Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-25wd4 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-29T17:56:18.970Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Institutional Logics: Motivating Action and Overcoming Resistance to Change

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 December 2023

Heather A. Haveman*
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley, Berkeley, CA, USA
David Joseph-Goteiner
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley, Berkeley, CA, USA
Danyang Li
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley, Berkeley, CA, USA
*
Corresponding author: Heather Haveman (haveman@berkeley.edu)
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Institutional logics are interrelated sets of cultural elements (norms, values, beliefs, and symbols) that help people and organizations make sense of their everyday activities and order those activities in time and space. In this paper, we describe the rise of a robust literature on institutional logics, which mostly focuses on Western societies. We then describe changes in Chinese society and economy over the past four decades, as it shifted from state-controlled planning and redistribution to market-mediated exchange. We detail how the institutional logics that guide Chinese firms have been transformed in the wake of the economic transition. The state logic, which developed in the Maoist era, valorizes equality, national community, and political stability. Although it is still in evidence, it has been partly supplanted by a market logic that encourages efficiency, competition, and property rights. But this market logic differs from the one that prevails in Western capitalist economies. The Chinese version of the market logic valorizes the central role that the state and the Communist Party continue to play in economic life. Therefore, in the Chinese version of the market logic, efficiency, competition, and property rights are tempered by a continued concern for political stability. We review and summarize the existing literature on institutional logics and Chinese firms, and then identify fruitful lines that future research could take.

摘要

制度逻辑是一系列相互关联的文化元素, 包括规范、价值观、信仰和符号等。制度逻辑有助于个人和组织理解其日常活动, 并在一定的时间和空间里安排这些活动。本文首先回顾聚焦于西方社会的制度逻辑研究,然后描述中国在过去40多年中的经济社会变化, 重点阐释从计划经济向社会主义市场经济的转型,并分析指导中国企业运作的制度逻辑是如何随经济社会转型而发生变化的。在计划经济时代, 中国社会强调的是平等、民族共同体和政治稳定的国家逻辑。如今, 原有国家逻辑仍然存在, 但一部分已经被鼓励效率、竞争和产权的市场逻辑取代。然而,中国的市场逻辑与西方资本主义经济的市场逻辑不同,因为它强调党和政府在经济生活中继续发挥核心作用, 效率、竞争和产权都需要服从政治稳定性。最后,本文总结了有关制度逻辑和中国企业的现有研究, 并提出了一些有前景的研究方向。

Type
Dialogue, Debate, and Discussion
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of International Association for Chinese Management Research

Introduction

China's dramatic economic transformation from state planning and redistribution to market exchange, which started in 1978, has challenged our understanding of how societal change works. Central to this transformation are organizations – government bureaus, of course, but also state-owned enterprises (SOEs), township and village enterprises (TVEs), privately owned small- and medium-sized firms, and large publicly traded corporations. Civil-society organizations such as educational institutions, professional-service associations, and religious organizations have also played important roles in this transformation. Given their importance, it is not surprising that organizational scholars have joined economists, legal scholars, sociologists, and political scientists in asking how this transformation came about, how it was implemented, and how it managed to succeed so well (e.g., Clarke, Murrell, & Whiting, Reference Clarke, Murrell, Whiting, Rawski and Brandt2008; Keister & Zhang, Reference Keister and Zhang2009; Kennedy, Reference Kennedy2008; Lin, Reference Lin2001b; Naughton, Reference Naughton2018; Nee, Reference Nee1992; Oi, Reference Oi1999; Walder, Reference Walder1989).

To understand China's transformation from an organizational perspective, and in particular to focus attention on the evolving values, norms, and practices that underpinned productive organizations during this transformation, we consider a typical enterprise, founded in 1966 as a small state-run factory. A half-century later, it had become a global leader in the power-equipment industry (Raynard, Lu, & Jing, Reference Raynard, Lu and Jing2020). For the first decade of this factory's operations, work processes and policies were dictated by central state authorities and enterprise managers were subordinated to a revolutionary committee of Communist Party members. Rewards for workers were based on position, not performance. Workers accepted self-sacrifice and valued camaraderie, and applauded their enterprise's contributions to the nation's economic development. In the 1980s, the central state shifted from planning and redistribution to market-mediated transactions, and enterprises like this one lost their formerly steady sources of supply and income. The development of market-based exchange spurred competition. Enterprise performance became critical, so worker rewards became tied to performance – although slowly, as it took until 2002 to fully adopt a performance-based wage system.

To legitimize the changes that occurred to this organization's goals, structures, and procedures during the economic transition, this organization's managers did considerable ‘values work’ (Raynard et al., Reference Raynard, Lu and Jing2020), meaning actions directed at articulating and rearticulating what was good or bad in how their organization operated. For example, they often relied on existing values, such as by framing changes in terms of national imperatives mandated by the state. To avoid clashes in values between the old way of operating (under the system of state planning and redistribution) and the new way of operating (under the system of market exchange), managers implemented some market-based practices only partially or not at all. For instance, rewards were eventually determined by worker performance rather than position, but this change was buffered by minimizing inequalities between workers in similar positions. Thus, this enterprise retained and redeployed values and practices from the pre-reform era, even while fundamentally transforming its operations to become a global industry leader.

This firm's history illustrates the concept of institutional logics, ‘systems of cultural elements (values, beliefs, and normative expectations) by which people, groups, and organizations make sense of and evaluate their everyday activities, and organize those activities in time and space’ (Haveman & Gualtieri, Reference Haveman, Gualtieri and Aldag2017: 1). Let us take this definition apart to make sure it is clear. To begin, the definition states that institutional logics are systems of cultural elements: cultural because they include values, beliefs, and normative expectations, and systems because elements are connected in a coherent and discernable pattern. Individuals, groups, and entire organizations use institutional logics to make sense of and evaluate their everyday activities. Sense-making involves creating a coherent account of the world by categorizing what we see, do, and feel, and applying patterns to connect this account to things we've seen, done, and felt before, or anticipate seeing, doing, and feeling in the future (for more details, see Weick, Reference Weick1995). Evaluation involves judging the worth of the people and things we have categorized: individuals, groups, organizations, actions, symbols, material objects, etc. (for a review, see Lamont, Reference Lamont2012). Beyond sense-making and evaluation, institutional logics are used by individuals, groups, and entire organizations to order their activities in time and space. This encompasses creating, maintaining, evaluating, and adjusting formal organizational structures (the individuals and subunits that are assigned responsibility for particular tasks, as well as the flow of tasks and lines of authority that connect individuals and subunits), procedures (e.g., processes for hiring, evaluating, rewarding, and firing employees; searching for, acquiring, and using resources to carry out assigned tasks; and surveying the external environment), informal cultures (symbols, norms, values, and expectations of behavior), and power distributions (which individuals, subunits, and organizations have formal authority or informal influence over which others).

In this paper, we begin by tracing the evolution of the concept of institutional logics and survey the burgeoning line of research on this concept. We then compare and contrast the institutional logics instantiated in different types of Chinese business organizations: SOEs, domestic privately owned firms, collectively owned enterprises (COEs), and foreign-owned firms. We conclude with speculation about fruitful paths for the study of institutional logics in China.

Institutional Logics

The concept of institutional logics first emerged in the 1990s. Sociologists Roger Friedland and Robert Alford were inspired by Max Weber's (Reference Weber1904–05 [1958]) writings on value systems, in which Weber contrasted four kinds of rationalities that could drive action: tradition or ingrained habit, emotions, values and ethical beliefs, and instrumentality and means-end relationships (Weber, Reference Weber1978: 24–26). Weber argued that the behavior of individuals, groups, and organizations depends on both rationalities and external factors such as state policy and technology. For their part, Friedland and Alford recognized that in most organizations, instrumental and value rationality coexist in the logics that guide organizational behavior: these rationalities set the rules of the game and determine what practices can (indeed must) be used and what structures and roles are acceptable (indeed essential). Friedland and Alford wanted to follow early sociologists like Weber and bring back larger social structures into the study of organizations – structures beyond immediate organizational environments such as industries or industrial sectors. To this end, they defined institutional logics as ‘sets of material practices and symbolic constructions [that] constitute [the] organizing principles’ of institutional orders (Friedland and Alford, Reference Friedland, Alford, Powell and DiMaggio1991: 248–249). In Weber's theory, five social orders prevail in modern Western societies: the capitalist market, the bureaucratic state, democratic politics, the nuclear family, and Christian religion. Each institutional order has a different logic, so we speak of the family logic, the bureaucratic logic, the capitalist market logic, etc. Thus, according to this definition, institutional logics are societal-level phenomena.

Institutional logics determine both what should be done in order to achieve desired outcomes and what is good to do. In other words, they encompass two of Weber's forms of rationality, instrumental (means-end) rationality and value rationality. Multiple societal-level logics exist, sometimes competing, other times coexisting more or less peacefully. This view privileges structure over agency: societies create constraints and opportunities for organizational action, while organizations create constraints and opportunities for individual and group action. This leaves little room for individuals, groups, or organizations to find ways to maneuver around or challenge and change institutional logics.

It is important to note that although institutional logics are cognitive-cultural elements used in sense-making, evaluation, and planning, we observe them through their material manifestations: organizational structures, practices, policies, and the roles played by organizational members. Thus, there is a duality of institutional logics and their material manifestations: they are co-constitutive (Haveman & Rao, Reference Haveman and Rao1997). This means that material phenomena like organizational practices are the consequences of actions guided by institutional logics. But those material phenomena also shape institutional logics: their very existence can support, transform, or challenge institutional logics.

Multiple Levels of Analysis

While Friedland and Alford originally envisioned people and groups in organizations ‘competing and negotiating’ (Reference Friedland, Alford, Powell and DiMaggio1991: 240–241) over logics, they insisted that logics were societal-level constructs. But two decades later, scholars came to see institutional logics as existing at multiple levels of analysis: not just at the societal level, but also at the organizational, industry, and interorganizational field levels (Dunn & Jones, Reference Dunn and Jones2010; Thornton, Ocasio, & Lounsbury, Reference Thornton, Ocasio and Lounsbury2012).Footnote 1 An example of an organizational-level institutional logic comes from the Italian design and manufacturing firm Alessi. It blends two logics – industrial manufacturing and cultural production – to achieve a hybrid logic that gives it a competitive advantage while also allowing this firm to maintain its cultural legitimacy (Dalpiaz, Rindova, & Ravasi, Reference Dalpiaz, Rindova and Ravasi2016). An example of a field-level institutional logic comes from American health care (e.g., hospitals and clinics). In the 1970s, this field was dominated by a professional logic, where doctors dominated decision making (Scott, Ruef, Mendel, & Caronna, Reference Scott, Ruef, Mendel and Caronna2000). Later, it became driven by a state logic where government agencies like Medicare determined how medical professionals and healthcare organizations made decisions. Currently, it is dominated by an economic (efficiency) logic involving cost–benefit analysis conducted by insurance companies.

Expanding the definition of institutional logics to operate at multiple levels of analysis makes it possible to posit cross-level effects of institutional logics. It also places greater emphasis on agency than the original definition. Indeed, scholars who expanded the definition invoked the term ‘embedded agency’ (Thornton et al., Reference Thornton, Ocasio and Lounsbury2012: 2) to reflect their assumption that while institutional logics constrain the choice sets available to individuals, groups, and organizations, they also provide opportunities for those actors to socially construct and reconstruct logics in ways that reflect their interests. This means that individuals, groups, and organizations can create new institutional logics and change or undermine existing ones in order to achieve their interests; they accomplish this by selecting cultural elements of higher-level logics and applying them to lower-level logics. This expanded definition implies that while actors are embedded in institutional logics, they are at least partly autonomous from them. Actors like individuals and organizations can pursue their own interests by picking and choosing logics, or by joining with others in social-movement-like activism to create or change logics.

Relationship with Other Cultural/Cognitive Phenomena

Institutional logics differ in subtle ways from four prominent cultural/cognitive concepts that organizational theorists use in their research: organizational cultures, organizational identities, schemas, and frames. We consider each in turn. Organizational cultures consist of underlying assumptions (existential statements about how things work), espoused values (understandings of what is good and bad), shared norms (understandings of what is normal and abnormal, of what we do and how we do it), and symbols (tangible artifacts like clothing, jargon, and office décor, intangible elements like stories and ceremonies) (Geertz, Reference Geertz1973; Pettigrew, Reference Pettigrew1979; Schein, Reference Schein1996; Selznick, Reference Selznick1957). Because organizational cultures involve shared ideologies that are revealed in language, rites, and rituals, they are some of the most commonly studied everyday manifestations of institutional logics.

Closely related to organizational cultures are organizational identities, beliefs organizational members hold about what makes their organizations distinctive (Gioia et al., Reference Gioia, Patvardhan, Hamilton and Corley2013; Whetten, Reference Whetten2006). They function as subliminal guides for organizational responses to unanticipated operational or strategic issues, shaping how people in organizations interpret issues and influencing their motivations for acting on them (Dutton & Dukerich, Reference Dutton and Dukerich1991). The focus in research on organizational identities is variation between organizations – how much a focal organization stands out from the crowd or blends in. In contrast, the focus of research on institutional logics is broader, encompassing both variation and similarity. In addition, the focus in research on institutional identities is on external evaluators, while the focus in research on institutional logics includes both external and internal evaluators.

The other two concepts, schemas and frames, are widely used, not just in organizational research, but also in cultural sociology, cognitive psychology, behavioral economics, and linguistics. Schemas are sets of mental associations: patterned knowledge about people, events, objects, groups, and organizations that develop with experience and that provide default associations about the characteristics of people, events, etc., and the relationships between them (DiMaggio, Reference DiMaggio1997; Hunzaker & Valentino, Reference Hunzaker and Valentino2019). Schemas are used by people to interpret themselves, others with whom they interact, and their surroundings. Schemas can be widely shared; if so, they are usually labeled cultural schemas to emphasize the social interactions required to share them. Frames are contextual stimuli that elicit schemas and so help people interpret their situations and figure out how to act (DiMaggio, Reference DiMaggio1997; Goffman, Reference Goffman1974). Different frames evoke different schemas. For example, consider seeing a tiger at the zoo versus in your backyard. The first framing of the tiger might elicit your calm curiosity; the second would probably frighten you. What you do next has a certain logic to it (run? hide? shoot? call animal control?), informed by not only instinct but also learned ideas and habits. Like schemas, institutional logics involve sense-making, but they are broader than schemas because they also involve evaluation and because they link sense-making to social structure (Valentino, Reference Valentino2021). Like frames, institutional logics were originally conceptualized as external stimuli, but institutional logics later came to be recognized as internal to organizations, even to groups (e.g., occupational groups) within organizations (Valentino, Reference Valentino2021).

A final consideration in comparing institutional logics to other cultural/cognitive concepts is that institutional logics are interdependent with material practices. As explained above, institutional logics and material practices are co-constitutive, reflecting and reinforcing each other. This is very different from identities, frames, and schemas, which are purely cultural/cognitive phenomena, independent of the material world. For their part, organizational cultures are sometimes conceived of as purely cultural/cognitive structures, but at other times as including material practices such as rituals and roles, and material objects such as physical structures and office decor.

Empirical Examples of Institutional Logics

To make this mostly abstract discussion concrete, we discuss several empirical studies of institutional logics. To begin, consider early American thrifts, financial institutions that brought people together to save money and build or buy houses. These organizations were guided by a series of institutional logics involving beliefs about how to organize saving and home ownership; different logics arose at different times, replacing earlier logics (Haveman & Rao, Reference Haveman and Rao1997). The first thrift logic, which appeared in the 1860s, valorized mutual cooperation and rigidly structured action. It was predicated on the idea of community as the source of interpersonal trust. Thrifts following this logic had members who perceived each other as belonging to the same community (they tended to know each other before joining) and who met at regular intervals to save money and then borrow from the growing communal fund to build or buy homes. They dissolved their associations when their joint task was completed. All thrift members played the same roles, as both savers and borrowers.

Sixty years later, the dominant thrift logic valorized bureaucracy (the division of labor by role and time) and voluntary, instrumentally rational action, predicated on the notion of bureaucracy as the source of interpersonal trust. Thrifts following this logic were permanent organizations run by professional managers. They distinguished between owners of installment shares (which could be withdrawn at any time, or augmented at any time in any amount) and guarantee shares (capital investment that was non-withdrawable and used to guarantee earnings on installment shares). They also distinguished between savers (owners of installment and guarantee shares) and borrowers: not all savers had to borrow to build or buy homes.

This narrative reveals that as thrifts’ institutional logics shifted, so did thrift members’ roles and thrifts’ goals, authority structures, financial-intermediation technologies, and services. Table 1 summarizes the foundational values and material features of the two thrift logics. As this example illustrates, institutional logics can vary over time and across space, depending on external events, the composition of actors (individual and organizational) in the fields organized by the logics under study, and actors’ preferences and knowledge about or skill with practices.

Table 1. Comparing thrift logics

Changes in institutional logics have also been observed in the US book publishing industry, where the editorial logic, which viewed editors as professionals and emphasized their relationships with authors as the key to success, was replaced in the 1970s by the market logic, which viewed editors as corporate executives and emphasized competition between publishing firms as the main determinant of success (Thornton & Ocasio, Reference Thornton and Ocasio1999). This shift in institutional logics changed how publishing companies grew (originally by nurturing new authors, later by acquiring other firms to gain market power) and the forces that drove executive succession (originally organizational size and internal structure, later the market for corporate control). In a very different context, for over a century, fine French restaurants followed the classical cuisine logic, which valorized conservatism and connections to the past (e.g., dishes named after pre-Revolutionary nobility), conformity with eighteenth-century rules, and physical refinement of ingredients (e.g., sauces). The new logic that became dominant by the 1990s, the logic of nouvelle cuisine, was centered on the values of truth, light, simplicity, and imagination; it valorized creativity and novelty, transgression of classical prescriptions, and ‘exotic’ ingredients and techniques from foreign culinary traditions (Rao, Monin, & Durand, Reference Rao, Monin and Durand2003). On the ground, these two logics led to the creation of different organizational structures, practices, and power distributions: who held power (restaurant owners or chefs), menu length (long and dependent on stored ingredients or short and focused on fresh ingredients), and the roles of wait staff (preparing food table-side or merely delivering it).

Although the strength of institutional logics generally varies over time, with newer logics replacing older ones, they may not die out completely. For example, in American medical schools, the strength of two logics – care and science – fluctuated in response to contestation among physicians, competition with rival healthcare practitioners, funding changes (the rise of managed care), and the increasing representation of women (Dunn & Jones, Reference Dunn and Jones2010). In a more extreme case, the craft brewing logic almost disappeared from Holland, but it regained strength as craft brewing resurged in other countries such as Germany, Belgium, and the US (Kroezen & Heugens, Reference Kroezen and Heugens2019). Its re-emergence in the Netherlands was facilitated by the ‘institutional remnants’ of the craft logic: artifacts such as writings about beer and the craft of brewing, brewery names, and brewery buildings.

Institutional logics can persist even in the face of powerful forces propelling change. For example, in the American banking industry, the Bank of North Dakota (BND) has consistently embodied a hybrid of the community and state logics, and has long resisted adopting the market logic (Schneiberg, Reference Schneiberg2013). The community logic values local activities over nonlocal ones; for banking, this means originating loans from community members and holding them locally. The state logic valorizes public ownership of enterprises, such as municipally owned associations (e.g., municipal power or sewer companies), and investing in public works; for banks, this means cooperating with state agencies and state-owned organizations, and offering them preferential interest rates on loans. In contrast, the market logic values private ownership, pursuit of profits above all else, and transactions on a national (and transnational) level; for banking, this means originating loans from anywhere, charging the highest interest rates that borrowers would accept, bundling loans into securities, and selling those securities on the national market to free up capital for future lending. BND was able to resist adopting the market logic because its hybrid community-state logic is successful: it has been consistently profitable for a half-century. Notably, none of the local financial-service institutions that it supports failed during the 2008–2010 financial crisis. Part of the strength of BND's hybrid logic is its deep historical roots: it was forged during the Progressive era (the early twentieth century), when local farmers and government officials banded together to fight outside corporate interests over the financing and operation of the state's grain trade.

Multiple Institutional Logics May Coexist

Many scholars have studied how multiple logics interact. For example, the actions of Spanish firms depend on the location of their branch establishments: those with operations more concentrated in regions with higher levels of government spending on economic development are less likely to downsize, emphasizing an equity logic, which values employees, over an efficiency logic, which values maximizing earnings relative to expenses (Greenwood, Díaz, Li, & Lorente, Reference Greenwood, Díaz, Li and Lorente2010). Similarly, local banks whose founders are motivated by a finance logic, which sees banks as investment vehicles and places a priority on maximizing profits, are more likely to finance growth using risky deposit instruments than banks whose founders are motivated by a community logic, which values meeting community needs over earning profits (Almandoz, Reference Almandoz2014).

Multiple institutional logics vary in their compatibility with and centrality to organizational functioning (Besharov & Smith, Reference Besharov and Smith2014). Considering both dimensions yields a four-cell typology of situations where two or more logics coexist. (1) Low compatibility and high centrality of both (or all) logics yields contestation and extensive conflict. For example, bank acquisitions in the United States in the 1990s and 2000s, driven by the logic of efficient geographic diversification, led those who supported the logic of community banking to actively oppose such acquisitions by launching new local, community-focused banks (Marquis & Lounsbury, Reference Marquis and Lounsbury2007). (2) High compatibility and high centrality yields alignment (or blending/hybridization) and minimal conflict. For instance, in public–private energy-industry alliances, people grapple with very different logics of success; as they confront outcomes that are successes when viewed through the logic of public service, but failures when viewed through the logic of client service, they are forced to synthesize the logics into a new one (Jay, Reference Jay2012). (3) High compatibility and low centrality (meaning one logic is core to organizational functioning) yields a single dominant logic and no conflict. For example, the shareholder-value logic, which posits that corporations’ primary goal is to maximize share price by cutting costs to ensure short-term profits, has dominated American corporations since the 1980s (Fligstein, Reference Fligstein2001). This logic is so overpowering that it was not imperiled even by the 2008–2010 financial crisis (Fligstein & Goldstein, Reference Fligstein and Goldstein2022). (4) Low compatibility and low centrality yields one dominant logic and moderate conflict, as people adjudicate between logics. For instance, the peacefully coexisting cultural-preservation and professional logics held by workers in one cultural organization were confronted with a market logic espoused by senior managers and funding agencies; however, the market logic was peripheral to the organization's goals, so conflict was moderate for a long period of time (Townley, Reference Townley2002).

Agency and Institutional Logics

The existence of multiple logics offers opportunities for actors to choose the logics that best suit their interests. For example, Belgium's ornamental horticulture industry, which traditionally valued maximizing plant yield and minimizing risk by using fertilizers and chemical pesticides, was challenged by an environmentally focused logic, which valorized ‘green’ (environmentally friendly) pest-control methods, such as using insects to eat pest insects, and carefully treating waste to reduce the toxicity of chemicals released into the soil and water (Lepoutre & Valente, Reference Lepoutre and Valente2012). This new logic required owner-managers to develop ‘immunity’ to the traditional (yield-oriented, risk-minimizing) logic by theorizing the future of their industry as contributing to environmental sustainability. This framing persuaded others – customers, funding sources, and employees – that adhering to the environmental logic would also yield profits. In addition, owner-managers adapted their organizations’ strategies and routines to fit the new environmental logic, such as by selling directly to consumers who appreciated organic horticulture.

Instead of choosing one logic over another, actors sometimes deploy multiple logics simultaneously. For example, in the international film industry, successful filmmakers must balance the logics of art and business to create ‘optimal distinctiveness’, meaning films that have an idiosyncratic style but are not so different from other films that they cannot appeal to large audiences (Alvarez, Mazza, Pedersen, & Svejenova, Reference Alvarez, Mazza, Pedersen and Svejenova2005). To maximize their autonomy over the film-production process, filmmakers take on multiple artistic roles – writers, directors, and producers – while simultaneously creating their own production companies or developing strong ties to existing production companies. Control over multiple roles makes it possible for filmmakers to craft their own idiosyncratic styles, while working within production companies keeps them focused, at least in part, on audience engagement. At a lower (intraorganizational) level of analysis, professionals can use different logics to their own advantage. For example, in a US drug court, public defenders (lawyers who represent the accused) sometimes deploy the punishment logic, which values sanctioning and controlling offenders, and which is most strongly associated with probation officers (agents of the state who supervise offenders) (McPherson & Sauder, Reference McPherson and Sauder2013). Public defenders do this in order to argue for early release of the accused or admission to drug rehabilitation, instead of sentencing them to serve time in jail. These examples show how actors can alter core organizational practices and performance-related outcomes by choosing from among multiple logics.

The Broader Consequences of Institutional Logics

Institutional logics affect individuals, entire organizations, and society at large. For example, adherence to the shareholder-value logic described above has pushed many large Japanese and American firms to downsize their workforces (Ahmadjian & Robbins, Reference Ahmadjian and Robbins2005; Jung, Reference Jung2016) – although in American firms, managers have been less affected than line workers and support staff (Goldstein, Reference Goldstein2012). Most of the low-level employees who remain are paid less and offered fewer benefits than they were before the shareholder-value logic took hold, while managers, professionals, and skilled technical workers receive better pay and benefits, although they are expected to work longer hours. The result is increasing earnings inequality (Fligstein & Shin, Reference Fligstein, Shin and Neckerman2004) and the rise of precarious jobs with unpredictable schedules for low-level employees, which harm their mental and physical health (Schneider & Harknett, Reference Schneider and Harknett2019).

Institutional Logics in Chinese FirmsFootnote 2

China's idiosyncratic historical trajectory makes it a rich laboratory for studying institutional logics because large-scale changes in Chinese society and economy impelled dramatic changes in the logics guiding the organization and operation (indeed, the very existence) of business organizations. The end of the Qing Dynasty in 1912 ushered in an extended period of conflict between shifting political factions, most notably the Nationalists and the Communists, punctuated by war with Japan. Conflict ended in 1949 and the Communist Party came to power under the leadership of Mao Ze Dong. The communist regime sought to restore the economy after decades of raging battles: it repaired transportation and communication systems, unified the monetary system, and gradually took control of all productive enterprises. In political-economic terms, the result was ‘China Inc.’, where all extractive, manufacturing, and service enterprises were state-owned and state-controlled, and agriculture was collectivized under state supervision. Economic production was mandated by a series of five-year plans designed by central state authorities, with cascading effects from central state authorities down through the administrative ranks to provinces, prefectures, counties, and finally townships and villages. This system relied heavily on distribution and redistribution of inputs, outputs, and economic surpluses guided by the central state and flowing across administrative levels, productive enterprises, regions, and economic sectors.

This political-economic regime institutionalized state intervention in and direction of China's economy (as well as all other aspects of Chinese society, including language, family, and education). As a result, productive enterprises ranging from agricultural collectives to healthcare facilities to factories – you can think of them all as subsidiaries of ‘China, Inc.’ – uniformly embodied a state logic. This logic valorized equality and national collectivism. With regard to equality, productive enterprises, no matter how unprofitable or inefficient, could survive because the central state supported them financially with funds reallocated from profitable enterprises. With regard to national collectivism, central state officials (rather than enterprise managers) set goals and production targets, directed flows of raw materials and equipment, and established and enforced rules governing the workforce (i.e., hiring, promotion, and wage rates). The national collectivism pillar of the state logic emphasized the notion of national self-reliance and self-sufficiency; it valorized ‘manual labor [and] mass mobilization over technology, intellect and efficiency’ (Fan, Reference Fan2005).

Despite its concern for equality, the state logic also involved a concern for political stability that prioritized political goals and social and market stability over economic efficiency. As a result, political capital – i.e., ties to state officials – was an important determinant of the economic prospects of enterprises and individuals alike (Bian, Reference Bian1997; Chang, Reference Chang2011; Peng & Luo, Reference Peng and Luo2000). The importance of political ties reflected the fact that guanxi – social relations involving mutual obligation and indebtedness – has long been the bedrock of Chinese society, due to the influence of Confucianism (Fei, Reference Fei1948 [1992]; Lin, Reference Lin, So, Lin and Poston2001a). Confucianism valorizes morality, justice, and social correctness; it emphasizes that such values derive from relations with family, friends, and neighbors, which define who people are and what they can do.

The situation changed dramatically, albeit slowly, starting in the late 1970s. A series of laws were passed to legally define forms of business, safeguard property rights, and regulate competition (Guthrie, Reference Guthrie2009; Nee, Reference Nee1992; Oi & Walder, Reference Oi and Walder1999). State administrative reforms empowered enterprise managers to experiment, innovate, and undertake new or expanded activities; enterprises could retain whatever profits their enterprises earned above state quotas; in the economy, the central state gradually replaced state redistribution with market-mediated transactions (Keister & Zhang, Reference Keister and Zhang2009; Naughton, Reference Naughton1995, Reference Naughton2007, Reference Naughton2018). Under this system, state officials shucked off old roles as allocators and redistributors of resources, forged new roles as regulators and brokers of market transactions, and focused increasingly on promoting economic growth (Lin, Reference Lin2001b). State policies also shifted to a new development strategy that emphasized ‘efficiency over equity, individual creativity over collectivism, and regional comparative advantages over defense and ideological considerations’ (Lin, Reference Lin2001b).

Reforms were instituted in piecemeal fashion, at different times in different locations, starting with rural and township villages, then proceeding to Special Economic Zones in Shenzhen and Shanghai and along the east coast, before being rolled out across provinces and prefectures nationwide. New forms of economic actors like privately owned and foreign-owned businesses appeared, and SOEs closed or were transformed into firms with either private or hybrid state-private ownership (Nee, Reference Nee1992; Oi, Reference Oi1992, Reference Oi1999). As a result of these reforms, ownership of productive enterprises shifted away from the central state (‘China Inc.’) toward a combination of local state authorities (province, county, prefecture, township, and village) and private, non-state entities, both domestic and foreign.

As these reforms unfolded over the decades, a new market logic developed, valorizing efficiency, market competition, and property rights. With regard to efficiency, the goal is to maximize output (sales and especially profits) while minimizing inputs (raw materials, human labor, equipment, and especially funding). This logic tolerates economic development that is uneven across Chinese regions as long as it yields efficient outcomes for the nation as a whole. The principle of market competition allows any enterprise to buy any good or service from any other enterprise, and sell to any other enterprise or individual. The price and quality of the goods and services offered for sale jointly determine which market exchanges happen. These principles apply to both the private and public sectors: like private firms, SOEs, and local governments also compete over resources and development gains. With regard to property rights, ownership is established through payment or through the creation of goods and services. Owners have the exclusive right to use and benefit from their property, and can exchange their property voluntarily and without restriction.

To facilitate comparisons between the state and market logics, Table 2 details both. The state logic prevailed under the state socialist (state-redistributive) system; the market logic developed under the capitalist (market-exchange) system. The state logic depended on central-state planning and control over inputs, outputs, and earnings; the market logic depends, as its name suggests, on market-mediated exchanges between buyers and sellers. Under the state logic, the state controlled all labor relations, and all rewards were determined by political status and political capital; under the market logic, firm managers control labor, and rewards are determined by performance and human capital. Under the state logic, enterprises sought to meet output goals and stabilize their operations, and low-productivity firms could survive because the state reallocated resources from profitable firms to support them; under the market logic, firms seek to maximize sales and therefore profits and low-productivity firms fail. In sum, the state logic valorizes equality, national community, and political stability; the market logic seeks efficiency by encouraging competition and valuing property rights.

Table 2. Dominant institutional logics in China: State and market

Note: The material in parentheses discusses how the market logic actually plays out on the ground in China, which is very different from how it plays out in many western capitalist countries.

Table 2 depicts the state and market logics as distinct – as ideal types in the Weberian sense. In practice, however, these two logics are related. The market logic, as it is realized in China, has ‘Chinese characteristics’, meaning that it is different in important ways from the market logic that prevails in advanced capitalist economies such as the US, Japan, Britain, and Germany. In the description of the market logic in Table 2, these ‘Chinese characteristics’ are noted in parentheses. Most important is that the Chinese version of the market logic continues to recognize the central role that the state and the Communist Party play in economic life (Nee Reference Nee1992). The persistence of state and party power over the economy is embedded in China's history, which has propelled the transition toward market-mediated transactions in a specific way. In short, economic reform was not accompanied by political reform, so China remains an authoritarian country (Economist Intelligence Unit, 2021). The Communist Party has retained control over politics, the state bureaucracy, and the legal system (Clarke et al., Reference Clarke, Murrell, Whiting, Rawski and Brandt2008; McGregor, Reference McGregor2012). State authorities retain the power to issue permits and licenses, and to levy fees, fines, and taxes (e.g., Lin, Reference Lin2001b; Yang, Reference Yang2005). They also control the remaining SOEs, as well as land and most sources of capital (e.g., Shih, Reference Shih2008).

As a result, in the early years of economic reform, many Chinese firms, especially the rural (township and village) enterprises that were some of the earliest organizations to venture into market exchanges, were guided by a distinct combination of the state and market logics (Nee, Reference Nee1992; Oi, Reference Oi1992, Reference Oi1999). In later years, when membership in the Communist Party was opened to business people, those who led privately owned firms found ways to reconcile their Communist Party membership and their other connections to the state with their activities as capitalists (Marquis & Qiao, Reference Marquis and Qiao2020). Today, the values and schemas of many who run Chinese privately owned firms continue to be shaped by Maoist ideology. Three Maoist principles – nationalism, frugality, and devotion to serving the masses – influence firms’ cost strategy, internationalization strategy, and social-responsibility practices (Marquis & Qiao, Reference Marquis and Qiao2022).

Clearly, in the Chinese version of the market logic, efficiency, competition, and property rights have always been tempered by a continued concern for political stability. A prominent example of this is then-President Hu Jintao's (Reference Hu2005) concern for a ‘harmonious society’ [hexie shehui]. The driving ideology behind China's development strategy was that economic growth must be balanced by the equitable distribution of prosperity through what Hu called the ‘scientific view on development’. This would attain social justice and ensure social stability. This development strategy was also depicted as intrinsic to ‘socialism with Chinese characteristics’. More recently, President Xi Jinping expressed concern for ‘common prosperity’ (Xi, Reference Xi2021), indicating a desire to stem rising economic inequality. Concerns about economic inequality and social instability shifted the state's focus from economic growth to a more balanced, Confucian-style value system, which involved maintaining economic growth while ameliorating rural poverty, income inequality, environmental degradation, and corruption. This twin concern also involved maintaining central state control of development, while allowing for some decentralized participation by local governments and entrepreneurs.

Recently, there has been a shift in China's approach toward business indicating a resurgence of Maoist values and increasing state control over private enterprise. Two key examples of this shift are the rise of Communist Party cells in privately owned firms and the tightening of control over firms’ initial public offerings (IPOs). First, the Chinese government has ramped up requirements that all privately owned firms with more than three Party members among their workers must have Party cells (Marquis & Qiao, Reference Marquis and Qiao2022). These cells are usually headed by people appointed by the central Party; they bring together workers who are Party members. Their main activities involve socializing new members, providing them benefits like housing and insurance, mapping out career paths for them, mentoring them, and helping them meet other members. Communist Party cells also help company leaders understand government policies. This requirement has been interpreted as a way to strengthen the Party's control over private firms, blurring the boundary between state and market.

Second, the Chinese government has taken measures to tighten control over IPOs. Several highly publicized IPOs of Chinese privately owned firms were suspended or canceled. Perhaps best-known is that Ant Group's highly anticipated IPO on the Shanghai and Hong Kong exchanges, which was set to be the world's largest IPO, was postponed in 2020 and not approved until 2 years later. State-directed cancelation and postponement of IPOs suggest a growing concern about the risks posed by unregulated, rapidly growing privately owned companies and a desire to exert more oversight over their activities.

Forms of Ownership and Institutional Logics

Which institutional logic guides a Chinese firm – state, market, or a mixture – depends in large part (but not entirely) on the firm's governance and ownership. Chinese firms can be most easily classified into four ownership forms: SOEs; COEs, which are known as TVEs when they are located in rural areas; privately owned enterprises (POEs); and foreign-owned enterprises (FOEs). Table 3 details the ideal-typical features of the four forms of ownership, as well as the institutional logics central to each. SOEs are owned by state agencies, either central or local, controlled by state authorities, and dominated by the state logic. COEs are owned by different local communities (either urban districts or rural townships and villages), controlled by state agencies at those levels, and balance both state and market logics. They pursue efficiency through competing in the market, but also emphasize the equitable distribution of profits. COEs’ success is partly due to local government-business partnerships: local state officials are directly involved in COE business activities through formal public policies and informal social ties with CEO managers (Li, Reference Li2005; Oi, Reference Oi1999). POEs are owned by individual investors, families, or investment groups like mutual funds. They follow the market logic because they have strong incentives to compete and perform well, as profits return to their owners. But, as explained above, many POEs are guided by Maoist values, so the market logic in POEs has distinct ‘Chinese characteristics’. Finally, FOEs can be wholly owned subsidiaries of foreign firms or joint ventures between foreign and domestic firms. They are dominated by the market logic.

Table 3. Typology of Chinese ownership forms

Notes: In practice, these ownership forms are usually blended. For example, many SOEs have minority private and/or foreign owners. This is especially likely for firms that are listed on the domestic stock exchanges, where A shares are held by domestic investors while B and H shares are held by foreign investors.

Although Table 3 draws sharp lines between forms of ownership and the logics that guide them, reality on the ground is complicated by hybrid ownership forms. Shares in SOEs that have been listed on the stock markets have been allowed to be sold to private investors, creating a partial state, partial private ownership form. Such hybrid ownership necessarily blurs the boundaries between the state and market logics, since different ownership groups are likely to be guided by different institutional logics: state owners are guided by the state logic more than the market logic; private owners are guided by the market logic (with Chinese characteristics) more than the state logic.

The situation is further complicated by the fact that starting in 1984, COEs began to allow employees and managers to sell shares to private and foreign investors (Che & Qian, Reference Che and Qian1998). This shift in ownership pushed COE owners as a whole toward the market logic and away from the state logic. But that did not mean abandoning the state logic in toto. Taking a longer view of the evolution of the Chinese political economy, the COE form can be considered a transitional form incorporating both political goals and market-economic incentives (Nee, Reference Nee1992; Oi, Reference Oi1992, Reference Oi1999; Xu, Lu, & Gu, Reference Xu, Lu and Gu2014).

Empirical Studies of Institutional Logics in Chinese FirmsFootnote 3

The factory described in the introduction, which became a power-machine firm during the reform era, illustrated key features of the state logic and the Chinese market logic (Raynard, Lu, & Jing, Reference Raynard, Lu and Jing2020). Many others have investigated how these two logics are manifested in Chinese firms, and how these two logics influence the behavior of both firms and their workers. For example, productive organizations founded under the Maoist regime are still more likely than those founded under the Deng regime to emphasize corporate social responsibility (CSR); the different institutional landscapes in which these organizations were founded shaped their approaches both materially and symbolically (Raynard, Lounsbury, & Greenwood, Reference Raynard, Lounsbury, Greenwood, Lounsbury and Boxenbaum2013).

The state logic influences the strategies used by Chinese entrepreneurs as well as established firms and state officials. Entrepreneurs who were more exposed to communist ideology in their youth – notably the Party's anti-foreign and anti-capitalist biases – were less likely to adopt an internationalization strategy for their ventures. But that ideological imprint could be gradually eroded through interactions promoting the market logic (Marquis & Qiao, Reference Marquis and Qiao2020). In the same vein, mayors with longer exposure to communist ideology were more likely to offer positions on local councils to managers from SOEs, farmers, or workers (vs. entrepreneurs) than were mayors with shorter exposure to communist ideology (Wang, Du, & Marquis, Reference Wang, Du and Marquis2019).

A national survey of Chinese manufacturing firms shows that, compared to POEs founded in the reform era, both POEs founded in the state socialist era and SOEs are more likely to comply with social insurance requirements because both bear the imprint of the state socialist logic concerning labor relations (Han, Zeng, & Xu, Reference Han, Zheng and Xu2014). In the same vein, SOEs can more easily obtain resources such as funding from state-controlled banks to invest in R&D than POEs because of their ownership-based ties to state authorities (Jia, Huang, & Zhang, Reference Jia, Huang and Zhang2019; Zhou, Gao, & Zhao, Reference Zhou, Gao and Zhao2017). But SOEs are less capable than POEs of transforming these resources into innovations because they are less driven by competition, due to SOEs’ adherence to the state logic. And employees in joint ventures between Chinese and foreign firms exhibit less guanxi behavior toward their supervisors than do those in SOEs, indicating that supervisor–subordinate guanxi behavior is deeply related to collectivism and that the state logic continues to guide SOEs (Chen, Reference Chen2020).

Contradictions and tensions exist based on who deploys the state logic and for what ends. Non-state actors can participate in firms’ governance processes, threatening the government's stability and its centrality in the market. For example, when environmental activists create social movements that are visible to the public through coverage by local media outlets, the state imposes severe environmental penalties on firms that pollute heavily (Marquis & Bird, Reference Marquis and Bird2018). But when complaints move through regular bureaucratic channels, penalties are seldom imposed and if they are imposed, they are small. The ability of social movements and news media to challenge state policies – and thus the logics that support and are reinforced by those policies – has been characterized as ‘responsive authoritarianism’ (Heurlin, Reference Heurlin2016).

Institutional logics are manifested in different and sometimes contradictory ways at different levels of the Chinese government. For example, the market logic prompted local governments to commercialize Buddhist temples and raise entrance fees, but the central government resisted this commercialization in response to public grievances articulated in terms of social justice, which are congruent with the state logic (Yue, Wang, & Yang, Reference Yue, Wang and Yang2019). Similarly, firms with stronger institutional linkages to the central government, which are more influenced by the state logic, wrote higher-quality CSR reports than firms located in provinces more heavily focused on GDP growth, which are more likely to be influenced by the market logic (Luo, Wang, & Zhang, Reference Luo, Wang and Zhang2017). But it is important to realize the considerable variation in fragmentation among state agencies, and in levels of market competition. The combination of fragmented state authority and market competition among media outlets gave local media leeway to produce critical news reports (Lei, Reference Lei2016).

Tensions between state and market logics can be seen most clearly in SOEs when they are expected to compete through technological innovation. For example, consider the Chinese railroad industry's effort to develop high-speed rail networks starting in 1989. It is difficult for railroad SOEs to balance the market logic's valorization of competition, which is often manifested as the development of new products or new production or distribution processes, with the state logic's valorization of maintaining social stability, especially by devoting resources to employee housing as well as generous healthcare and retirement benefits (Genin, Tan, & Song, Reference Genin, Tan and Song2021). Railroad SOEs that were directly supervised by state owners with majority stakes were less likely to innovate than SOEs with hybrid ownership (that is, substantial fractions of private and foreign ownership stakes). The latter tended to be affiliated with, but not directly supervised by, state authorities. The result was more conflict between state and market logics in the former than in the latter organizations; in the latter, the market logic prevailed.

Tension between state and market logics also occurs when firms with hybrid ownership seek to undertake acquisitions. Proponents of the state logic (that is, state owners) prefer acquisitions to be planned and administered by state authorities in order to maintain employment levels and thus ensure social stability. Market-oriented acquisitions might reduce employment levels, as they so often do in Western liberal economies. Proponents of the market logic (private domestic owners and foreign owners), in contrast, favor acquisitions that are based on strategic planning (that is, assessment of risk and strategic fit) and that create market value (in terms of market control through achieving economies of scale and or scope, and thus increases in stock prices). The more ownership of Chinese firms shifted away from state authorities to private investors (especially investment groups, which have considerable resources to bargain with management), the more the balance of ideas guiding acquisition activity tipped from the state logic to the market logic (Greve & Zhang, Reference Greve and Zhang2017). This shift became more pronounced over time, as more and more market reforms were rolled out. A similar tension between market and state logics can be seen in Chinese business groups, collections of firms that are closely linked by cross-ownership ties (Keister, Reference Keister2000). Business groups seek to achieve market-oriented goals, but they long continued to operate under state ownership (Yiu, Hoskisson, Bruton, & Yu, Reference Yiu, Hoskisson, Bruton and Lu2014) so they have had to balance market and state logics.

Hybrid logics can create tensions within individual firms, but it can also smooth the transition between institutional logics at the national or provincial level. As explained above, COEs are hybrid forms that accommodate both state and market logics, which eased the economic transition (Xu, Lu, & Gu, Reference Xu, Lu and Gu2014). Firms can also leverage the ambiguity of institutional logics to navigate their contradictions. For instance, a high-technology research park embraced elements of socialism, capitalism, and meritocracy in order to encourage positive associations among those logics and avoid their liabilities (Hsu, Reference Hsu2006). This study suggests that institutional entrepreneurs, like the founders of this technology park, can craft new forms of organization by selecting organizational elements that are congruent with different institutional logics; doing so makes it possible to signal multiple meanings to multiple audiences – to become polysemic and thus more legitimate to all audiences.

Table 4 summarizes research on institutional logics in Chinese organizations. It lists the authors, publication dates, and publication outlet. It also notes the type of organization(s) studied, the dependent variable, and the main argument. Most importantly, it explains how the authors operationalized institutional logics: how they ‘saw’ institutional logics manifested in their data. Finally, it notes the time period studied, which is important if we are to make the study of institutional logics in China more historically sensitive, and the methodological approach.

Table 4. Summary of empirical research on institutional logics in Chinese organizations

Directions for Future Research

We see three fruitful directions for the future study of institutional logics in Chinese firms. First, much of the existing research on institutional logics in China focuses on whether Chinese firms incorporate the state or market logic, or a combination of the two. This work is generally ahistorical, treating as it does Chinese political, legal, and economic institutions as background facts, and ignoring variation in these institutions over time and across regions, or holding these institutions constant by focusing on one set of organizations in one region at one point in time. (There are, of course, exceptions; e.g., Greve & Zhang, Reference Greve and Zhang2017). We could learn much more about the nuances of how institutional logics are manifested in Chinese firms the evolution of these logics if we took into consideration variation in these institutions over time and across regions, and if we investigated how temporal changes and regional differences in these institutions drove changes and cross-region differences in institutional logics.

Above, our necessarily brief description of China's historical trajectory glossed over many changes in these institutions (such as the passage of laws protecting property rights and contracts, the development of the financial-service sector to fund privately owned firms, and changes in the legal and accounting professions that support market-based exchange) that occurred during and after leadership transitions beginning with Deng Xiaoping and through Xi Jinping's rule (Naughton, Reference Naughton1995, Reference Naughton2007, Reference Naughton2018). Even before Deng Xiaoping became China's supreme leader in 1978 and economic reforms began in earnest, Premier Zhou Enlai's regime had experimented with reforms in the Sichuan Province; for example, by delegating authority for decision making to factory managers in 1975. Under Deng, these experiments were extended to other regions. In addition, the central state gradually delegated control over SOEs to local state authorities. SOEs began to retain a fraction of whatever they earned above the plan, and agricultural cooperatives began to be authorized to conduct administrative and financial experiments. In 1983, SOEs began to pay taxes instead of turning over profits to state authorities. In 1999, Jiang Zemin's administration continued reforms, including transforming SOEs into limited-liability companies and selling off small enterprises. The most notable recent change is that in 2012, Xi Jinping's regime mounted an anti-corruption campaign, which is still ongoing. Throughout the reform era, passage of legislation, notably the Accounting Law of 1985, the Enterprise Bankruptcy Law of 1986, the Enterprise Law of 1988, the Company Law of 1994, the Securities Law of 1999, and amendments to the Company and Securities Laws in 2005, gradually created a foundation for the rule of law. In addition, many changes in other economic institutions, most notably shifts in banks’ lending policies, were instituted to cope with different macroeconomic circumstances, such as the worldwide recession of 2008–2010. But there was great regional variation in the pace and nature of political-economic reforms. Such regional and temporal variation in political, legal, and social institutions requires nuanced treatment of which institutional logics guided business activities and how those logics evolved as societal institutions changed.

Second, future research should take into consideration the fact that the Chinese state is hierarchical, with multiple administrative levels that have different powers, with influence flowing both from the top to the bottom and from the bottom to the top. And, as outlined above, the extent of those powers has changed over time. The delegation of control over productive enterprises from the central state to local authorities in the 1990s and the transition from state redistribution over several decades transformed the logics associated with all state authorities, and thus their behavior, in four ways. First, the Chinese state became an embedded one (Evans, Reference Evans1995), as political and economic elites forged close social relations. For example, in 1989, entrepreneurs were allowed to join the Communist Party. As they did, entrepreneurs became more accepting of the Party's continued domination of political life (Dickson, Reference Dickson2003, Reference Dickson2008; Tsai, Reference Tsai2007). Other co-optive efforts have involved creating formal linkages between the Party and entrepreneurs in trade, professional, and industry associations (Kennedy, Reference Kennedy2005).

Second, the Chinese state became a developmental one (Evans, Reference Evans1995; Nee, Opper, & Wong, Reference Nee, Opper and Wong2007), as officials focused more and more on fostering economic development to achieve growth targets (Lin, Reference Lin2001b). The increasing importance of economic development was bolstered by changes in the reward system for bureaucrats: cadres’ career success became increasingly tied to economic growth (Naughton, Reference Naughton2007; Witt & Redding, Reference Witt and Redding2013). Then, starting in 1994, with the doctrine of ‘grasping the large and letting go of the small’ [zhuada fangxiao], the developmental state bifurcated, with central authorities promoting and tightly managing development in sectors deemed strategic, and local authorities (province-level and below) overseeing enterprises in other sectors.

Third, by launching and actively managing a wide array of state-owned business ventures, many local officials created an entrepreneurial state (Duckett, Reference Duckett1998; ten Brink, Reference ten Brink2011). The level of state entrepreneurship varied widely across locations and over time. Moreover, entrepreneurial officials in different locations focused on different economic sectors; for example, local officials in Yiwu supported a small-commodities market that became a behemoth, serving over 75,000 domestic firms exporting goods ranging from jewelry to luggage to holiday decorations to baby strollers to restaurant supplies, while those in Wuhan supported a robust manufacturing sector including automobiles, pharmaceuticals, and high-tech optical equipment. Fourth and finally, within the state bureaucracy, formal rules multiplied and personnel qualifications increased. To cope with new rules and meet new performance standards designed to increase effectiveness in policy implementation, officials cooperated with each other informally, but in highly institutionalized ways (Zhou, Reference Zhou2010).

All of these temporal shifts in the institutional logics guiding Chinese state agencies and officials, and the great regional differences (notably between coastal and inland provinces), merit consideration in studies of Chinese firms. For instance, entrepreneurial state officials might be expected to offer stronger support for technological innovation than traditional state officials. In contrast, state officials embedded in webs of social and economic relationships with business people might be more focused on private gain (that is, corruption). For their part, developmentally oriented state officials might be more likely to focus on profitability in general (rather than on innovation as the way to increase profits). The goals of and logics guiding the actions of these officials are likely to diverge in important ways, which may cause conflicts across levels of the state administrative hierarchy; for example, between entrepreneurial or embedded officials at the prefecture level and developmental officials at the provincial or central level. Such conflicts, which would have to be carefully managed by Chinese firms, merits investigation.

Finally, scholars could investigate other societal-level institutional logics that affect Chinese firms, beyond the state and market logics. The religious value sphere is perhaps the most interesting and potentially the most significant. China has always been shaped by religion (Goossaert & Palmer, Reference Goossaert and Palmer2011; Weber, Reference Weber1951), especially Confucianism, which centers on four key values: social harmony (respect for the social order and conflict-free social relations), the importance of the family, the importance of informal social relations [guanxi], and respect for hierarchy (father–son, teacher–student, ruler–ruled, friend–friend). A few studies have already shed light on the influence of Confucianism on organizations in China (e.g., Du, Reference Du2016; Ralston, Pounder, Lo, Wong, Egri, & Stauffer, Reference Ralston, Pounder, Lo, Wong, Egri and Stauffer2006), but more could be done. For example, the Confucian values of interpersonal trust and obligation [guanxi] are critical for doing business in China, which requires dynamic reciprocity and involvement in people's personal and social lives (Chen, Chen, & Huang, Reference Chen, Chen and Huang2013). Further evidence of religion's influence comes from the case of classical Chinese medicine, where entrepreneurial practitioners, keenly aware of the market allure of ‘tradition’ and ‘spirituality’ from Daoism, have crafted a niche amidst competition from bio-pharmaceutical companies run on Western medical principles (Zhan, Reference Zhan, Otsuki, Satsuka, Omura and Morita2018).

Another value sphere that is worth investigating is the family. The family logic is closely associated with Confucianism, which views the family as the basic organizing unit in society. This logic is hierarchical, with children expected to be subordinate to fathers. Trust among family members is deep and strong. The family trust circle begins with an inner circle consisting of extended family members. A second, slightly weaker, circle consists of proto-family, such as long-standing friends, key employees and business partners, and former schoolmates. A third, outermost and weakest, circle consists of people with whom family members have relationships of reciprocity, their guanxi connections. The family logic became increasingly important as economic reforms progressed: the number of family-owned Chinese firms rose dramatically, and family-owned and family-run firms came to account for a large fraction of economic output. Indeed, over 90% of privately owned small- and medium-sized enterprises in China are owned and controlled by families (Chen, Reference Chen2001; Redding & Witt, Reference Redding and Witt2007).

A small stream of work has already appeared on the family logic in Chinese firms. For example, small- or medium-sized Chinese firms controlled by a single family are more effective at translating R&D investments into innovations than are firms where multiple families vie for control (Deng, Hofman, & Newman, Reference Deng, Hofman and Newman2013). The reason is that in firms controlled by a single family, the interests of owners and senior managers (both members of the same family circle) are closely aligned. In sharp contrast, in firms controlled by two or more families, owners’ interests may conflict, reducing the flow of information among owners, which in turn may make it difficult for owners to monitor senior managers. Another paper described a family-focused ‘community’ logic in five firms operating in different industries and different locations (Han & Yao, Reference Han and Yao2022). This study revealed that historical imprinting (all firms studied were founded early in the Maoist period) and founders’ motives (to serve society, including workers, not just to earn profits) guided the development of subunits that focused on social services, such as recreation centers and schools for workers’ children.

Scholars could also take into consideration industry- and occupation-specific institutional logics, which reflect the histories of those industries and occupations. At the occupational level, Chinese lawyers (and the law firms for which they work) are subject to a changing institutional environment. Before reforms began, lawyers were state officials with clear allegiance to the government. ‘Unhooking and privatizing’ law firms and the legal profession began in 1988, and reforms throughout the 1990s formally severed ties between the profession and the state. In most parts of the world, lawyers are disinterested or non-partisan, focused on upholding ‘the rule of law’. But in China, despite ostensible privatization, lawyers are still deeply intertwined with the state, with the career success of individual lawyers and the performance of law firms both generally dependent, in part, on being embedded in webs of relationships with state officials (Michelson, Reference Michelson2007). These political ties safeguard lawyers and law firms against state obstructionism, harassment, and threats. Thus, lawyers working in the Chinese business sector actually operate in-between the market and state logics.

Conclusion

The many complex changes that China's political economy has experienced over the past five decades (and before) make it a fascinating site for research on the many different institutional logics that, in different times and locations, have guided business firms. Institutional logics are interrelated sets of cultural elements (norms, values, beliefs, symbols) that help people and organizations make sense of their everyday activities and order those activities in time and space. In particular, the gradual roll-out of economic reforms since the late 1970s has led to the decline of the old state logic, which valorizes equality, national community, and political stability, and rise of a new market logic, which encourages efficiency, competition, and property rights. But the state logic has not been fully eclipsed by the market logic; instead, the market logic, as it is manifested in China, has come to incorporate one key element of the state logic: it recognizes the central role that the state and the Communist Party continue to play in economic life. As a result, efficiency, competition, and property rights are tempered by a continued concern for political stability. In this, the Chinese market logic differs in a critical way from the one that prevails in Western capitalist economies.

In this paper, we first reviewed the literature on institutional logics as applied to organizations in Western capitalist economies. We followed this with a review and summary of the literature on institutional logics as it has been applied to organizations in China. Finally, we identified several avenues for future research on institutional logics and Chinese firms. We are confident that the study of institutional logics will continue to provide insights into how Chinese firms (and other organizations, like state bureaus and professional associations) operate.

Acknowledgement

We thank Haiyang Li and an anonymous reviewer for their helpful comments.

Heather A. Haveman () is a Professor of Sociology and Business at the University of California, Berkeley. She studies how organizations, industries, and employees’ careers evolve, and the impact of organizations on their employees and society. Her work has been published in Academy of Management Journal, Administrative Science Quarterly, American Journal of Sociology, American Sociological Review, and Management and Organization Review. She published The Power of Organizations: A New Approach to Organizational Theory in 2022.

David Joseph-Goteiner () is a PhD candidate in Sociology at University of California, Berkeley. He received his BA in American studies from Yale University, and an MA from l'École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales. His research interests include organizations, work and occupations, economic sociology, and the consequences of digital innovation on individuals and institutions. His dissertation examines why individuals are satisfied or dissatisfied with their work on digital labor platforms.

Danyang Li () is a PhD student in Sociology at University of California, Berkeley, with a Designated Emphasis in the Sociology of Organizations and Management. She is interested in organizational, cultural, and economic sociology, as well as computational linguistics.

Footnotes

1. To be clear, an industry is a set of organizations within some geographic area doing things similar to the focal organization, such as restaurants or internet-service providers. A field is the set of all organizations that are connected to the focal organization and its industry, including governmental agencies; professional, scientific, and trade associations; suppliers; customers; and potential employees (DiMaggio & Powell, Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983).

2. Because two of the three co-authors of this paper do not read Mandarin, we limit our discussion of research on Chinese firms to work published in English.

3. Some of the studies we discuss do not use the term ‘institutional logics’. Instead, they may discuss the values held by organizations or key decision-makers in organizations, or the policies that organizations (state bureaus or firms) enact. But organizational values are part and parcel of institutional logics, as we explained above, and organizational policies reflect institutional logics.

References

Ahmadjian, C. L., & Robbins, G. E. 2005. A clash of capitalisms: Foreign shareholders in 1990s Japan. American Sociological Review, 70(3): 451471.Google Scholar
Almandoz, J. 2014. Founding teams as carriers of competing logics: When institutional forces predict banks’ risk exposure. Administrative Science Quarterly, 59(3): 442473.Google Scholar
Alvarez, J. L., Mazza, C., Pedersen, J. S., & Svejenova, S. 2005. Shielding idiosyncrasy from isomorphic pressures: Towards optimal distinctiveness in European filmmaking. Organization, 12(6): 863888.Google Scholar
Besharov, M. L., & Smith, W. K. 2014. Multiple institutional logics in organizations: Explaining their varied nature and implications. Academy of Management Review, 39(3): 364381.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bian, Y. 1997. Bringing strong ties back in: Indirect ties, network bridges, and job searches in China. American Sociological Review, 62(3): 366385.Google Scholar
Chang, C.-Y. 2011. Creativity and Taoism: A study of Chinese philosophy, art, and poetry. London: Singing Dragon.Google Scholar
Che, J., & Qian, Y. 1998. Insecure property rights and government ownership of firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(2): 467496.Google Scholar
Chen, C. C., Chen, X.-P., & Huang, S. 2013. Chinese guanxi: An integrative review and new directions for future research. Management and Organization Review, 9(1): 167207.Google Scholar
Chen, M.-J. 2001. Inside Chinese business. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
Chen, X. 2020. The state-owned enterprise as an identity: The influence of institutional logics on guanxi behavior. Management and Organization Review, 16(3): 543568.Google Scholar
Clarke, D. C., Murrell, P., & Whiting, S. 2008. The role of law in China's economic development. In Rawski, T. & Brandt, L. (Eds.), China's great economic transition: 375428. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dalpiaz, E., Rindova, V., & Ravasi, D. 2016. Combining logics to transform organizational agency: Blending industry and art at Alessi. Administrative Science Quarterly, 61(3): 347392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Deng, Z., Hofman, P. S., & Newman, A. 2013. Ownership concentration and product innovation in Chinese private SMEs. Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 30(3): 717734.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dickson, B. J. 2003. Red capitalists in China: The party, private entrepreneurs, and prospects for political change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dickson, B. J. 2008. Wealth into power: The communist party's embrace of the private sector. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, P. 1997. Culture and cognition. Annual Review of Sociology, 23: 263287.Google Scholar
DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48(2): 147160.Google Scholar
Du, X. 2016. Does Confucianism reduce board gender diversity? Firm-level evidence from China. Journal of Business Ethics, 136(2): 399436.Google Scholar
Duckett, J. 1998. The entrepreneurial state in China: Real estate and commerce departments in reform era Tianjin. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Dunn, M. B., & Jones, C. 2010. Institutional logics and institutional pluralism: The contestation of care and science logics in medical education, 1967-2005. Administrative Science Quarterly, 55(1): 114149.Google Scholar
Dutton, J. E., & Dukerich, J. M. 1991. Keeping an eye on the mirror: Image and identity in organizational adaptation. Academy of Management Journal, 34(3): 517554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Economist Intelligence Unit. 2021. Democracy index 2020. London: Economist Intelligence Unit.Google Scholar
Evans, P. B. 1995. Embedded autonomy: States and industrial transformation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Fan, C. 2005. Of belts and ladders: State policy and uneven regional development in post-Mao China. Annals of the Association of American Geographers, 85(3): 421449.Google Scholar
Fei, X. 1948 [1992]. From the soil: The foundations of Chinese society. (Translated by Gary Hamilton and Wang Zhang. Originally published as Xiangtu Zhongguo.). Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Fligstein, N. 2001. The architecture of markets: An economic sociology of twenty-first-century capitalist societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Fligstein, N., & Goldstein, A. 2022. The legacy of shareholder value capitalism. Annual Review of Sociology, 48: 193211.Google Scholar
Fligstein, N., & Shin, T. 2004. The shareholder value society: A review of the changes in working conditions and inequality in the United States, 1976 to 2000. In Neckerman, K. (Ed.), Social inequality: 401432. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Press.Google Scholar
Friedland, R, & Alford, R. R. 1991. Bringing society back in: Symbols, practices, and institutional contradictions. In Powell, W. W., & DiMaggio, P. J. (Eds.), The New Institutionalism in Organizational Analysis: 232263. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Geertz, C. 1973. The interpretation of cultures. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Genin, A. L., Tan, J., & Song, J. 2021. State governance and technological innovation in emerging economies: State-owned enterprise restructuration and institutional logic dissonance in China's high-speed train sector. Journal of International Business Studies, 52(4): 621645.Google Scholar
Gioia, D. A., Patvardhan, S. D., Hamilton, A. L., & Corley, K. D. 2013. Organizational identity formation and change. Academy of Management Annals, 7(1): 123192.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goffman, E. 1974. Frame analysis: An essay on the organization of experience. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Goldstein, A. 2012. Revenge of the managers: Labor cost-cutting and the paradoxical resurgence of managerialism in the shareholder value era, 1984 to 2001. American Sociological Review, 77(2): 268294.Google Scholar
Goossaert, V., & Palmer, D. A. 2011. The religious question in modern China. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Greenwood, R., Díaz, A. M., Li, S. X., & Lorente, J. C. 2010. The multiplicity of institutional logics and the heterogeneity of organizational responses. Organization Science, 21(2): 521539.Google Scholar
Greve, H. R., & Zhang, C. M. 2017. Institutional logics and power sources: Merger and acquisition decisions. Academy of Management Journal, 60(2): 671694.Google Scholar
Guthrie, D. 2009. China and globalization: The social, economic, and political transformation of Chinese society, Revised Ed. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Han, Y., & Yao, J. 2022. Building organizations as communities: A multicase study of community institutional logic at Chinese firms. Management and Organization Review, 18(5): 829858.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Han, Y., Zheng, E., & Xu, M. 2014. The influence from the past: Organizational imprinting and firms’ compliance with social insurance policies in China. Journal of Business Ethics, 122(1): 6577.Google Scholar
Haveman, H. A., & Gualtieri, G. 2017. Institutional logics. In Aldag, R. (Ed.), Oxford research encyclopedia of business and management. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Haveman, H. A., & Rao, H. 1997. Structuring a theory of moral sentiments: Institutional and organizational coevolution in the early thrift industry. American Journal of Sociology, 102(6): 16061651.Google Scholar
Heurlin, C. 2016. Responsible authoritarianism in China: Land, protests, and policy making. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hsu, C. L. 2006. Market ventures, moral logics, and ambiguity: Crafting a new organizational form in post-socialist China. Sociological Quarterly, 47(1): 6992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hu, J. 2005. Zai sheng buji zhuyao lingdao ganbu tigao goujian shehui zhuyi hexie shehui nengli zhuanti yantaoban shang de jianghua (Speech at the special meeting of provincial cadres to discuss the construction of a socialist harmonious society). Renmin Ribao.Google Scholar
Hunzaker, M. B. F., & Valentino, L. 2019. Mapping cultural schemas: From theory to method. American Sociological Review, 84(5): 950981.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jay, J. 2012. Navigating paradox as a mechanism of change and innovation in hybrid organizations. Academy of Management Journal, 56(1): 137159.Google Scholar
Jia, N., Huang, K. G., & Zhang, C. M. 2019. Public governance, corporate governance, and firm innovation: An examination of state-owned enterprises. Academy of Management Journal, 62(1): 220247.Google Scholar
Jung, J. 2016. Through the contested terrain: Implementation of downsizing decisions by large U.S. firms, 1984 to 2005. American Sociological Review, 81(2): 347373.Google Scholar
Keister, L. A. 2000. Chinese business groups: The structure and impact of interfirm relations during economic development. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Keister, L. A., & Zhang, Y. 2009. Organizations and management in China. Academy of Management Annals, 3(1): 377420.Google Scholar
Kennedy, S. 2005. The Business of Lobbying in China. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kennedy, S. 2008. China's emerging credit rating industry: The official foundations of private authority. China Quarterly, 193: 6583.Google Scholar
Kroezen, J. J., & Heugens, P. P. M. A. R. 2019. What is dead may never die: Institutional regeneration through logic reemergence in Dutch brewing. Administrative Science Quarterly, 64(4): 9761019.Google Scholar
Lamont, M. 2012. Toward a comparative sociology of valuation and evaluation. Annual Review of Sociology, 38: 201221.Google Scholar
Lei, Y.-W. 2016. Freeing the press: How field environment explains critical news reporting in China. American Journal of Sociology, 122(1): 148.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lepoutre, J. M. W. N., & Valente, M. 2012. Fools breaking out: The role of symbolic and material immunity in explaining institutional nonconformity. Academy of Management Journal, 55(2): 285313.Google Scholar
Li, P. P. 2005. The puzzle of China's township-village enterprises: The paradox of local corporatism in a dual-track economic transition. Management and Organization Review, 1(2): 197224.Google Scholar
Lin, N. 2001a. Guanxi: A conceptual analysis. In So, A., Lin, N., & Poston, D. (Eds.), The Chinese triangle of Mainland China, Taiwan, and Hong Kong: 153166. Greenwood: Greenwich, CT.Google Scholar
Lin, Y.-M. 2001b. Between politics and markets: Firms, competition, and institutional change in post-Mao China. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Luo, X. R., Wang, D., & Zhang, J. 2017. Whose call to answer: Institutional complexity and firms’ CSR reporting. Academy of Management Journal, 60(1): 321344.Google Scholar
Marquis, C., & Bird, Y. 2018. The paradox of responsive authoritarianism: How civic activism spurs environmental penalties in China. Organization Science, 29(5): 948968.Google Scholar
Marquis, C., & Lounsbury, M. 2007. Vive la resistance: Consolidation and community-level professional counter-mobilization in US banking. Academy of Management Journal, 50(4): 799820.Google Scholar
Marquis, C., & Qiao, K. 2020. Waking from Mao's dream: Communist ideological imprinting and the internationalization of entrepreneurial ventures in China. Administrative Science Quarterly, 63(5): 795830.Google Scholar
Marquis, C., & Qiao, K. 2022. Mao and markets: The communist roots of Chinese enterprise. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McGregor, R. 2012. The party: The secret world of China's communist rulers. New York: Harper Perennials.Google Scholar
McPherson, C. M., & Sauder, M. 2013. Logics in action: Managing institutional complexity in a drug court. Administrative Science Quarterly, 58(2): 165196.Google Scholar
Michelson, E. 2007. Lawyers, political embeddedness, and institutional continuity in China's transition from socialism. American Journal of Sociology, 113(2): 352414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Naughton, B. 1995. Growing out of the plan: Chinese economic reform 1979–1993. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Naughton, B. 2007. The Chinese economy: Transitions and growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Naughton, B. 2018. The Chinese economy: Adaptation and growth, 2nd Ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Nee, V. 1992. Organizational dynamics of market transition: Hybrid forms, property rights, and mixed economy in China. Administrative Science Quarterly, 37(1): 127.Google Scholar
Nee, V., Opper, S., & Wong, S. 2007. Developmental state and corporate governance in China. Management and Organization Review, 3(1): 1953.Google Scholar
Oi, J. C. 1992. Fiscal reform and the economic foundations of local state corporatism. World Politics, 45(1): 99126.Google Scholar
Oi, J. C. 1999. Rural China takes off: Institutional foundations of economic reform. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Oi, J. C., & Walder, A. G. Eds. 1999. Property rights and economic reform in China. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Peng, M. W., & Luo, Y. 2000. Managerial ties and firm performance in a transition economy: The nature of a micro-macro link. Academy of Management Journal, 43(3): 486501.Google Scholar
Pettigrew, A. M. 1979. On studying organizational cultures. Administrative Science Quarterly, 24(4): 570581.Google Scholar
Ralston, D. A., Pounder, J., Lo, C. W. H., Wong, Y.-Y., Egri, C. P., & Stauffer, J. 2006. Stability and change in managerial work values: A longitudinal study of China, Hong Kong, and the US. Management and Organization Review, 2(1): 6794.Google Scholar
Rao, H., Monin, P., & Durand, R. 2003. Institutional change in Tocque Ville: Nouvelle cuisine as an identity movement in French gastronomy. American Journal of Sociology, 108(4): 795843.Google Scholar
Raynard, M., Lounsbury, M., & Greenwood, R. 2013. Legacies of logics: Sources of community variation in CSR implementation in China. In Lounsbury, M. & Boxenbaum, E. (Eds.), Research in the sociology of organizations: 243276. Leeds, UK: Emerald.Google Scholar
Raynard, M., Lu, F., & Jing, R. 2020. Reinventing the state-owned enterprise? Negotiating change during profound environmental upheaval. Academy of Management Journal, 63(4): 13001335.Google Scholar
Redding, G., & Witt, M. A. 2007. The future of Chinese capitalism: Choices and chances. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Schein, E. H. 1996. Culture: The missing concept in organization studies. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41(2): 229240.Google Scholar
Schneiberg, M. 2013. Lost in transposition? (A cautionary tale): The bank of North Dakota and prospects for reform in American banking. Research in the Sociology of Organizations, 39A: 277310.Google Scholar
Schneider, D., & Harknett, K. 2019. Consequences of routine work-schedule instability for worker health and well-being. American Sociological Review, 84(1): 82114.Google Scholar
Scott, W. R., Ruef, M., Mendel, P. J., & Caronna, C. A. 2000. Institutional change and healthcare organizations: From professional dominance to managed care. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Selznick, P. 1957. Leadership in administration: A sociological interpretation. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Shih, V. C. 2008. Factions and finance in China: Elite conflict and inflation. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
ten Brink, T. 2011. Institutional change in market-liberal state capitalism: An integrative perspective on the development of the private business sector in China. Working Paper, Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies.Google Scholar
Thornton, P. H., & Ocasio, W. 1999. Institutional logics and the historical contingency of power in organizations: Executive succession in the higher education publishing industry, 1958 to 1990. American Journal of Sociology, 105(3): 801843.Google Scholar
Thornton, P. H., Ocasio, W., & Lounsbury, M. 2012. The institutional logics perspective: A new approach to culture, structure and process. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Townley, B. 2002. The role of competing rationalities in institutional change. Academy of Management Journal, 45(1): 163179.Google Scholar
Tsai, K. S. 2007. Capitalism without democracy: The private sector in contemporary China. Ithaca, NY, and London: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Valentino, L. 2021. Cultural logics: Toward theory and measurement. Poetics, 88: 101574.Google Scholar
Walder, A. G. 1989. Social change in post-revolution China. Annual Review of Sociology, 15: 405424.Google Scholar
Wang, D., Du, F., & Marquis, C. 2019. Defending Mao's dream: How politicians’ ideological imprinting affects firms’ political appointment in China. Academy of Management Journal, 62(4): 11111136.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1904–05 [1958]. The protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism. (Translated by Talcott Parsons.). New York: Charles Scribners’ Sons.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1951. The religion of China: Confucianism and Taoism. (Translated and edited by Hans H. Gerth.). Glencoe, IL: Free Press.Google Scholar
Weber, M. 1978. Economy and society: An outline of interpretive sociology (Translated and edited by Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich). Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Weick, K. E. 1995. Sensemaking in organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
Whetten, D. A. 2006. Strengthening the concept of organizational identity. Journal of Management Inquiry, 15(3): 219234.Google Scholar
Witt, M. A., & Redding, G. 2013. Asian business systems: Institutional comparison, clusters, and implications for varieties of capitalism and business systems theory. Socio-Economic Review, 11(2): 265300.Google Scholar
Xi, J. 2021. Caixin Global. Full text of Xi Jinping's speech on boosting common prosperity. Available from URL: https://www.caixinglobal.com/2021-10-19/full-text-xi-jinpings-speech-on-boosting-common-prosperity-101788302.htmlGoogle Scholar
Xu, D., Lu, J. W., & Gu, Q. 2014. Organizational forms and multi-population dynamics: Economic transition in China. Administrative Science Quarterly, 59(3): 517547.Google Scholar
Yang, D. 2005. Remaking the Chinese Leviathan: Market transition and the politics of Governance in China. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Yiu, D. W., Hoskisson, R. E., Bruton, G. D., & Lu, Y. 2014. Dueling institutional logics and the effect on strategic entrepreneurship in Chinese business groups. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal, 8(3): 195213.Google Scholar
Yue, L. Q., Wang, J., & Yang, B. 2019. Contesting commercialization: Political influence, responsive authoritarianism, and cultural resistance. Administrative Science Quarterly, 62(4): 435465.Google Scholar
Zhan, M. 2018. Out of nothing: (Re)worlding ‘theory’ through Chinese medical entrepreneurship. In Otsuki, G. J., Satsuka, S., Omura, K., & Morita, A. (Eds.), The world multiple: The quotidian politics of knowing and generating entangled worlds: 175189. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Zhou, K. Z., Gao, G. Y., & Zhao, H. 2017. State ownership and firm innovation in China: An integrated view of institutional and efficiency logics. Administrative Science Quarterly, 62(2): 375404.Google Scholar
Zhou, X. 2010. The institutional logic of collusion among local governments in China. Modern China, 36(1): 4778.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Comparing thrift logics

Figure 1

Table 2. Dominant institutional logics in China: State and market

Figure 2

Table 3. Typology of Chinese ownership forms

Figure 3

Table 4. Summary of empirical research on institutional logics in Chinese organizations