Every graduate school has its own distinctive historythat makes it unique in some way, but every graduate school isalso part of the broader economics profession and reflects thecurrents in the profession. The following dialogue focuses onthe question: Is it useful to distinguish a “Yale school ofmacroeconomics” from other schools of economics? The idea forthis dialogue came from William Barnett in a discussion with BobShiller. Bill suggested to Bob some names of individuals whomight conduct the “dialogue” and I was selected from that list.I happily agreed because, from my knowledge of the writings ofthe Yale faculty, I felt that there was a uniformity of ideas withwhich I was sympathetic, and which might deserve to be called a“Yale School”—a view shared with Bob Shiller.
Exploring the issue further, I found that there was farless agreement on whether the macroeconomics work that currently goes onat Yale can be classified meaningfully as “the Yale school.” Theobjections to specifying a separate Yale school were thefollowing: (1) The term, Yale school, had been used in the 1960'sto describe Jim Tobin's position in a debate with monetarists. Some felt it would be confusing to use the Yale schoolclassification to describe a broader set of works that are notconnected to that earlier, more narrow, use. (2) Calling thework in macroeconomics currently done at Yale a “school” distinguishes ittoo much. The work that goes on in Yale is similar to the workthat goes on in any top graduate economics program. It is not soclear how the work at Yale differs from, for example, MIT or Princeton. Itwould need to be more distinct to warrant calling it a “school.”(3) There is a diversity of approaches that are used at Yale,and it is not clear that they actually fit together. Forexample, Chris Sims's work follows from a time-series statisticstradition with influences from real-business-cycle and calibration work; Shiller's work follows from a Keynesiantradition. Fitting them together requires a bit of a stretch.(4) The degree of continuity in the Yale school over time is notas great as I had first imagined. There was little linkage atYale from Irving Fisher to Jim Tobin; thus the historicalcontinuity needed for specifying a Yale school does not exist.These objections are elaborated in the dialogues below. After discussing these issues with a number of Yalefaculty, I decided that there probably wasn't a Yale school ofeconomics, but that there was a Yale tradition. We also decidedto have a conversation with only two individuals—Jim Tobin andBob Shiller—because they are major figures in maintaining what Ibelieve is a Yale tradition. The conversations were heldseparately, although I asked many of the same questions to both,and focused much of the conversation on the issue of whether itis useful to distinguish a Yale school. Thus, the conversationsdiscuss the work of other individuals at Yale more than adialogue with another focus would have, and do not cover Tobin'sor Shiller's current work as much as conversations with analternative focus would have. The results are, I believe,interesting. They provide some useful insight into both the Yaletradition and current thinking and debates in macro.