Hostname: page-component-8448b6f56d-c4f8m Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-16T22:44:38.685Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Public Goods, Common Pool Resources, and International Law

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 September 2017

J. Samuel Barkin
Affiliation:
Professor, University of Massachusetts Boston, Department of Conflict Resolution, Human Security, and Global Governance.
Yuliya Rashchupkina
Affiliation:
PhD Candidate, University of Massachusetts Boston, Department of Conflict Resolution, Human Security, and Global Governance.

Abstract

The concept of public goods is often operationalized in the literature as anything that demands some form of international cooperation. While this may be politically useful in generating international cooperation, it is analytically problematic for designing international law with the purpose of enhancing international cooperation. Many of the issues characterized as public goods are in fact common pool resources, which pose distinct issues for international cooperation and demand different legal architectures than public goods for effective international cooperation.

Type
Notes and Comments
Copyright
Copyright © 2017 by The American Society of International Law 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Cafaggi, Fabrizio & Caron, David D., Global Public Goods Amidst a Plurality of Legal Orders: A Symposium, 23 Eur. J. Int'l L. 643, 643 (2012)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

2 See, e.g., Global Public Goods: International Cooperation in the 21st Century (Kaul, Inge, Grunberg, Isabelle & Stern, Marc A. eds., 1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

3 Bodansky, Daniel, What's in a Concept? Global Public Goods, International Law, and Legitimacy, 23 Eur. J. Int'l L. 651 (2012)Google Scholar; Shaffer, Gregory, International Law and Global Public Goods in a Legal Pluralist World, 23 Eur. J. Int'l L. 669 (2012)Google Scholar; Cafaggi, Fabrizio, Transnational Private Regulation and the Production of Global Public Goods and Private ‘Bads,’ 23 Eur. J. Int'l L. 695 (2012)Google Scholar.

4 Rajshri Jayaraman & Ravi Kanbur, International Public Goods and the Case for Foreign Aid, in Global Public Goods, supra note 2, at 450; Arce, Daniel G. & Sandler, Todd, Transnational Public Goods: Strategies and Institutions, 17 Eur. J. Pol. Econ. 493 (2001)Google Scholar; International Public Goods: Incentives, Measurement, and Financing (Ferroni, Marco & Mody, Ashoka eds., 2002)Google Scholar.

5 Bodansky, supra note 3

6 Krisch, Nico, The Decay of Consent: International Law in an Age of Global Public Goods, 108 AJIL 1 (2014)Google Scholar. See also Guzman, Andrew T., Against Consent, 52 Va. J. Int'l L. 747 (2012)Google Scholar.

7 Petersmann, Ernst-Ulrich, International Economic Law, ‘Public Reason,’ and Multilevel Governance of Interdependent Public Goods, 14 J. Int'l Econ. L. 23 (2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

8 Walker, Neil, Human Rights and Global Public Goods: The Sound of One Hand Clapping, 23 Indiana J. Glob. Legal Stud. 249 (2016)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

9 Cafaggi & Caron, supra note 1, at 644.

10 Samuelson, Paul A., The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure, 36(4) Rev. Econ. & Stat. 387 (1954)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

11 Mancur Olson, The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups (1965); Ostrom, Vincent & Ostrom, Elinor, Public Goods and Public Choices, in Polycentricity and Local Public Economies 75 (McGinnis, Michael D. ed., 1977)Google Scholar.

12 The United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea, opened for signature Dec. 10, 1982, 1833 UNTS 397.

13 See, e.g., Voluntary Programs: A Club Theory Perspective (Potoski, Matthew & Prakash, Aseem eds., 2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

14 Richard Cornes & Todd Sandler, The Theory of Externalities, Public Goods, and Club Goods (2d ed. 1996).

15 Cafaggi, supra note 3, at 706.

16 Fikret Berkes, Common-Property Resources: Ecology and Community-Based Sustainable Development (1989).

17 Cafaggi, supra note 3.

18 Scott Barrett, Why Cooperate? The Incentive to Supply Global Public Goods (2007).

19 Thomas C. Schelling, Micromotives and Macrobehavior 218–23 (2006); Snidal, Duncan, The Limits of Hegemonic Stability Theory, 39 Int'l Org. 579 (1985)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

20 Barrett, supra note 18.

21 Anarchy and the Environment: The International Relations of Common Pool Resources (Barkin, J. Samuel & Shambaugh, George E. eds., 1999)Google Scholar.

22 DeSombre, Elizabeth R., The Experience of the Montreal Protocol: Particularly Remarkable, and Remarkably Particular, 19 UCLA J. Envtl. L. & Pol'y 49 (2000)Google Scholar.

23 Barkin, J. Samuel & Shambaugh, George E., Common Pool Resources and International Environmental Politics, 5 Envtl. Pol. 429, 434 (1996)Google Scholar.

24 Anarchy and the Environment, supra note 21.

25 Larson, Bruce A. & Bromley, Daniel W., Property Rights, Externalities, and Resource Degradation: Locating the Tragedy, 33 J. Dev. Econ. 235 (1990)Google Scholar; Coase, Ronald H., The Problem of Social Cost, 3 J. L. & Econ. 1 (1960)Google Scholar; Alchian, Armen A. & Demsetz, Harold, The Property Rights Paradigm, 33 J. Econ. Hist. 16 (1973)Google Scholar.

26 Convention on Wetlands of International Importance Especially as Waterfowl Habitat (The Ramsar Convention), Feb. 2, 1971, TIAS No. 11084, 996 UNTS 245; The Convention on International Trade in Endangered Species of Wild Fauna and Flora, Mar. 3, 1973, 993 UNTS 243, 12 ILM 1085.

27 See, e.g., Elizabeth R. DeSombre, Flagging Standards: Globalization and Environmental, Safety, and Labor Regulations at Sea (2006).

28 Id.; see also DeSombre, Elizabeth R., Fishing Under Flags of Convenience: Using Market Power to Increase Participation in International Regulation, 5 Glob. Envtl. Pol. 73 (2005)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

29 See, e.g., Krasner, Stephen D., Global Communications and National Power: Life on the Pareto Frontier, 43 World Pol. 336 (1991)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

30 See, e.g., Francioni, Francesco, Public and Private in the International Protection of Global Cultural Goods, 23 Eur. J. Int'l L. 719 (2012)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

31 Barkin, J. Samuel, Time Horizons and Multilateral Enforcement in International Cooperation, 48 Int'l Stud. Q. 363 (2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

32 Snidal, Duncan, Coordination Versus Prisoners’ Dilemma: Implications for International Cooperation and Regimes, 79 Am. Pol. Sci. Rev. 923 (1985)Google Scholar; Olson, supra note 11; Kindleberger, Charles P., Dominance and Leadership in the International Economy: Exploitation, Public Goods, and Free Rides, 25 Int'l Stud. Q. 242 (1981)Google Scholar.

33 Barkin, supra note 31.

34 Id.

35 See, e.g., Gowa, Joanne, Rational Hegemons, Excludable Goods, and Small Groups: An Epitaph for Hegemonic Stability Theory?, 41 World Pol. 307 (1989)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

36 Österblom, Henrik & Sumaila, Ussif Rashid, Toothfish Crises, Actor Diversity and the Emergence of Compliance Mechanisms in the Southern Ocean, 21 Glob. Envtl. Change 972 (2011)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

37 Schlager, Edella & Ostrom, Elinor, Property-Rights Regimes and Natural Resources: A Conceptual Analysis, 68 Land Econ. 249 (1992)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

38 McKean, Margaret A., Common Property: What Is It, What Is It Good For, and What Makes It Work?, in People and Forests: Communities, Institutions, and Governance 27 (Gibson, Clark C., McKean, Margaret A. & Ostrom, Elinor eds., 2000)Google Scholar; Dunoff, Jeffrey L., Reconciling International Trade with Preservation of the Global Commons: Can We Prosper and Protect?, 49 Wash. & Lee L. Rev. 1407 (1992)Google Scholar.

39 Anarchy and the Environment, supra note 21.

40 Sanchirico, James N. & Wilen, James E., Global Marine Fisheries Resources: Status and Prospects, 7 Int'l J. Glob. Envtl. Issues 106 (2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

41 Bailey, Jennifer L., States, Stocks, and Sovereignty: High Seas Fishing and the Expansion of State Sovereignty, in Conflict and the Environment 215 (Gleditsch, Nils Petter ed., 1997)CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dunoff, supra note 38.

42 See, e.g., J. Samuel Barkin & Elizabeth R. DeSombre, Saving Global Fisheries: Reducing Fishing Capacity to Promote Sustainability (2013).

43 Gowa, supra note 35.

44 Daniel W. Drezner, All Politics Is Global: Explaining International Regulatory Regimes 142 (2007).

45 Haufler, Virginia, The Kimberley Process Certification Scheme: An Innovation in Global Governance and Conflict Prevention, 89 J. Bus. Ethics 403, 404 (2009)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

46 DeSombre, supra note 27.

47 Bodansky, supra note 3.

48 Coase, supra note 25; Buchanan, James M. & Stubblebine, W. Craig, Externality, 29 Economica 371 (1962)Google Scholar; Davis, Otto A. & Whinston, Andrew B., Some Notes on Equating Private and Social Cost, 32 S. Econ. J. 113 (1965)Google Scholar; Wellisz, Stanislaw, On External Diseconomies and the Government-Assisted Invisible Hand, 31 Economica 345 (1964)Google Scholar.

49 Wijkman, Per Magnus, Managing the Global Commons, 36 Int'l Org. 511 (1982)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

50 Paavola, Jouni, Institutions and Environmental Governance: A Reconceptualization, 63 Ecological Econ. 93 (2007)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

51 McKean, supra note 38.

52 Bodansky, supra note 3.

53 Cornes & Sandler, supra note 14; Buchanan, James M., An Economic Theory of Clubs, 32 Economica 1 (1965)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

54 Cornes & Sandler, supra note 14.

55 See, e.g., Lloyd Gruber, Ruling the World: Power Politics and the Rise of Supranational Institutions (2000).

56 Stone, Christopher D., Common but Differentiated Responsibilities in International Law, 98 AJIL 276 (2004)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

57 Brunnée, Jutta & Streck, Charlotte, The UNFCCC as a Negotiation Forum: Towards Common but More Differentiated Responsibilities, 13 Climate Pol'y 589, 590 (2013)Google Scholar.

58 Barkin & DeSombre, supra note 42.

59 Bodansky, supra note 3; Bernstein, Steven, Legitimacy in Global Environmental Governance, 1 J. Int'l L & Int'l Rel. 139 (2004)Google Scholar.

60 Rogoff, Kenneth, International Institutions for Reducing Global Financial Instability, 13 J. Econ. Persp. 21 (1999)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.

61 John Rawls, A Theory of Justice (1971).

62 Cafaggi & Caron, supra note 1, at 645.

63 Bodansky, supra note 3, at 665.

64 Boyd, Philip W., Ranking Geo-engineering Schemes, 1 Nature Geoscience 722 (2008)Google Scholar; Victor, David G., Morgan, M. Granger, Apt, Jay, Steinbruner, John & Ricke, Katharine, The Geoengineering Option: A Last Resort Against Global Warming?, 88 Foreign Aff. 64 (2009)Google Scholar.

65 Corner, Adam & Pidgeon, Nick, Geoengineering the Climate: The Social and Ethical Implications, 52 Env't 24 (2010)Google Scholar.

66 Shaffer, supra note 3, at 687.

67 Lloyd, Ian & Oppenheimer, Michael, On the Design of an International Governance Framework for Geoengineering, 14 Glob. Envtl. Pol. 45 (2014)CrossRefGoogle Scholar.