes Tributaries: Relations to Watershed Attributes and Hydrology. Environmental Science and Technology 50(19): 1037710385. https://doi.org/10.1021/acs.est.6b02917 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Baumol, W.J., and Oates, W.E.. 1971. The Use of Standards and Prices for Protection of the Environment. In Bohm, P. & Kneese, A. V. (Eds.), The Economics of Environment. Palgrave Macmillan. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-01379-1_4 Google Scholar
Baumol, W.J., and Oates, W.E.. 1988. The Theory of Environmental Policy (2nd ed.). Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bellomo, N., Lods, B., Revelli, R., and Ridolfi, L.. 2007. Generalized Collocation Methods: Solutions to Nonlinear Problems. Springer Science and Business Media.Google Scholar
Bishop, R.C. 1993. Economic Efficiency, Sustainabiliy and Biodiversity. Ambio 22: 23.Google Scholar
Bloomberg. 2017, September 5). Plastic Film Covering 12% of China’s Farmland Pollutes Soil. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2017-09-05/plastic-film-covering-12-of-china-s-farmland-contaminates-soil (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Braden, J.B., Johnson, G.V., Bouzaher, A., and Miltz, D.. 1989. Optimal Spatial Management of Agricultural Pollution. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71(2): 404413. https://doi.org/10.2307/1241598 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brodhagen, M., Goldberger, J.R., Hayes, D.G., Inglis, D.A., Marsh, T.L., and Miles, C.. 2017. Policy Considerations for Limiting Unintended Residual Plastic in Agricultural Soils. Environmental Science and Policy 69: 8184. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envsci.2016.12.014 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bueno, M., and Valente, M.. 2019. The Effects of Pricing Waste Generation: A Synthetic Control Approach. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 96: 274285. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2019.06.004 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cai, W., Bai, M., and Davey, H.. 2022. Implementing Environmental Protection Tax in China: An Alternative Framework. Pacific Accounting Review 34(3): 479513. https://doi.org/10.1108/PAR-02-2021-0021 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, A., and Dudek, T.A.. 2009. Problems with Plastics. http://recycle.meridian.mi.us/facts/Problems_with_Plastics.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Cao, Z. 2011. Gansu “White Revolution”--the Worry of Mulch Remnant Disposal. Gansu Daily. http://gansu.gansudaily.com.cn/system/2011/11/02/012249320_02.shtml (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Carattini, S., Carvalho, M., and Fankhauser, S.. 2018. Overcoming Public Resistance to Carbon Taxes. WIREs Climate Change 9(5): e531. https://doi.org/10.1002/wcc.531 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chen, K.-J., Galinato, S.P., Marsh, T.L., Tozer, P.R., and Chouinard, H.H.. 2020. Willingness to Pay for Attributes of Biodegradable Plastic Mulches in the Agricultural Sector. HortTechnology 1(aop): 111. https://doi.org/10.21273/HORTTECH04518-20 Google Scholar
Chen, K.-J., Marsh, T. L., Tozer, P. R., and Galinato, S. P.. 2019. Biotechnology to Sustainability: Consumer Preferences for Food Products Grown on Biodegradable Mulches. Food Research International 116: 200210. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.foodres.2018.08.013 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Conrad, J.M., and Clark, C.W.. 1987. Natural Resource Economics: Notes and Problems. Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Conrad, J.M., and Olson, L.J.. 1992. The Economics of a Stock Pollutant: Aldicarb on Long Island. Environmental and Resource Economics 2(3): 245258. https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00376199 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coskun, D., Britto, D.T., Shi, W., and Kronzucker, H.J.. 2017. Nitrogen Transformations in Modern Agriculture and the Role of Biological Nitrification Inhibition. Nature Plants 3(6): 17074. https://doi.org/10.1038/nplants.2017.74 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dentzman, K., and Goldberger, J.R.. 2020. Plastic Scraps: Biodegradable Mulch Films and The Aesthetics of ‘Good Farming’in US Specialty Crop Production. Agriculture and Human Values 37(1): 8396. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10460-019-09970-x CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Derraik, J.G.B. 2002. The Pollution of The Marine Environment by Plastic Debris: A Review. Marine Pollution Bulletin 44(9): 842––52. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0025-326X(02)00220-5 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Dragusanu, R., Giovannucci, D., and Nunn, N.. 2014. The Economics of Fair Trade. Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(3): 217236. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.28.3.217 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dreyer, K., Fourie, L.J., and Kok, D.J.. 1999. Assessment of Cattle Owner’s Perceptions and Expectations, and Identification of Constraints on Production in a Peri-urban, Resource-poor Environment. Onderstepoort Journal of Veterinary Research 66(2): 8. http://hdl.handle.net/2263/19937 Google Scholar
Ellis, S., Kantner, S., Saab, A., and Watson, M.. 2005. Plastic Grocery Bags: The Ecological Footprint. http://www.vipirg.ca/archive/publications/pubs/student_papers/05_ecofootprint_plastic_bags.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Endres, A. 2011. Environmental Economics: Theory and Policy. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Environmental Research and Education Foundation. 2018. Analysis of MSW Landfill Tipping Fees— April 2018. www.erefdn.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/12/MSWLF-Tipping-Fees-2018-Rev.ed_.2019.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Eriksen, M., Mason, S., Wilson, S., Box, C., Zellers, A., Edwards, W., Farley, H., and Amato, S.. 2013. Microplastic Pollution in The Surface Waters of The Laurentian Great Lakes. Marine Pollution Bulletin 77(1-2): 177182. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpolbul.2013.10.007 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Feder, G., Just, R.E., and Zilberman, D.. 1985. Adoption of Agricultural Innovations in Developing Countries: A Survey. Economic Development and Cultural Change 33(2): 255298. http://www.jstor.org/stable/1153228 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Federal Trade Commission. 2012. Federal Register Volume 77, Issue 197 (October 11, 2012): Guides for the Use of Environmental Marketing Claims. Office of the Federal Register, National Archives and Records Administration. https://www.govinfo.gov/app/details/FR-2012-10-11/2012-24713 (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Federal Trade Commission. 2014. Code of Federal Regulations: Degradable claims (NO:AE 2.106/3:16/). https://www.govinfo.gov/app/details/CFR-2014-title16-vol1/CFR-2014-title16-vol1-sec260-8 (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Free, C.M., Jensen, O.P., Mason, S.A., Eriksen, M., Williamson, N.J., and Boldgiv, B.. 2014. High-levels of Microplastic Pollution in A Large, Remote, Mountain Lake. Marine Pollution Bulletin 85(1): 156163. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.marpolbul.2014.06.001 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fullerton, D., and Kinnaman, T.C.. 1996. Household Responses to Pricing Garbage by the Bag. The American Economic Review 86(4): 971984. https://www.jstor.org/stable/2118314 Google Scholar
Fullerton, D., and Muehlegger, E.. 2019. Who Bears the Economic Burdens of Environmental Regulations? Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 13(1): 6282. https://doi.org/10.1093/reep/rey023 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galinato, S.P., Miles, C.A., and Ponnaluru, S.S.. 2012. 2011 Cost of Producing Fresh Market Field-Grown Tomatoes in Western Washington. https://wpcdn.web.wsu.edu/extension/uploads/sites/25/FS080E.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Gao, H., Yan, C., Liu, Q., Ding, W., Chen, B., and Li, Z.. 2019. Effects of Plastic Mulching and Plastic Residue on Agricultural Production: A Meta-Analysis. Science of the Total Environment 651: 484-–492. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2018.09.105 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gautam, S.P. 2009. Bio-degradable Plastics-Impact on Environment. http://www.cpcb.nic.in/upload/NewItems/NewItem_150_PlasticsWaste.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Germain, M., Toint, P., Tulkens, H., and Zeeuw, A.. 2006. Transfers to Sustain Dynamic Core-Theoretic Cooperation in International Stock Pollutant Control. In Chander, P., Drèze, J., Lovell, C. K., and Mintz, J. (Eds.), Public Goods, Environmental Externalities and Fiscal Competition (pp. 251274). Springer US. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1889(02)00107-0 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ghimire, S., Wszelaki, A.L., Moore, J.C., Inglis, D.A., and Miles, C.. 2018. The Use of Biodegradable Mulches in Pie Pumpkin Crop Production in Two Diverse Climates. HortScience 53(3): 288294. https://doi.org/10.21273/HORTSCI12630-17 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goldberger, J.R., DeVetter, L.W., and Dentzman, K.E.. 2019. Polyethylene and Biodegradable Plastic Mulches for Strawberry Production in the United States: Experiences and opinions of growers in three regions. HortTechnology 29(5): 619628. https://doi.org/10.21273/HORTTECH04393-19 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golub, G.H., and Ortega, J.M.. 1992. Scientific Computing and Differential Equations: An Introduction to Numerical Methods. Academic press.Google Scholar
Griffin, R.C., and Bromley, D.W.. 1982. Agricultural Runoff as a Nonpoint Externality: A Theoretical Development. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 64(3): 547552. https://doi.org/10.2307/1240648 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griffin-LaHue, D., Ghimire, S, Yu, Y., Scheenstra, E.J, Miles, C.A., and Flury, M.. 2022. In-field Degradation of Soil-Biodegradable Plastic Mulch Films in A Mediterranean Climate. Science of the Total Environment 806: 150238. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2021.150238 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holland, S.P. 2012. Emissions Taxes Versus Intensity Standards: Second-Best Environmental Policies with Incomplete Regulation. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 63(3): 375387. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeem.2011.12.002 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Horton, A.A., Walton, A., Spurgeon, D.J., Lahive, E., and Svendsen, C.. 2017. Microplastics in Freshwater and Terrestrial Environments: Evaluating the Current Understanding to Identify the Knowledge Gaps and Future Research Priorities. Science of the Total Environment 586: 127141. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2017.01.190.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Ingman, M., Santelmann, M.V., and Tilt, B.. 2015. Agricultural Water Conservation in China: Plastic Mulch and Traditional Irrigation. Ecosystem Health and Sustainability 1(4): 111. https://doi.org/10.1890/EHS14-0018.1 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Innes, R. 2000. The Economics of Livestock Waste and Its Regulation. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 82(1): 97117. https://doi.org/10.1111/0002-9092.00009 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Issanchou, A., Daniel, K., Dupraz, P., and Ropars-Collet, C.(2019. Intertemporal Soil Management: Revisiting the Shape of the Crop Production Function. Journal of Environmental Planning and Management 62(11): 18451863. https://doi.org/10.1080/09640568.2018.1515730 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobs, J.J., and Timmons, J.F.. 1974. An economic analysis of agricultural land use practices to control water quality. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 56(4): 791798. https://doi.org/10.2307/1239309 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiang, J. 2016. Peer pressure in voluntary environmental programs: a case of the bag rewards program. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 16: 155190. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-015-0208-6 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jiang, L., Ma, Y., Li, B., and Zhang, L.. 1998. Effect of Plastic Mulches Residue on Tomatoes Growth and Yield. Fujian Agricultural Sciences and Technology, 5, 12-15.Google Scholar
Jørgensen, S., and Zaccour, G.. 2001. Incentive Equilibrium Strategies and Welfare Allocation in A Dynamic Game of Pollution Control. Automatica 37(1): 2936. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0005-1098(00)00119-9 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joyner, C.C., and Frew, S.. 1991. Plastic Pollution in the Marine Environment. Ocean Development and International Law 22(1): 3369. https://doi.org/10.1080/00908329109545949 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkham, M., Antony, R. M., and Bolan, N. S.. 2020. Particulate Plastics from Agriculture. In Particulate Plastics in Terrestrial and Aquatic Environments (pp. 1937). CRC Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kolstad, C.D. 2011. Environmental Economics (2nd ed.). Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lgbokwe, I.O., Kolo, M.Y., and Egwu, G.O.. 2003. Rumen Impaction in Sheep with Indigestible Foreign Bodies in the Semi-Arid Region of Nigeria. Small Ruminant Research 49(2): 141146. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0921-4488(03)00074-9 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, C., Moore-Kucera, J., Miles, C., Leonas, K., Lee, J., Corbin, A., and Inglis, D.. 2014. Degradation of Potentially Biodegradable Plastic Mulch Films at Three Diverse US locations. Agroecology and Sustainable Food Systems 38(8): 861889. https://doi.org/10.1080/21683565.2014.884515 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madrid, B., Wortman, S., Hayes, D. G., DeBruyn, J. M., Miles, C., Flury, M., Marsh, T., Galinato, S., Englund, K., Agehara, S., and DeVetter, L.W.. 2022a. End-of-life Management Options for Agricultural Mulch Films in the United States—A Review. Frontiers in Sustainable Food Systems 6: 921496. https://doi.org/10.3389/fsufs.2022.921496 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Madrid, B., Goldberger, J.R., Miles, C.A., and DeVetter, L.W.. 2022b. Risk and uncertainty of plastic mulch adoption in raspberry production systems. Renewable Agriculture and Food Systems, 1–12. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1742170522000291 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marí, A.I., Pardo, G., Cirujeda, A., and Martínez, Y.. 2019. Economic Evaluation of Biodegradable Plastic Films and Paper Mulches Used in Open-Air Grown Pepper (Capsicum annum L.) crop. Agronomy 9(1): 36. https://doi.org/10.3390/agronomy9010036 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martínez, Y., and Albiac, J.. 2004. Agricultural Pollution Control under Spanish and European Environmental Policies. Water Resources Research 40(10): W10501. https://doi.org/10.1029/2004WR003102 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M.D., and Green, J. R.. 1995. Microeconomic theory (Vol. 1). New York: Oxford university press.Google Scholar
Mason, S.A., Garneau, D., Sutton, R., Chu, Y., Ehmann, K., Barnes, J., Fink, P., Papazissimos, D., and Rogers, D.L. 2016. Microplastic Pollution Is Widely Detected in US Municipal Wastewater Treatment Plant Effluent. Environmental Pollution 218: 10451054. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.envpol.2016.08.056 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Miles, C., Wallace, R., Wszelaki, A., Martin, J., Cowan, J., Walters, T., and Inglis, D.. 2012. Deterioration of Potentially Biodegradable Alternatives to Black Plastic Mulch in Three Tomato Production Regions. HortScience 47(9): 12701277. https://doi.org/10.21273/HORTSCI.47.9.1270 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miles, C., and Ghimire, S.. 2020. Soil-Biodegradable Mulches: Workshop. https://s3.wp.wsu.edu/uploads/sites/2181/2021/10/1.-What-is-BDM.pdf (accessed 13 January 2022)Google Scholar
Miranda, M.J., and Fackler, P.L.. 2004. Applied Computational Economics and Finance. MIT press.Google Scholar
Moffitt, L.J., Zilberman, D., and Just, R.E.. 1978. A “Putty-Clay” Approach to Aggregation of Production/Pollution Possibilities: An Application in Dairy Waste Control. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 60(3): 452459.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mohanty, A., Misra, M.a., and Hinrichsen, G.. 2000. Biofibres, Biodegradable Polymers and Biocomposites: An Overview. Macromolecular materials and Engineering 276(1): 124. https://doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1439-2054(20000301)276:1<1::AID-MAME1>3.0.CO;2-W.3.0.CO;2-W>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nizzetto, L., Futter, M., and Langaas, S.. 2016. Are Agricultural Soils Dumps for Microplastics of Urban Origin? Environmental Science and Technology 50(20): 1077710779. https://doi.org/10.1021/acs.est.6b04140 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Oestreich, A.M., and Tsiakas, I.. 2024. Carbon Emissions and Firm Profitability. Journal of Sustainable Finance & Investment 14(4): 766786. https://doi.org/10.1080/20430795.2024.2386476 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Omidi, A., Naeemipoor, H., and Hosseini, M.. 2012. Plastic Debris in the Digestive Tract of Sheep and Goats: An Increasing Environmental Contamination in Birjand, Iran. Bulletin of Environmental Contamination and Toxicology 88(5): 691694. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00128-012-0587-x CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Phelps, C.E. 2024. A User’s Guide to Economic Utility Functions. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 69(3): 235280. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11166-024-09443-5 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piehl, S., Leibner, A., Löder, M.G., Dris, R., Bogner, C., and Laforsch, C.. 2018. Identification and Quantification of Macro-And Microplastics on An Agricultural Farmland. Scientific Reports 8(1): 19. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-018-36172-y CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pigou, A.C. 1932. The Economics of Welfare. Fourth edition. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Pratt, J.W. 1964. Risk Aversion in the Small and in the Large. Econometrica 32(1/2): 122136. https://doi.org/10.2307/1913738 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Repa, E.W. 2005. NSWMA’s 2005 Tip Fee Survey. NSWMA Research Bulletin 5(3). https://freewaterindependence.com/tipping_fee_bulletin_2005.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Rillig, M.C. 2012. Microplastic in Terrestrial Ecosystems and The Soil? Environmental Science and Technology 46(12): 64536454. https://doi.org/10.1021/es302011r CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rising, J., and Devineni, N.. 2020. Crop switching reduces agricultural losses from climate change in the United States by half under RCP 8.5. Nature Communications 11: 4991. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41467-020-18725-w CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rochman, C.M. 2018. Microplastics Research—from Sink to Source. Science 360(6384): 2829. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aar7734 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Russo, G., Candura, A., and Scarascia-Mugnozza, G.. 2004. Soil Solarization with Biodegradable Plastic Film: Two Years of Experimental Tests. Paper presented at the International Conference on Sustainable Greenhouse Systems-Greensys 2004, 691, 717-724. https://doi.org/10.17660/ActaHortic.2005.691.88 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sarpong, K.A., Adesina, F.A., DeVetter, L.W., Zhang, K., DeWhitt, K., Englund, K. R., and Miles, C.. 2024. Recycling agricultural plastic mulch: limitations and opportunities in the United States. Circular Agricultural Systems 4: e005. https://doi.org/10.48130/cas-0024-0003 Google Scholar
Schnitkey, G.D., and Miranda, M.J.. 1993. The Impact of Pollution Controls on Livestock-Crop Producers. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 18: 2536. https://www.jstor.org/stable/40986773 Google Scholar
Seufert, V., Ramankutty, N., and Foley, J.. 2012. Comparing the yields of organic and conventional agriculture. Nature 485: 229232. https://doi.org/10.1038/nature11069 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Shone, R. 2003. Economic Dynamics: Phase Diagrams and their Economic Application (2 ed.). Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sintim, H.Y., Bandopadhyay, S., English, M.E., Bary, A.I., DeBruyn, J.M., Schaeffer, S.M., Flury, M.. 2019. Impacts of Biodegradable Plastic Mulches on Soil Health. Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment 273: 3649. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.agee.2018.12.002 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sintim, H. Y., and Flury, M.. 2017. Is Biodegradable Plastic Mulch the Solution to Agriculture’s Plastic Problem? Environmental Science and Technology 51(3): 10681069. https://doi.org/10.1021/acs.est.6b06042 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Steinmetz, Z., Wollmann, C., Schaefer, M., Buchmann, C., David, J., Tröger, J., , K., Frör, O., and Schaumann, G.E.. 2016. Plastic Mulching in Agriculture. Trading Short-Term Agronomic Benefits for Long-Term Soil Degradation? Science of the Total Environment 550: 690705. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scitotenv.2016.01.153 CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tietenberg, T. 2004. Environmental Economics and Policy. Fourth Edition. Pearson Addison Wesley.Google Scholar
Tofanelli, M.B., and Wortman, S.E.. 2020. Benchmarking the Agronomic Performance of Biodegradable Mulches Against Polyethylene Mulch Film: A Meta-Analysis. Agronomy 10(10): 1618. https://doi.org/10.3390/agronomy10101618 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
United State Environmental Protection Agency. 2000. National Water Quality Inventory. https://www.epa.gov/sites/production/files/2015-09/documents/2000_national_water_quality_inventory_report_to_congress.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
USDA-National Agricultural Statistics Service. 2020. Vegetables 2019 Summary [Press release]. https://downloads.usda.library.cornell.edu/usda-esmis/files/02870v86p/0r967m63g/sn00bf58x/vegean20.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
USDA. 2012. Mulching. USDA Natural Resources Conservation Services. https://www.nrcs.usda.gov/Internet/FSE_DOCUMENTS/nrcs142p2_036981.pdf Google Scholar
USDA. 2021. National Retail Report - Specialty Crops. USDA Agricultural Marketing Service. https://www.ams.usda.gov/mnreports/fvwretail.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)Google Scholar
Velandia, M., Galinato, S., and Wszelaki, A.. 2020a. Economic Evaluation of Biodegradable Plastic Films in Tennessee Pumpkin Production. Agronomy 10(1): 51. https://doi.org/10.3390/agronomy10010051 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Velandia, M., DeLong, K.L., Wszelaki, A.L., Schexnayder, S.M., Clark, C.D., and Jensen, K.L.. 2020b. Use of Polyethylene and Plastic Biodegradable Mulches among Tennessee Fruit and Vegetable Growers. HortTechnology 30(2): 212218. https://doi.org/10.21273/HORTTECH04559-19 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Velandia, M., Jensen, K., DeLong, K.L., Wszelaki, A., and Rihn, A.. 2020c. Tennessee Fruit and Vegetable Farmer Preferences and Willingness to Pay for Plastic Biodegradable Mulch. Journal of Food Distribution Research 51(856-2021-261): 6387. https://doi.org/10.22004/ag.econ.309030 Google Scholar
Velandia, M., Smith, A., Wszelaki, A., Galinato, S., and Marsh, T.. 2018. The Economics of Adopting Biodegradable Plastic Mulch Films. chrome-extension://efaidnbmnnnibpcajpcglclefindmkaj/https://biodegradablemulch.tennessee.edu/wp-content/uploads/sites/214/2020/12/Velandia-et-al-The-Economics-of-Adopting-Biodegradable-Mulch.pdf (accessed 10 August 2021)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wang, T., Ma, Y., and Ji, R.. 2020. Aging Processes of Polyethylene Mulch Films and Preparation of Microplastics with Environmental Characteristics. Bulletin of Environmental Contamination and Toxicology 107, 736740. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00128-020-02975-x CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Xu, Q., and Kim, T.. 2022. Financial Constraints and Corporate Environmental Policies. The Review of Financial Studies 35(2): 576635. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhab056 CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yan, C., Mei, X., He, W., and Zheng, S.. 2006. Present Situation of Residue Pollution of Mulching Plastic Film and Controlling Measures. Transactions of the Chinese Society of Agricultural Engineering 22(11): 269272 Google Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Grower decision-making flow chart9.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Lifetime profits comparison between using PEMs and using BDMs meeting standards.a). PEMs is optimum b). BDMs meeting standards is optimum c). Both PEMs and BDMs meeting standards are optimum. Note: both point A and B achieve a local optimum. To obtain the global optimum, we need to compare the profit at point A and B, and the one having higher profit will be the global optimum.

Figure 2

Table 1. Baseline coefficients of production, cost, disposal, and plastic residual evolution in a fresh-market tomato production system

Figure 3

Table 2. Optimal steady-state disposal method, degradation rate and accumulated plastic pollutant in the farmland soil17

Figure 4

Table 3. Analysis of the impact of landfill tipping fee

Figure 5

Table 4. Profit comparison between using PEMs and using BDMs meeting standards

Figure 6

Table 5. Optimal steady-state disposal method, under the corrective tax

Figure 7

Figure 3. Difference in expected utility between using BDMs and PEMs under different coefficients of absolute risk aversion.

Supplementary material: File

Jiang et al. supplementary material

Jiang et al. supplementary material
Download Jiang et al. supplementary material(File)
File 292.4 KB