Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-75dct Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-06-01T20:28:16.227Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Fiscal Transfers between Buenos Aires and the Viceregal Interior at the End of the Colonial Period: Fall of the Situado and the Relation with the Regional Royal Treasuries (1800–1810)

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 December 2023

Antonio Galarza*
Affiliation:
CONICET, INHUS/Universidad Nacional de Mar del Plata, Buenos Aires, Argentina
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

This study reconstructs remittances from different regional haciendas to the main treasury of the Viceroyalty of the Río de la Plata, located in Buenos Aires, between 1800 and 1810. It estimates the extent and periodization of the decline of the situado of Potosí during the last colonial decade, determining whether the contributions from regional treasuries made up for it. It also estimates the impact of transfers on the regional treasuries. By drawing on the accounting books of various treasuries, the article identifies the main mechanisms that the Royal Treasury of Buenos Aires implemented to seize surplus resources of the viceroyalty’s interior haciendas at the end of the colonial period. The ability of the Royal Treasury to seize those surpluses was significant and implemented through various mechanisms of the ancien régime.

Resumen

Resumen

La investigación reconstruye las remesas enviadas desde las distintas haciendas regionales a la tesorería mayor del Virreinato del Río de la Plata, ubicada en Buenos Aires, entre 1800 y 1810. Estima la extensión y periodización de la caída del “situado” de Potosí durante la última década colonial, determinando si los aportes de las haciendas regionales lo compensaron. También se estima el impacto de estas transferencias en las haciendas regionales. A partir de los libros de contabilidad de las distintas tesorerías, se identifican los principales mecanismos implementados por la Real Hacienda de Buenos Aires para captar los recursos excedentes de las haciendas interiores del Virreinato a fines del período colonial. Se concluye que la capacidad de la Real Hacienda de Buenos Aires para hacerse de los excedentes de las haciendas del interior fue significativa y se implementó a través de diversos mecanismos propios de una administración de antiguo régimen.

Type
New Perspectives in Historical Studies
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution and reproduction, provided the original article is properly cited.
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Latin American Studies Association

At the beginning of the nineteenth century, the Spanish monarchy was in a secular crisis characterized by two principal issues: the imperial wars and the expenses required to cope with them. Since the Seven Years’ War (1756–1763), the empire had prioritized its finances and found in the Spanish-American territories a place to implement the Bourbon reforms until the end of the century in order to improve the empire’s institutional and fiscal performance.

During the first decade of the 1800s, the urgency of these issues increased, powered by the troubled European monarchies’ relationships, which brought changed imperial alignments, with important consequences for America. In just a few years, Spain went from engaging in naval wars against Great Britain and frontier conflicts with Portugal (1796–1802) to plunging into a deep imperial crisis unleashed by the French invasion of 1808. These events had a powerful impact on Hispanic America, especially the Río de la Plata region. The region became isolated from the metropolis in 1803 with the supremacy of the Royal Navy. However, the viceregal capital successfully resisted English invasions in 1806 and 1807, financing instead through its own South American resources (military and fiscal). This experience gave way to a convulsive revolutionary process, accelerated by the monarchic crisis caused by the Napoleonic invasion and the subsequent fall of the Junta de Sevilla. This revolutionary process began in May 1810 and culminated in the independence of the United Provinces in 1816.

On October 16, 1802, the viceroys of New Spain, Lima, and Buenos Aires were notified of the serious situation of the monarchy’s finances because of the war. They were instructed to make “the greatest efforts to remit money” to the peninsula. Footnote 1 A reserved order with the same message was sent to similar recipients on January 17, 1804. Fiscal emergencies were not new to the Spanish monarchy, but they intensified during that decade in America and would only increase over the years. I demonstrate how, until the empire entered its final crisis, the main treasury of the Viceroyalty of Río de la Plata employed various mechanisms typical of an old regime tax administration to obtain fiscal resources from the treasuries of the viceregal interior.

Until a few decades ago, part of the historiography dedicated to colonial tax studies emphasized the extractive and predatory nature of the Spanish tax system in America. According to this perspective, this character of the system was pronounced at the end of the eighteenth and beginning of the nineteenth century, given the Crown’s urgent fiscal and military needs. Studies of economic divergence in the United States and Latin America emphasize the image of a voracious Bourbon treasury in contrast to the British Crown, with its representative institutions that limit the king’s discretion over political economy. Thus, a balanced British tax system would have been constructed to make economic development possible in the long term (North Reference North1990; North, Weingast, and Summerhill Reference North, Weingast, Summerhill, Mesquita and Root2000; Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson Reference Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson2001). The differences in these trajectories would only deepen in the heat of the imperial crisis, as the Spanish-American countries inherited a fiscal voracity based on a tradition of absolutist power and high institutional transaction costs for business that hindered economic development over the long run.

Current historiography has widely discussed views on the taxation of the Spanish Empire in America based on research that considers the negotiated nature of the American tax system between the monarchy and local elites. Researchers in the 1980s argued that the mere extraction of fiscal resources was a rather limited benefit of colonialism for the Spanish Empire (Klein and Barbier Reference Klein and Barbier1988).Footnote 2 More recently, studies of Hispanic American imperial taxation have stressed the redistributive character of the imperial fiscal system, which favored reducing costs for maintenance of the American colonies.Footnote 3 Before sending remittances to Spain, it was more important that the Crown reallocate resources between different regions in Latin American colonies (and the Philippines) to secure imperial borders and maintain social order.Footnote 4 This perspective emphasizes the necessary participation and benefit of Latin American elites in the management and distribution of fiscal resources (in the management of the so-called colonial situado, a transfer of fiscal resources from surplus treasuries to other royal treasuries), thus demonstrating the wide margins of action with which American oligarchies participated in the imperial treasury (Irigoin and Grafe Reference Irigoin and Grafe2006, Reference Irigoin, Grafe, Coffman, Leonard and Neal2013).

Thus, scholars have revised the dominant image of the monarchy and its tax system, which was based on negotiations between different powers to collect taxes, execute expenditures, and transfer resources from one region to another. This new image does not represent the Spanish Crown as an unopposed depredator of fiscal resources. Instead, it underlines the jurisdictional functioning of the imperial treasury and the difficulties for the Crown, even under the Bourbons, to centralize decisions and tax resources on both sides of the Atlantic with the resistance and autonomous institutional spaces of the Hispanic American elites and royal treasury officers.Footnote 5

However, from this perspective, a discussion topic revolves around the Crown’s negotiations and its incapacity to fiscally centralize. Recent historiography considers the negotiated government with local Spanish-American elites the necessary counterbalance for allowing the fiscal system to function, given limitations on the king’s discretion in managing finances (Irigoin and Grafe Reference Irigoin and Grafe2006; Grieco Reference Grieco2018). In contrast, the perspective associated with the neo-institutional model of Douglas North (Reference North1990) is that negotiations between the Spanish Crown and its subjects had negative effects. This perspective especially underlines the heterogeneous, noninstitutionalized, and corporate characteristics of fiscal negotiation that resulted in the monarchy’s incapacity for fiscal centralization, thus increasing financing costs and opening up opportunities to the king’s discretion, above all in taking out loans (Summerhill Reference Summerhill2008; Bohorquez Reference Bohorquez2022).

This research is inserted into the context of these studies to identify the capacity of the Royal Treasury of the Viceroyalty of the Río de la Plata to collect surpluses from the regional treasuries in its jurisdiction beyond the situado of Potosí. Because the imperial treasury was constituted as a jurisdictional treasury of the old regime, the article presents an analysis of mechanisms of this type of system that allowed the Royal Treasury of Buenos Aires to attract surplus funds from the regional haciendas of the viceregal interior. Although historiography has identified the different resources that served to offset the fall of the situado of Potosí from the perspective of the Buenos Aires treasury (Halperín Donghi Reference Halperín Donghi1982; Grieco Reference Grieco2018; Amaral Reference Amaral2014; Kraselsky Reference Kraselsky2016; Wasserman Reference Wasserman2017), I examine and reconstruct the extent to which transfers to the capital affected the main treasuries of the interior in relation to their incomes.

Next, I present some commentaries on the accounting books with respect to their importance as documents of the reconstruction of colonial accounting. I then analyze the volumes of the situado received in Buenos Aires from Alto Perú between 1780 and 1810. Finally, I examine the contributions of the interior haciendas and the mechanisms through which it sent funds to the capital during the last colonial decade (1800–1810).

The use of accountability documents and their possibilities

Like any language, the language of the accountant has its own peculiarities. TePaske and Klein (Reference TePaske and Klein1982–1990) researched the structure of all the royal treasuries of the Spanish fiscal system in America. Based on the documentation known as cartas-cuentas, this monumental examination rebuilt the incomes and expenses of each treasury, but with the accounting summaries’ own limitations, an issue that has generated many discussions among economic historians about the reliability of the information contained in these sources (Klein Reference Klein1984; Amaral Reference Amaral1984; Sánchez Santiró Reference Sánchez Santiró2015).Footnote 6 Although the studies based on these documents were very valuable in terms of showing general trends in tax collection, they were limited in their ability to appreciate the values of transfers between royal treasuries, in part given the particularities of the colonial accounting language of double and simple entry.Footnote 7 In this way, the possibility of estimating and characterizing aspects like transferred volume of resources, links between different treasuries and fiscal jurisdictions, and capacity of the principal royal treasuries to channel the regional surplus, among other questions, becomes problematic if working only with the database of Klein or the same sources. Precisely because many transfers between treasuries were recorded as entries and exits in each ramo, transactions can be identified only by examining the ledger and manual books together. For this reason, new works have retraced the reconstruction of the operation of ramos, the income and expenses of different treasuries, and special rents from accounting books, demonstrating the potential of such sources to estimate fiscal collections and transfers between treasuries and to engage in dialogue with other research on economic circuits and contribute to reconstructing regional economic performance (Wayar Reference Wayar2011; Sánchez Santiró Reference Sánchez Santiró2015, Reference Sánchez Santiró2016; Pinto Bernal Reference Pinto Bernal2015; Biangardi Reference Biangardi2016; Wasserman Reference Wasserman2017; Galarza Reference Galarza2019a, Reference Galarza2019b). All the values reconstructed here are based on fiscal primary documentation (major and manual books) to improve the precision in estimates of the different figures (e.g., tax collection, transfers).

The Royal Treasury of Buenos Aires and the arrivals of the situado of Potosí

In South America, the situado of Potosí is the case that has received the most attention, given the importance of silver production to Potosí and the impact of the injection of related resources on the taxation and economy of Buenos Aires (Klein Reference Klein1973; Halperín Donghi Reference Halperín Donghi1982; Mira and Gil Lázaro Reference Mira, Gil Lázaro, Irigoin and Schmit2003; Cuesta Reference Cuesta2009; Wasserman Reference Wasserman2017). Studies underline the increasing flow of money to Buenos Aires from this situado after 1776 and until 1805, which then declined and finally disappeared between 1811 and 1813. In “Guerra y finanzas,” Halperín Donghi (Reference Halperín Donghi1982) identified a significant decrease in the volume of the situado potosino collected at the principal treasury of the viceroyalty, particularly between 1801 and 1810, and it had already started to decrease in previous years. Other research has confirmed this downward trend and tried to understand the reasons for the decline. Mira and Gil Lázaro (Reference Mira, Gil Lázaro, Irigoin and Schmit2003, 52) retrieve data prepared by TePaske and Klein (Reference TePaske and Klein1982–1990) from sources known as cartas-cuentas to assert a decreasing evolution in shipments of situado during the same period. The authors attribute the fall in shipments to a combination of an extended drought and a shortage of both mercury and workers in Potosí between December 1801 and May 1805, which hindered silver production. Footnote 8 Klein estimates that this decline spanned the entire eighteenth century, until 1809, with a brief rebound during the 1780s. Unlike Mira and Gil Lázaro, Klein (Reference Klein1998, 60) identifies the causes of the deterioration of Potosí silver production post-1780 as the influence of the European wars on trade and mercury supply.

However, along with the dropping income on behalf of the situado, the Buenos Aires treasury also stopped sending large money transfers to the metropolis. As Halperín’s research shows, the shipments to Spain declined from $8.6 million pesos between 1791 and 1805 to $162.000 pesos (in “hard silver”) between 1806 and 1810. In addition to this, and a point relevant to this research, the documentation studied by Halperín shows another offset to the arrival of lower volumes of situado: the increase of transfers from other treasuries in the interior of the viceroyalty of the Río de la Plata, especially during 1806 to 1810. In fact, Halperín’s examination of the major books allows him to claim that the volume of funds contributed by the regional treasuries went from 151.762 pesos between 1801 and 1805 to 692.217 during the last five years of the colonial period, 1806–1810. The problem with the information thus presented is that the five-year organization makes it difficult to estimate the evolution of volume year by year (or by fiscal exercise). A major difficulty is identifying the origin of fiscal contributions from the different interior regions. As I demonstrate later, these values can be adjusted and corrected by consulting the accounting books of the different treasuries.

I reexamined the values of situado incomes at the Buenos Aires treasury between 1780 and 1810 to identify the ups and downs of the transfers. On the basis of the accounting books of the Real Hacienda of Buenos Aires, I adjusted the numbers of the situado—until now, estimated from cartas-cuentas by most other historians, except for Amaral (Reference Amaral2014). Footnote 9

From a review of the accounting ledgers, I have identified the itinerary followed by the values entered on behalf of the situado potosino in Buenos Aires between 1780 and 1810. Constantly fluctuating, the 1790s presented an increase in the values entered in the Caja de Buenos Aires via Potosí (a secular trend, according to other historians) to show a clear decline in the volumes registered during the first decade of the nineteenth century.

As identified in Table 1, during the final years of the eighteenth century, the million pesos constituted a floor for the values of the situado; during the following decade, it became a ceiling. More importantly, for the purposes of this article, the fall began in 1801, when the amount declined from more than 2 million pesos to 1.1 million; it continued to fall until 1806. However, these numbers can be adjusted further, especially for income during 1806 and 1807. My research into the contributions of the treasuries of the interior to the viceregal capital allows me to establish that, in 1807, a large volume of funds was deposited in the Caja of Buenos Aires through promissory notes of individuals to be paid in the treasury of Córdoba (something similar happened in 1806). As I demonstrate, these funds were, in fact, part of the situado of Potosí that arrived in Córdoba, but the Royal Treasury of Buenos Aires managed to use them by libranzas.Footnote 10

Table 1. Incomes by situado according to accounting books of Buenos Aires treasury

Note: All values in tables are in silver pesos, each peso equivalent to ocho reales

Source: Accounting books of Buenos Aires royal treasury. Archivo General de la Nación, Sala XIII, Buenos Aires Royal treasury, major books 43-5-12(1780); 43-4-15(1781); 43-6-1(1782); 43-6-4(1783); 43-6-5(1784), 43-6-11(1785); 43-6-19(1786); 44-1-5(1787); 44-1-10(1788); 44-1-15(1789); 44-1-19(1790); 44-2-1(1791); 44-2-5(1792); 44-2-9(1793); 44-2-12(1794); 44-3-1(1795); 44-3-5(1796); 44-3-8(1797); 44-3-10(1798); 44-3-13(1799); 44-4-3 (1800); 44-4-4(1801); 44-4-8(1802); 44-4-11(1803); 44-4-15(1804); 44-4-19(1805); 44-5-7(1806); 44-5-14(1806); 44-5-18(1807); 44-5-21(1808); 44-5-26(1809); and Sala III, 39-3-3 (1810).

In 1807, about 561.000 pesos were entered into the ramo “Real hacienda en común” of the Buenos Aires treasury to be paid to third parties in the treasury of Córdoba. How did the Córdoba treasury cope with these commitments? The examination of the ledgers and accounting manuals of the two treasuries (Córdoba and Buenos Aires) allows us to reconstruct the payment circuit. By order of the viceroy, the Caja of Córdoba took a total of 193.000 pesos from the situado of Potosí led by the situadistas (which passed through Córdoba on its way from Alto Perú; Figure 1) on January 31 and August 22, 1807. In February 1807, 95.000 pesos in silver bars were transferred from Buenos Aires to Córdoba, likely part of the situado received the last year in the capital and spent on payments for money deposited in Buenos Aires during 1807. This amounts to a total of 288.000 pesos of the situado that the Córdoba treasury managed to collect to meet the commitments assumed in Buenos Aires. This implies that the funds from the situado managed by the viceroy treasury in 1807 were more than those registered in the Caja of Buenos Aires. Instead of the 1.078.169 pesos that historians have assumed, the total of the situado managed by the Real Hacienda’s treasury amounted to 1.272.051 pesos that year, including the resources brought to Córdoba.

Figure 1. Path of conductors of trade flows from Potosí to Buenos Aires. Map by Javier Kraselsky, based on a map found in the Archivo General de la Nación, Written Documents Department, map library IV-168. See Kraselsky (Reference Kraselsky2016, 224). I appreciate the author’s generosity in facilitating use of the map.

The management of part of the situado from Córdoba was not new; with the first English invasions of 1806, Viceroy Sobremonte settled in Córdoba and tried to establish his base of operations and the viceregal capital. On July 29 and September 29, 1806, part of the situado was given to the Córdoba treasury, which was in charge of its transfer to other haciendas (97.221 and 1.269.302 pesos, respectively). Part went to Montevideo for war and reconquest expenses (97.221 in gold ounces), and another part would be transferred to Santa Fe (16.000 pesos dobles) and Mendoza (10.000 pesos dobles).Footnote 11 Still, the bulk would be forwarded through cash carriers (situadistas) to Buenos Aires (950.000) for use in payments made by the Royal Treasury in Córdoba (for the viceroy’s salary and the soldiers and Cordovan militiamen destined to reconquer Buenos Aires).Footnote 12 The total contributed by Potosí to the viceregal treasury in 1806 amounted to 1.366.523.Footnote 13 The new estimated values of the situado corresponding to 1806 and 1807 are included in Table 2.

Table 2. Incomes by situado in Buenos Aires according to authors 1801–1810

Source: Amaral (Reference Amaral2014); Halperín Donghi (Reference Halperín Donghi1982).

As shown, the funds received by the situado between 1806 and 1807 were greater than historians have previously considered. A considerable portion did not enter Buenos Aires but Córdoba and was redistributed by order of Viceroy Sobremonte and disposed of in the context of the English Invasions. Especially throughout 1807, the treasury of Buenos Aires had the funds of the situado brought to Córdoba through promissory notes. Advancing funds to the Royal Treasury for metallic silver was a common practice, especially among traders, in the Río de la Plata (Gelman Reference Gelman1996; Grieco Reference Grieco2009). These operations highlight a few important aspects. For the Córdoba treasury, this meant establishing itself as a redistribution Caja for the resources of the situado, especially during 1806, when it executed an important part of the expenditures. But given that the royal treasury of Córdoba did not pay all the commitments in a timely manner, this implied a credit in favor of the Royal Treasury. The review of the accounting books (ledgers and manuals) of the Córdoba treasury demonstrates that, at least until 1810, a good portion of the funds received in Buenos Aires during 1807 to be paid in Córdoba had not yet been paid.Footnote 14 For individuals, there was the possibility of obtaining the silver of the situado from Potosí, from advancing funds in pesos dobles de cordoncillo in Buenos Aires (to meet the emergencies of the treasury), in addition to acquiring silver in Córdoba through agents.Footnote 15 This was a practice that allowed the benefits from currency arbitrage prizes to be privatized, albeit not without risk, since payments could take a long time to process

Last but not least, for the treasury of Buenos Aires, the use of promissory notes meant quickly raising funds to pay off military expenses. In this way, private individuals deposited a total of 465.000 pesos in the Buenos Aires treasury, an amount that should be paid in Córdoba for war outlays. The examination of the data (outputs) of Real Hacienda en común of the main treasury of the viceroyalty shows that it used these resources to pay institutions such as the navy in Montevideo or kept them in the capital’s treasury. Above all, using this mechanism in these circumstances granted the Caja of Buenos Aires the possibility of continuing to manage the resources of the situado even when, by order of the viceroy, funds had arrived at Córdoba. After the experience of 1806, when the distribution of situado and a significant part of the expenditure execution were under the authority of the Córdoba treasury, the money received by the Buenos Aires treasury by 1807 through promissory notes was used to more directly and quickly dispose of the Potosí funds, delegating the payment of the commitments assumed in the Córdoba treasury.

These findings demand a reassessment of the evolution of the situado during the first decade of the nineteenth century. As evident in Table 2, in the period 1801–1805 the situado suffered the biggest decline before recovering in 1806 and 1807. However, previously, specialized historiography had affirmed that the most important fall took place between 1805 and 1806 and in 1810. It had confused the funds introduced through promissory notes with contributions of the Córdoba treasury when those actually came from Potosí.Footnote 16 For the period 1801–1805, the differences between the estimations of Amaral (Reference Amaral2014) and Halperín Donghi (Reference Halperín Donghi1982) and my own research are because those authors recorded contributions from other Cajas in the interior within the situado.Footnote 17 Even if the amounts arrived together, the funds of other haciendas belonged to the surplus of each treasury and ramo.

If during the period 1801–1810 the income per situado reached 8.593.756 pesos, the decline in this period with respect to the previous decade amounted to 5.382.751 pesos. In the first five years of this period, however, silver arrivals from Potosí fell the most. How did the Real Hacienda of Buenos Aires manage to counterbalance this drop in income? What role did the funds of the regional treasuries of the viceregal interior play in the process?

The contributions of the regional treasuries between 1801 and 1810

A combination of resources and factors contributed to or allowed for the fall of the situado potosino beginning in 1801 and the rise in war-related expenditures with the English invasions. The most important factor was the consumption of accumulated funds in the ramos of the Real Hacienda (“Depósitos”; “Bienes de difuntos”) funds coming from Chile, transfers and loans from special rents (like tithes or tobaccos), and private loans through entities like the consulate and the cabildo (Halperín Donghi Reference Halperín Donghi1982; Amaral Reference Amaral2014; Kraselsky Reference Kraselsky2016; Grieco Reference Grieco2018).Footnote 18 The contributions of the Cajas of the viceregal interior were a factor, but a less important one. According to historians, the greatest contribution of the treasuries of the interior took place between 1806 and 1810, to help compensate for the presumed fall of the situado. But these figures confuse the contributions from Potosí during 1806 and 1807 with contributions originally from Córdoba. Research in the accounting books from different treasuries locates the biggest fall of the situado between 1801 and 1805, in line with the production crises in Potosí found in other studies, and its subsequent recovery to higher levels. In the following, I reconstruct the contributions of the royal treasuries of the viceregal interior of Río de la Plata to demonstrate that these shipments were more important during the first years of the century, when the situado fell and the monarchy repeated the requests for funds transfers. I also describe the different mechanisms through which the main treasury of Buenos Aires collected funds from the interior. Finally, I estimate the impact of remittances on the origin treasuries.

I have managed to identify all the entries of funds from the viceregal interior treasuries for the period 1801 to 1810 in the ramos that made up the Real Hacienda of Buenos Aires. Thus, it is possible to identify the amount that each regional hacienda contributed to mitigation of the effects of the fall of the situado during the period 1801–1810 while pinpointing the income collected by the Buenos Aires treasury year after year.

The reconstructed figures allow for corrections of the values estimated in the specialized historiography, demonstrating that the resources provided by the interior treasuries [without Alto Perú] were less than those previously assumed but show a different moment of arrival. Footnote 19 If we observe the total funds deposited on behalf of these treasuries during the period in which the situado declined (1801–1810), the value reaches 469.930.52 pesos (Table 3). This amount represented only 5.4 percent of the value contributed by the situado during the same period. If the amount references the values that the hacienda of Buenos Aires ceased to receive for this item compared to the income during the previous decade of the 1790s, that is, the 5.380.751 pesos in decline, then the resources contributed by the viceregal interior covered 8.7 percent of that total amount. Footnote 20

Table 3. Real Hacienda of Buenos Aires, incomes by treasuries of the viceregal interior (without Alto Perú)

I want to emphasize that the biggest surplus arrivals took place between 1801 and 1805, when the situado’s fall was more significant and the authorities of the royal treasury repeated their request for remittances as a result of imperial financial urgencies. During the following five years, this type of contribution became smaller as the situado potosino recovered. The main difference with the existing specialized research is this: the reconstruction of the circulation of situado only from the perspective of the Buenos Aires treasury meant that resources acquired through promissory notes were registered from Córdoba instead of Potosí. This led historians to believe that between 1806 and 1807, there was a greater decrease in the situado, which was compensated by loans from the Cabildo and other corporations together with an increase in contributions from the interior treasuries.

My research in the ledgers of the treasuries of Buenos Aires, Córdoba, Mendoza, and Santa Fe allowed me to reconstruct payment circuits, identifying and differentiating the funds that originated in the situado from contributions by regional treasuries. It also allowed me to understand how the Real Hacienda of Buenos Aires collected the surplus of these regional treasuries, which, between the years 1801 and 1805, served to feed the funds that were used to compensate for the fall of the situado. I explain this mechanism next.

Transfer mechanisms: An old regime treasury

In addition to the use of promissory notes to acquire funds from the situado received in Córdoba, the Royal Treasury of Buenos Aires had other mechanisms for acquiring resources under the jurisdiction of Córdoba. I identify two ways it acquired funds from Buenos Aires. First, it requested remittances with the help of carriers, who, in their journey from Potosí, added the surplus available in Córdoba to the flow rates to hand over in the viceregal capital. This was one of the main ways to send resources. The same was true in the cases of Tucumán, Salta, and the minor treasuries under the jurisdiction of Salta (Wayar Reference Wayar2011).

The other mechanism that allowed the Viceregal treasury to intercept funds was the recollection of the nuevo impuesto of the jurisdiction of Córdoba. Introduced during fiscal pressures with the Bourbon Reforms at the end of the eighteenth century, this tax affected the circulation of goods coming from the Northwest that crossed Córdoba to the coast (especially from Salta and Jujuy, at the south of Alto Perú, toward Santa Fe and Buenos Aires). The tax was created to cover frontier expenses, and it was under the jurisdiction of the cabildo of Córdoba city (which appointed a deputy for its collection) and the Royal treasury. The collection of the tax was divided between Córdoba and the Buenos Aires Customhouse, where a specific receiver, Domingo Hidalgo, took charge of the collection.

The funds from this tax in the Aduana of Buenos Aires were collected by the viceregal treasury from the surplus of the Córdoba treasury. The mechanism was simple: Domingo Hidalgo directly deposited part of the collection of the nuevo impuesto of Córdoba in the treasury of Buenos Aires. In return, the treasury of Córdoba transferred the equivalent value of its own surplus to a common fund, with which it paid the frontier expenditures. In this way, the treasury of the capital had access to the surplus of the Cordovan caja, drawing directly from the collection of the nuevo impuesto at the customs, thus avoiding the physical transfer of money and its risks. This also ensured the treasury would obtain the resources from Córdoba in a simpler and more efficient way instead of having to await the carrier’s arrival. For the treasury of Córdoba, the advantage was that it could use its surpluses to cover urgent frontier expenses, making the arrival of the nuevo impuesto collection from Buenos Aires unnecessary.Footnote 21 As seen in Table 4, this method of reimbursement represented 14 percent of the shipments from Córdoba to the main treasury of Real Hacienda in Buenos Aires.

Table 4. Funds from Córdoba treasury according to shipping mechanism

Source: Accounting books of Córdoba royal treasury. AGN, Sala XIII, Córdoba royal treasury (1800–1810) N° 573, 574, 575, 579, 581, 582, 584, 586-A, 587 and 589.

My research into regional treasuries in Mendoza and Santa Fe has allowed me to identify other similar mechanisms for transferring funds (Galarza Reference Galarza2019a, Reference Galarza2019b). In the case of Mendoza, the main mechanism for attracting resources by the Caja of Buenos Aires was the transfer of surpluses by treasury ministers. As Table 5 shows, the highest volume of transfers registered between 1801 and 1810 corresponds to this mode of shipments; a smaller percentage was made by promissory notes and private contributions in Buenos Aires charged to the Mendoza treasury (in 1809 and 1810).

Table 5. Funds from Mendoza treasury according to shipping mechanism.

Source: Accounting books of Mendoza royal treasury. AGN, Sala XIII, Mendoza royal treasury (1780–1810) N° 10-09-01; 10-09-02; 10-09-03; 10-09-04; 10-10-01; 10-10-02; 10-10-03; 10-10-04; 11-01-01; 11-01-02; 11-01-03; 11-01-04; 11-01-05; 11-02-01; 11-02-02; 11-02-03; 11-02-04; 11-02-05.

Meanwhile, in Santa Fe, the shipments of surplus originating from the regional treasury represented a lower percentage of the funds channeled to the capital (see Table 6). In this case, the main mechanism for capturing money was similar to that observed in the case of nuevo impuesto of Córdoba: the reimbursement of funds made from the caja de arbitrios of the cabildo of the city of Santa Fe to the Caja of Buenos Aires.Footnote 22 Furthermore, a third mechanism was direct remittance of funds from smaller fiscal jurisdictions that made up the Royal Treasury of Santa Fe, especially from the receivers of alcabalas of Entre Ríos (the villages of Concepción, Gualeguay, and Gualeguaychú) and from the villages of the former Jesuit missions that sent resources to the aduana in the capital without going through the hands of the royal officers of Santa Fe.

Table 6. Funds from Santa Fe treasury according to shipping mechanism

Note: We must point out that, since 1808, the excise tax fund collected in the port of Las Conchas was integrated as a ramo ajeno in the treasury of Buenos Aires, which reduced the amounts of refunds since the Buenos Aires treasury managed to get hold of these resources directly collected in Las Conchas. The amount of this collection between 1808 and 1810 extended to a total of 45,000 pesos deposited directly in the treasury of the capital. Thus, the total collected by this item for the period 1801–1810 amounted to 82,192 pesos.

Source: Accounting books of Buenos Aires royal treasury. For Santa Fe, see AGN, Sala XIII 31-04-05, “Propios y arbitrios de Santa Fe, 1777–1790” and Sala IX 03-10-05 “Propios y arbitrios de Santa Fe 1802–1808.”

Regarding refunds by arbitrios, as historians have reconstructed in previous works (Galarza Reference Galarza2019a), this mechanism allowed the Buenos Aires treasury to manage to retain part of the collection of this tax collected in the Port of Las Conchas, under the jurisdiction of the Caja de Buenos Aires. As these funds belonged to the Cabildo of Santa Fe and were used to pay expenses to the imperial frontier (especially military ones), the Buenos Aires treasury ordered the royal officers of the Santa Fe regional treasury to send their surpluses to the cabildo of Santa Fe to discount, in turn, the equivalent amounts of the arbitrios collection in Las Conchas and integrate them into their own coffers. In practice, this compensation mechanism was identical to the nuevo impuesto and served to channel surpluses from the treasury of Santa Fe to the treasury of the viceregal capital, avoiding the physical transfer of money.

These reimbursements represented 57 percent of funds that the Buenos Aires treasury managed to collect from the regional treasury of Santa Fe during the first decade of the 1800s, constituting the main mechanism for raising funds. The remaining volume of resources was channeled through transfers of remittances, especially in 1802, as I explain in detail in the next section. The three cases show the diversity of mechanisms implemented by the administration of the Royal Treasury of the viceroyalty to collect resources or surpluses from the royal treasuries of the interior.

With reference to the regional distribution of these contributions, the inputs realized by Córdoba stand out, followed by Mendoza, then Salta and the treasury of Santa Fe (Table 7). If the organization of resources is established based on the fiscal jurisdictions and their contribution to the main treasury of the viceroyalty, then the Córdoba treasury leads, with 33 percent, while the Salta treasury is a close second, reaching 27 percent of the total, leaving the Cuyo region with the smallest contribution of 23 percent. Meanwhile, the coastal region, led by Santa Fe, reaches 18 percent with a figure close to 83.000 pesos. Moreover, the Cajas of Paraguay and Montevideo demonstrate their character as recipients of funds from Buenos Aires (especially the latter) (see Table 8). Footnote 23

Table 7. Caja de Buenos Aires, incomes from interior treasuries 1801–1810

Table 8. Caja de Buenos Aires, incomes from interior by fiscal jurisdiction, 1801–1810

If in Buenos Aires the funds for moderating the fall of the situado of Potosí are consistently about 8.7 percent of the total resources, this pattern changes when we focus on the treasuries of the interior. The shipments from the regional treasuries of the viceroyalty changed composition throughout the decade, showing in different years the prominence of some treasuries that concentrated greater volumes of remittances. Although remittances from the interior were not voluminous for Buenos Aires, they were significant from the point of view of the income structure of the haciendas in the interior.

As Table 9 shows, the average percent was greater in the treasuries of Córdoba and Mendoza and smaller in Santa Fe. In this case, it was influential that part of the collection of arbitrios was placed directly under the jurisdiction of the Buenos Aires treasury in 1808 (and that the amounts collected were entered directly in the Caja principal). However, the amount of funds acquired by different mechanisms of the Royal Treasury of the viceregal capital was more important for the origin treasuries than the Buenos Aires treasury. It should be noted that in the period 1801–1805, which we emphasize as the greater fall of the situado of Potosí, the pressure that the remittances exercised on the incomes of the interior treasuries of Mendoza, Santa Fe and Córdoba was greater than the period from 1806-1810. In the first case, the average increased to 64 percent over the effective incomes of the Caja. As a result of these, for example, the Mendoza coffer went from registering a total of 37.399 pesos of remaining cash at the end of 1802, to having 8.805 pesos for the same item at the end of 1803. During that year, the funds acquired in June and December surpassed the previously accumulated funds in the coffers of the regional treasury.

Table 9. Shipments to Buenos Aires as percentage of incomes in regional treasuries of Mendoza, Santa Fe and Córdoba, 1801–1810

A: effective incomes of the treasury // B: funds collected by/send to Royal Treasury of Buenos Aires. Note: The column entitled % B/A represents remittances sent to Buenos Aires as a percentage of the annual income of the originating treasury.

A similar process had taken place in the Santa Fe treasury. Particularly in 1802 and 1804, the cash flow to the capital was very important. The shipments registered in 1802 originated in the superior order of the royal visitor Diego de la Vega to remit the totality of the treasury surpluses to the capital, in line with the requirements from the metropolis. This value amounted to 22.417 pesos, which, when compared to the effective income in the Santa Fe treasury in 1802 ($12.185), was almost twice as much. Undoubtedly, this also influenced the consumption of accumulated funds in the regional treasury, which at the beginning of 1802 reached $33.445 in “hard silver” and at the end of the same year only 21.044 pesos. The average pressure over the incomes between 1801 and 1805 rose to 23 percent.

The case of Córdoba shows a larger and more persistent pressure of remittances over incomes during the period 1801 to 1804, before a decrease in 1805. These affected the remaining money available in the coffer of the treasury, which had already seen the fall of metal values from 22.880 pesos in December 1803 to 12.861 pesos one year later. The average pressure on effective incomes during the period 1801 to 1805 amounted to 60 percent, demonstrating the impact of the remittances in the treasury. Here, too, the needs or demands of the Royal Treasury facilitated the mobilization of resources.Footnote 24

In the next years, the remittances to the capital decreased. In line with the possibility of the managed funds of the situado, at the end of 1806 the remaining money available in the coffers of the Córdoba treasury increased to 46.000 pesos. But during 1807, having to face the commitments of promissory notes ingresses in Buenos Aires made the cash in the treasury at the end of this year close to 18.000 pesos and would continue to decline especially between 1809 and 1810.

Finally, Wayar (Reference Wayar2011, 24) mentions the Salta case and estimates 55 percent in average volume of shipments to Buenos Aires between 1784 and 1808 which was calculated not in relation to treasury income, but in relation to the remaining cash available in the treasury.Footnote 25 However, Wayar states that it was a decreasing percentage considering the immediately previous period (88 percent).

Conclusions

The Royal Hacienda of the Viceroyalty of Río de la Plata attempted to obtain the surplus of the interior treasuries, according to the needs of the treasury. During the period 1801–1805, when the hacienda needed resources, the funds of the situado from Potosí fell sharply. However, the treasury of Buenos Aires could obtain the surplus of the regional treasuries, through different mechanisms. The royal visitor of the hacienda, Diego de la Vega, was key to channeling the surplus of the treasuries of Santa Fe, Córdoba, and Mendoza, especially between 1802 and 1803. During 1803, the were no revenues from the situado in the Caja of Buenos Aires. Notwithstanding, sending remittances was a mechanism that worked regularly, especially in the cases of Mendoza and Córdoba. So, the contributions of the interior treasuries between 1801 and 1805 were more important than the historiography has supposed.

The other important mechanism for channeling resources from the treasuries to Buenos Aires was the refunding of taxes of Santa Fe and Córdoba. In the first case, the refunds of the arbitrios of Santa Fe city and its form of recollection constituted a mechanism that allowed the treasury of Buenos Aires to recollect an important volume of funds during those years. Something similar was put into practice in the jurisdiction of Córdoba, where the division of the collection of the nuevo impuesto meant that customs in Buenos Aires had resources of Córdoba available to send quickly to the coffers of the treasury of the capital. This allowed part of the surplus of the treasury of Córdoba to be received in Buenos Aires through reimbursements, avoiding the transfer of money. The distribution of resources involved communication across various fiscal jurisdictions including the municipality of the cities of Córdoba and Santa Fe, the regional haciendas, and the viceroyalty, which was represented by the Buenos Aires treasury.

Historians have traditionally attributed the low revenue of the situado in Buenos Aires in 1806 and 1807 to a decline in shipments from Potosí. However, the situado shipments remained steady, but were diverted to Córdoba rather than directly to Buenos Aires. During 1806, the Córdoba treasury was able to manage and distribute these funds, including sending funds to Mendoza, Santa Fe, Montevideo, and Buenos Aires. This meant an improvement in the money available in the coffers of Córdoba at the end of 1806. By 1807, that situation ended. Although the situado of Potosí arrived at Córdoba again, the treasury of Buenos Aires took resources of individuals through promissory notes to pay the Cordovan treasury. In this way, the main hacienda of the Viceregal was able to manage an equivalent volume of funds faster, without having to wait for the money to arrive. Therefore, because in 1806 only 950.000 pesos from the total of 1.269.302 pesos of the situado that arrived at Córdoba were resent by carriers to Buenos Aires, the utilization of promissory notes facilitated direct access for the Buenos Aires treasury to the funds of the situado that arrived in Córdoba in 1807.

The participation of individuals as moneylenders through promissory notes was not new, but in this case expressed the competition between both treasuries (Córdoba and Buenos Aires) to manage the funds that came from Potosí, after the experience of 1806. The cost to the Real Hacienda was the privatization of the money prize, but the risk to the individuals was that payments could be delayed.

From 1806-1810, the income that came from Potosí improved, and the contributions from the other interior treasuries were less than the historiography today indicates. However, the mechanisms to extract surplus included reimbursing taxes between Córdoba and Santa Fe and the treasuries’ remittances through carriers.

All those mechanisms allowed the Royal Treasury of the Viceroyalty to obtain resources from the interior treasuries. Although the volume of these funds was minor for the income structure of Buenos Aires, they were important for the origin of regional haciendas. We proved that in the main treasuries of the interior, such as Mendoza, Santa Fe, and Córdoba, the volume of funds finally collected by Buenos Aires represented important percentages of the real incomes of these treasuries. In some years, the amount of these resources implied a strong reduction of the available money in each regional coffer.

We conclude that all of the situations described here show the good functioning of the Royal Treasury, which is far from the traditional view characterized by disorder and corruption. This contradicts the idea that the interior haciendas had large margins of autonomy. This autonomy was always in dispute. The development of different ways of channeling resources allowed their arrival in Buenos Aires, putting pressure on the interior haciendas, especially in times of urgency for the imperial treasury, during the first five years of the nineteenth century. But the objective of extracting a greater volume of funds did not take place by a process of standardizing and verticalizing the fiscal scheme under the Bourbon reforms. Nor were the reforms carried out by a resource-hungry Crown that set its own terms without regard for its subjects. The analysis shows that the circulation of funds between treasuries was developed in a framework of tension, disputes over jurisdictions, and mechanisms of money extraction that were typical of an old regime hacienda. Where some earned little, others earned a lot, and everyone had to give up something to protect their own interests. However, this did not mean that the system was dysfunctional; it may not have been efficient, but it was effective.

The empire worked, sending requests for resources to all corners of the viceregal treasury and exerting strong pressure on the regional treasury accounts, through the old regime mechanism. Whether or not these funds were later sent to the metropolis (and to what extent) is another story.

Acknowledgments

I would like to make special mention of Katherine Esterl, whose assistance with the proofreading was invaluable.

Footnotes

1 Archivo General de Indias (henceforth AGI), Indiferente General, 1348, N° 1, p. 42.

2 According to Marichal the cost of “being a colony” for New Spain was translated into large exports of resources to the Iberian Peninsula especially after 1762, reaching 250 million pesos in transfers at the end of the colonial period. This outlet of resources negatively influenced the possibilities for economic development of the region (Marichal Reference Marichal1999). But this reality is hardly generalizable to the rest of Hispanic America.

3 Lynch (Reference Lynch1969) had already pointed out this topic when analyzing the supposed crisis of the 17th century in Spanish America.

4 Marichal and Von Grafenstein (Reference Marichal and Von Grafenstein2012) highlight the weight of the fiscal transfers from New Spain to the Philippines and the Caribbean by virtue of solving the Spanish defense military system in these territories. Research indicates similar operations between Lima and places like Portobelo, Panamá, and Valdivia (Flores Guzmán Reference Flores Guzmán, Marichal and Grafenstein2012) and Cartagena, which received fiscal transfers from other treasuries like Santa Fe in the viceroyalty of Nueva Granada (Meisel Roca Reference Meisel Roca2002).

5 Some research argued that the impossibility of characterized the Spanish case like a successful “fiscal-military state” is based on the limited fiscal centralization and the incapacity of implement reliable credits systems to face of the war expenditure, unlike the British and Dutch empires, successful in this regard (González Enciso Reference González Enciso2008; Torres Sánchez Reference Torres Sánchez2013).

6 “In each treasury office, daily registers of incomes and expenditures were entered into a monthly manual. The monthly books in turn reorganized daily receipts into their respective taxes or ramos. At the end of the year, a final libro mayor was produced that organized all accounts into income and expenditure categories in yearly totals. At the end of this detailed libro mayor came a one-page relación jurada, tanteo, or carta-cuenta, which was sent to the next higher authority and ultimately to Spain” (Klein and Barbier Reference Klein and Barbier1988, 42).

7 Klein and Barbier (Reference Klein and Barbier1988, 43) stated in reference to these discussions: “It reminds all scholars of the necessity of using the annual summary figures in a provisional and cautious manner. The lesson seems to be that the annual statements are a crude, but faithful, measure of the colonial fiscal situation. More detailed use of the documentation at the micro level can be expected to yield sharper understanding without necessarily altering the essence of the original interpretation.”

8 The authors argue that “the average number of silver marks rescued between 1802 and 1810 (287.022 marks) was 25 percent below the one recorded during the period 1781–1800 (with 384.064 marks)” (Mira and Gil Lázaro Reference Mira, Gil Lázaro, Irigoin and Schmit2003, 42).

9 Amaral has rebuilt the values of situado between 1790 and 1811, finding similar numbers to those presented here, with the exceptions of 1803 and 1806.

10 A payment order given in the name of someone who has funds in favor of the issuer. In this case, private individuals deposited money in the Royal Treasury, and the Treasury issued a payment order in the name of a third-party agent of the person depositing the money (to be paid in the Córdoba treasury).

11 In this type of accounting, pesos dobles or pesos dobles de cordoncillo are the equivalent of the hard silver peso.

12 That would arrive in Buenos Aires during 1806 and 1807, in “hard silver” and silver bars.

13 This is confirmed by the deed of chartering delivered in Potosí on February 11 and recorded in Córdoba on 7/29 and 9/29 of 1806. See AGN, Sala XIII, N° 575, Manual book of Córdoba treasury 1806, folio N° 25 and 39v.

14 Of a total of 561.000 pesos ingresses in Buenos Aires during 1807 against promissory notes to be paid by the Royal Treasury of Córdoba, 240.410 pesos were paid in 1807 and 6.000 in 1808, in addition to 64.000 pesos corresponding to the “Philippines Cia”. Up to and including 1810 more payments were not registered in the Córdoba royal treasury on account of these funds.

15 The best example was the case of Francisco Letamendi, who ingresses in the “Real Hacienda en común”, ramo of the treasury of Buenos Aires, 100.000 pesos in March 1807 to Martín de Sarratea. On October 31st, the treasury of Córdoba paid the equivalent to Dámaso Gómez, to name of Letamendi, in 55 silver bars that had been deposited in the Royal treasury by the situado. AGN, Sala XIII, N° 584, Manual book of Córdoba treasury 1807, folio 56 and Sala XIII, N° 44-05-18, Major book of Buenos Aires treasury 1807, folio N° 17. Similar operations were carried out by agents of Anselmo Sáenz Valiente, Gerónimo Merino, Ambrosio Funes, Antonio Lezica, and others.

16 Amaral estimates the values of situado in 1806 at only 131.000 pesos, because he does not count incomes from the situado from quicksilver sales, silver bars ingresses in ramo “effects and jewels in deposit”, and the funds receipted in Córdoba (Amaral Reference Amaral2014, 401).

17 Something that started to be common during the final of 1770 decade. See Wasserman (Reference Wasserman2017).

18 Such was the relevance of the loans channeled by the Cabildo that authors such as Grieco (Reference Grieco2009, Reference Grieco2018) postulate that they displaced the Royal Treasury as the main supporter of viceregal spending, consolidating its political role in the process that would lead to the May Revolution of 1810.

19 Halperín Donghi (Reference Halperín Donghi1982) estimated the contribution of the interior treasuries around 843.979 pesos between 1801 and 1810.

20 The situado entered between 1801–1810 (period of falling values) reached a total of 8.593.756 pesos, while in the immediately previous period (1791–1800) the same item had contributed a total of 13.974.507 pesos. Between 1781 and 1790 the total of the situado amounted to 9.208.432 pesos. The values of 1801–1810 were the lowest in the last thirty colonial years.

21 An example from 1803 will facilitate the understanding of this mechanism. In the Córdoba treasury, the surplus of 1802 from the ramos “inválidos”, “monte pío”, “indulto”, “donativo voluntario”, “15% Vales Reales” and “naipes” was transferred to the funds for frontier expenses. Then, Gaspar Lozano, the officer of Córdoba, send a promissory note against Hidalgo so that he could enter the equivalent of these money transferred to the Buenos Aires treasury, taking it from the fund of nuevo impuesto collected at customs of Buenos Aires. See AGN, Sala XIII, núm. 575, Manual book of Córdoba treasury, 1803, folio 4.

22 The arbitrios were a municipal tax that the King could be granted as a prerogative to cities, especially to cover imperial border expenses. In the case of Santa Fe, taxed the trade in sugar, yerba mate and cotton from Paraguay toward the Río de la Plata. Since 1780, Viceroy Vértiz divided the collection between the ports of Santa Fe and Las Conchas, the last one located in the Buenos Aires fiscal jurisdiction, so part of the funds collected were deposited in the treasury of the capital.

23 Neither the treasuries of Paraguay or Montevideo record contributions to Buenos Aires between 1801 and 1810, only 150 and 45 pesos during 1800, respectively.

24 This is how Gaspar Lozano, accountant minister of the Royal Treasury of Córdoba, expressed himself when sending in December 1801 the totality of the Royal Treasury stocks corresponding to 1800: “doy en Data Doze mil ps. S entregados a Dn Ant.o Ortiz Alcalde Conductor del R.l Situado para que los condusca a la Capital de Buen.s Ay.s a disposis.n de los Sres. Mintros. Grales de aquella Thesoreria …, consecuente a la Superior Orn comunicada al efecto, con motibo de las actuales urjencias de la Corona,” AGN, Sala XIII, Córdoba Royal treasury, Major book of 1801, folio 44. The underline is ours.

25 We consider that estimating the amounts of shipments according to the real incomes is better than in relation to the remaining money, because the cash flows took place during the year and the remaining money was the result of accounting exercises, after discounting the remittances.

References

Acemoglu, Daron, Johnson, Simon, and Robinson, James. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 9 (5): 13691401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amaral, Samuel. 1984. “Public Expenditure Financing in the Colonial Treasury: An Analysis of the Real Caja de Buenos Aires Accounts, 1789–1791.” Hispanic American Historical Review 64 (2): 287295.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amaral, Samuel. 2014. “Las finanzas arcaicas: La atención del déficit fiscal en la Real Caja de Buenos Aires, 1789–1811.Revista Investigaciones y Ensayos (60): 381436.Google Scholar
Biangardi, Nicolás. 2016. “Financiamiento y distribución del gasto en la caja real de Maldonado (Río de la Plata) 1782–1806.” América Latina en la Historia Económica 23 (2): 735.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohorquez, Jesús. 2022. “Neither Absolutism nor Negotiation: Spanish Empire Building and Political Economy in the 18th Century Caribbean.” Revista de Historia Económica/Journal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History 40 (2): 313348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cuesta, Martín. 2009. “Impuestos imperiales: La Caja Real de Buenos Aires (1700–1800).Temas de Historia Argentina y Americana (14): 2756.Google Scholar
Flores Guzmán, Alberto. 2012. “Los situados peruanos: Desde Chile hasta Panamá, 1700–1800.” In El secreto del imperio español: Los situados coloniales en el siglo XVIII, coordinated by Marichal, Carlos and Grafenstein, Johanna Von, 3360. Mexico City: El Colegio de México, Instituto Mora.Google Scholar
Galarza, Antonio. 2019a. “La real hacienda en las fronteras del imperio americano: Estructura tributaria de la tesorería de Santa Fe y sus remesas a Buenos Aires (1778–1810).” Tiempos Modernos: Revista de Historia Moderna 9 (39/2): 2859.Google Scholar
Galarza, Antonio. 2019b. “Recaudar en los confines del imperio. Impuestos y remesas en la Caja Real de Mendoza [Río de la Plata] a fines del período colonial 1779–1810.” Revista de Indias 79 (276): 459496.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gelman, Jorge. 1996. De mercachifle a gran comerciante: los caminos del ascenso en el Río de la Plata colonial. Sevilla: Universidad Nacional de Andalucía.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
González Enciso, Agustín. 2008. “El estado fiscal-militar, una reflexión alternativa.” Memoria & Civilización 11: 271295.Google Scholar
Grieco, Viviana. 2009. “Socializing the King’s Debt: Local and Atlantic Financial Transactions of the Merchants of Buenos Aires, 1793–1808.” The Americas 65 (3): 321350. https://doi.org/10.1353/tam.0.0100.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grieco, Viviana. 2018. La política de dar en el Virreinato del Río de la Plata. Buenos Aires: Prometeo.Google Scholar
Halperín Donghi, Tulio. 1982. Guerra y finanzas en los orígenes del Estado argentino (1791–1850). Buenos Aires: Ed. de Belgrano.Google Scholar
Irigoin, Alejandra, and Grafe, Regina. 2006. “The Spanish Empire and Its Legacy: Fiscal Re-distribution and Political Conflict in Colonial and Post-Colonial Spanish America.” Working Paper No. 23, Global Economic History Network, London School of Economics, London.Google Scholar
Irigoin, Alejandra, and Grafe, Regina. 2013. “Bounded Leviathan: Fiscal Constraints and Financial Development in the Early Modern Hispanic World.” In Questioning Credible Commitment: Perspectives on the Rise of Financial Capitalism, edited by Coffman, D’Maris, Leonard, Adrian, and Neal, Larry, 199227. Macroeconomic Policy Making. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Herbert. 1973. “Las finanzas del Virreinato del Río de la Plata en 1790.” Desarrollo Económico 13 (50): 369400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Herbert. 1984. “Commentaries on ‘Public Expenditures Financing in the Colonial Treasury’ III. Robbing Peter to Pay Paul: The Internal Transfers Problem in the Royal Treasury Accounts.” Hispanic American Historical Review 64 (2): 310312.Google Scholar
Klein, Herbert. 1998. The American Finances of Spanish Empire. Royal Income and Expenditures in Colonial México, Perú and Bolivia, 1680–1809. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.Google Scholar
Klein, Herbert, and Barbier, Jacques. 1988. “Recent Trends in the Study of Spanish American Colonial Public Finance.” Latin American Research Review 23 (1): 3562.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kraselsky, Javier. 2016. “Conflictos corporativos entre comerciantes en el Virreinato del Río de la Plata.” Americanía 4 (July–December): 215246.Google Scholar
Lynch, John. 1969. Spain under the Habsbourgs. 2 vols. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Marichal, Carlos. 1999. La bancarrota del virreinato: Nueva España y las finanzas del Imperio español, 1780–1810. Mexico City: FCE-El Colegio de México.Google Scholar
Marichal, Carlos, and Von Grafenstein, Johanna, coord. 2012. El secreto del imperio español: Los situados coloniales en el siglo XVIII. Mexico City: El Colegio de México, Instituto Mora.Google Scholar
Meisel Roca, Adolfo. 2002. “Crecimiento a través de los subsidios: Cartagena de Indias y el situado, 1751–1810.Cuadernos de Historia Económica y Empresarial (9): 125.Google Scholar
Mira, Guillermo, and Gil Lázaro, Alicia. 2003. “Minería, comercio y moneda en un período de transición: Potosí, la crisis colonial y las bases del crecimiento económico del Río de la Plata después de la Independencia.” In La desintegración de la economía colonial, edited by Irigoin, Alejandra and Schmit, Roberto, 3756. Buenos Aires: Editorial Biblos.Google Scholar
North, Douglas. 1990. Institution, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglas, Weingast, Barry, and Summerhill, William. 2000. “Order, Disorder and Economic Change: Latin America versus North America.” In Governing for Prosperity, edited by Mesquita, Bruce Bueno de and Root, Hilton, 154. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Pinto Bernal, Joaquín. 2015. “Fiscalidad e independencia en Santa Fe y Bogotá, 1780–1830.” América Latina en la Historia Económica 22 (3): 743.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sánchez Santiró, Ernest, ed. 2015. El gasto público en los imperios ibéricos, siglo XVIII. Mexico City: Instituto Mora.Google Scholar
Sánchez Santiró, Ernest. 2016. La imperiosa necesidad: Crisis y colapso del Erario de Nueva España (1808–1821). Mexico City: Instituto Mora, El Colegio de Michoacán.Google Scholar
Summerhill, William. 2008. “Fiscal Bargains, Political Institutions, and Economic Performances”. Hispanic American Historical Review 88 (2): 219234.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
TePaske, John, and Klein, Herbert. 1982–1990. The Royal Treasuries of the Spanish Empire in America. 4 vols. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Torres Sánchez, Rafael. 2013. El precio de la guerra: El Estado fiscal-militar de Carlos III (1779–1783). Madrid: Marcial Pons.Google Scholar
Wasserman, Martín. 2017. “Recursos fiscales para administrar el Imperio: La gestión de los ingresos al Ramo de Situados de Buenos Aires, 1766–1784.” Estudios del ISHIR (Investigaciones Socio Históricas Regionales) 19: 82115.Google Scholar
Wayar, Alejandro. 2011. “Las remesas fiscales intra-coloniales: Una aproximación desde las cajas del Tucumán, 1759–1808.” Paper presented at V Jornadas Uruguayas de Historia Económica, Montevideo, November 23–25.Google Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Incomes by situado according to accounting books of Buenos Aires treasury

Figure 1

Figure 1. Path of conductors of trade flows from Potosí to Buenos Aires. Map by Javier Kraselsky, based on a map found in the Archivo General de la Nación, Written Documents Department, map library IV-168. See Kraselsky (2016, 224). I appreciate the author’s generosity in facilitating use of the map.

Figure 2

Table 2. Incomes by situado in Buenos Aires according to authors 1801–1810

Figure 3

Table 3. Real Hacienda of Buenos Aires, incomes by treasuries of the viceregal interior (without Alto Perú)

Figure 4

Table 4. Funds from Córdoba treasury according to shipping mechanism

Figure 5

Table 5. Funds from Mendoza treasury according to shipping mechanism.

Figure 6

Table 6. Funds from Santa Fe treasury according to shipping mechanism

Figure 7

Table 7. Caja de Buenos Aires, incomes from interior treasuries 1801–1810

Figure 8

Table 8. Caja de Buenos Aires, incomes from interior by fiscal jurisdiction, 1801–1810

Figure 9

Table 9. Shipments to Buenos Aires as percentage of incomes in regional treasuries of Mendoza, Santa Fe and Córdoba, 1801–1810