This book seeks to provide an overview of the modern world economy since 1870, dealing with the material in such a way as to give due weight to chronology, regional balance, and coverage of the main topics. It forms part of a two-volume publication, with the first volume taking the story from 1700 to 1870. Volume II begins in 1870 because by then modern economic growth had emerged in Britain and already spread to much of the rest of western Europe and the British offshoots in the New World (the United States, Canada, Australia, and New Zealand), and was poised to begin in Asia, following the institutional reforms in Japan associated with the Meiji Restoration of 1868. There was thus a great potential during the period after 1870 for closing the gap in living standards that had opened up between the West and the rest of the world. Although many more countries embarked on the process of sustained modern economic growth between 1870 and 2001, the gap nevertheless continued to grow during the long twentieth century, as catching up proved elusive (Reference MaddisonMaddison 2005: 11). By 2001, the world was nearly seven times richer than it had been in 1870, but the gains were unevenly distributed, with the West growing by a factor of nearly 12, while the rest of the world grew by a factor of less than 6. As a result, the spread between the West and the rest of the world increased from roughly 3:1 in 1870 to nearly 7:1 in 2001, while the spread between the richest and poorest regions increased from roughly 5:1 to 18:1 over the same period (Reference MaddisonMaddison 2005: 11).
The volume is divided into two parts, with Part I covering regional developments and Part II focusing on the key factors governing differential outcomes in different parts of the global economy. It draws on the upsurge of literature on the economic history of most regions of the world that has been produced in recent years, much of it available in the English language, but also firmly grounded in national literatures written in other languages. Much of this literature has also been based on quantitative data and makes explicit use of economic analysis in an accessible way. The book is aimed at a wide audience of historians and social scientists.
The central story of this book is of a dramatic increase in living standards between 1870 and 2010 in most parts of the world, but unequally distributed. The biggest gains were in western Europe and the New World, which increased their lead over other regions until after World War II, since when there has been some closing of the gap. The standard summary indicator of these trends is gross domestic product per head of the population (or GDP per capita), which will feature heavily in our story. However, it will also be supplemented by other indicators, such as the Human Development Index (HDI), which attempt to take a broader view of living standards.
Part I: Regional Developments
Volume I charts the beginning of modern economic growth in Britain during the eighteenth century and its spread to other parts of western Europe and the British offshoots in the New World. However, it also draws on recent research to capture the considerable variation in outcomes within regions as well as between the main regions of the world. This included reversals of fortune between north-west Europe and the Mediterranean economies of southern Europe, between China and Japan in Asia, and between the British offshoots and Latin America in the New World, as well as a range of outcomes within Africa.
Volume II encompasses a wide range of outcomes within regions as well as between the main regions, with Table i.1 providing a convenient overview. As in Volume I, the data are taken largely from the Maddison Project Database, version 2013. Following Reference MaddisonMaddison (2001), GDP per capita estimates for each country are presented in terms of a common currency unit, 1990 international $, so that they can be compared across both space and time. Although this clearly creates index number problems, it is likely that these are dwarfed by measurement errors, and the exercise should be treated as indicating broad trends rather than being correct to the second decimal point. To fix orders of magnitude, it is worth bearing in mind that in 1990 the World Bank regarded anyone existing on less than $1 per day as living in poverty. This means that the minimum GDP per capita consistent with a society being able to support itself and reproduce should be around $400, with most people living on $1 per day and a small elite who may have been much richer, but had only a small impact on the average income.
Table i.I GDP per capita by region, 1870–2010 (1990 international $)
1870 | 1913 | 1929 | 1950 | 1973 | 2010 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
France | 1,876 | 3,485 | 4,710 | 5,186 | 12,824 | 21,477 |
Germany | 1,839 | 3,648 | 4,051 | 3,881 | 11,966 | 20,661 |
Italy | 1,542 | 2,305 | 2,778 | 3,172 | 10,414 | 18,520 |
Spain | 1,207 | 2,056 | 2,739 | 2,189 | 7,661 | 16,797 |
Sweden | 1,345 | 2,874 | 4,063 | 6,739 | 13,494 | 25,306 |
United Kingdom | 3,190 | 4,921 | 5,503 | 6,939 | 12,025 | 23,777 |
WESTERN EUROPE | 2,006 | 3,488 | 4,167 | 4,517 | 11,346 | 20,889 |
Czechoslovakia | 1,164 | 2,096 | 3,042 | 3,501 | 7,041 | 13,020 |
Poland | 946 | 1,739 | 2,117 | 2,447 | 5,340 | 10,762 |
USSR | – | 1,414 | 1,386 | 2,841 | 6,059 | 7,733 |
Yugoslavia | 551 | 973 | 1,256 | 1,428 | 4,533 | 6,693 |
EASTERN EUROPE | 953 | 1,726 | 1,982 | 2,088 | 5,020 | 8,678 |
United States | 2,445 | 5,301 | 6,899 | 9,561 | 16,689 | 30,491 |
Australia | 3,273 | 5,157 | 5,263 | 7,412 | 12,878 | 25,824 |
BRITISH OFFSHOOTS | 2,419 | 5,233 | 6,673 | 9,268 | 16,179 | 29,564 |
Argentina | 1,468 | 3,797 | 4,367 | 4,987 | 7,962 | 10,256 |
Brazil | 713 | 811 | 1,137 | 1,672 | 3,880 | 6,879 |
Chile | 1,290 | 2,988 | 3,455 | 3,670 | 5,034 | 13,881 |
LATIN AMERICA | 794 | 1,586 | 2,053 | 2,696 | 4,874 | 7,770 |
China | 530 | 552 | 562 | 448 | 838 | 8,032 |
Japan | 1,011 | 1,567 | 2,302 | 1,921 | 11,434 | 21,935 |
India | 533 | 673 | 728 | 619 | 853 | 3,372 |
Indonesia | 517 | 869 | 1,087 | 667 | 1,566 | 4,722 |
ASIA | 540 | 673 | – | 667 | 1,566 | 6,375 |
Israel | – | – | – | 2,817 | 9,645 | 19,171 |
Saudi Arabia | – | – | – | 2,231 | 11,040 | 10,201 |
Turkey | 825 | 1,213 | 1,213 | 1,623 | 3,477 | 8,225 |
MIDDLE EAST | 781 | 1,133 | – | 1,776 | 4,855 | 7,231 |
Ghana | 439 | 781 | – | 1,122 | 1,397 | 1,922 |
Kenya | – | – | – | 651 | 970 | 1,141 |
South Africa | 807 | 1,151 | 1,497 | 2,535 | 4,175 | 5,080 |
AFRICA | 613 | 758 | 779 | 887 | 1,387 | 2,034 |
WORLD | 884 | 1,543 | – | 2,104 | 4,081 | 7,814 |
The transition to modern economic growth in north-west Europe, documented in Volume I, opened up the possibility of catch-up growth in other parts of the world, and the extent to which that possibility was realized is most conveniently summarized in Tables i.1 and i.2. Although in 1870 GDP per capita was still higher in the United Kingdom than in the United States, by 1913 the United States had not only caught up, but had gone on to forge ahead decisively, remaining the world’s most productive large economy throughout the twentieth century.Footnote 1 It is therefore instructive to plot regional GDP per capita as a percentage of the US level in Figures i.1 to i.5, to identify episodes of catching up and falling behind.

Figure i.1 Regional GDP per capita: western Europe and former USSR
The idea that a lagging economy may be expected to grow faster than a leading economy has had a major influence on economic history since the work of Reference Abramovitz and MalinvaudAbramovitz (1979; Reference Abramovitz1986), who saw the period since 1945 as an important phase of catch-up growth. In fact, the idea that economic backwardness may lead to a spurt of catch-up growth was not new in economic history, going back at least to Reference VeblenVeblen’s (1915) study of Imperial Germany and Reference GerschenkronGerschenkron’s (1962) analysis of European and especially Russian industrialization. However, Reference AbramovitzAbramovitz’s (1986) paper appeared in the same year as Reference BaumolBaumol’s (1986) influential paper which highlighted the negative relationship between the productivity growth rate and the initial level of productivity in a sample of sixteen economies covering the period 1870–1979. The negative relationship, which indicates convergence of living standards between countries, could be expected from a simple neoclassical growth model, either because of diminishing returns to capital or the assumption of exogenous technology. With diminishing returns to capital, an economy that falls behind because of insufficient capital may be expected to have a high rate of return to capital and therefore greater incentive to invest and catch up. Alternatively, a country which falls behind technologically may be expected to catch up by simply adopting the more advanced technology from abroad. In practice, of course, the potential for catching up has not always been realized, and economic historians have often stressed the barriers to catching up. Indeed, Reference AbramovitzAbramovitz (1986) himself noted that only economies with the right ‘social capabilities’ could be expected to take advantage of the possibilities of catching up. This is borne out by Figures i.1 to i.5, which are characterized as much by falling behind as by catching up, or by divergence as much as by convergence of living standards.
The rise to economic leadership by the United States is the focus of Chapter 1. The United States surpassed the United Kingdom in terms of GDP per capita between 1870 and 1913, then forged further ahead between 1913 and 1950 (Table i.1). Although many countries narrowed the gap after 1950, the United States has remained the richest large economy. It is tempting to link the rise of US economic leadership to modern business enterprise and technological innovation from the time of the Second Industrial Revolution, focused on the electrical, chemical, and automotive industries (Reference ChandlerChandler 1990). However, the situation was more complex, since the United States already had higher labour productivity than the United Kingdom in manufacturing by the mid-nineteenth century, and benefited from a later structural shift of labour from low-productivity agriculture, while comparative labour productivity in the whole economy most closely mirrored comparative labour productivity in services (Reference BroadberryBroadberry 1998).
Turning to the performance of other countries and regions, we begin in Figure i.1 with the situation in western Europe and the former USSR. The series for western Europe is derived from twelve economies for which high quality data are available: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Italy, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom. Chapter 2 examines convergence and divergence within western Europe, finding that the region as a whole fell behind the United States between 1870 and 1913, before recovering some ground between the wars. However, World War II saw western Europe falling further behind, with the US continuing to forge ahead technologically, and Europe suffering extensive physical destruction and economic disruption as the main theatre of war. Between 1950 and 1980, western Europe experienced a ‘Golden Age’ of rapid catch-up growth, but this tailed off at around 70 per cent of the US GDP per capita level rather than closing the gap completely.
Figure i.1 also includes data on the territory of the former USSR, which dominates the path of GDP per capita in eastern Europe. The pattern of catching up and falling behind in the former USSR largely reflects the socialist experiment arising from the Bolshevik revolution of 1917, which forms the focus of Chapter 3. Although imperial Russia did not experience any trend decline relative to the United States before World War I, it was a long way behind, at around 30 per cent of the US level of GDP per capita. War and revolution dealt a devastating blow, but this was followed by rapid Soviet catch-up growth during the 1920s and 1930s, which has sometimes been seen as casting a favourable light on the socialist experiment. After another setback across World War II, Soviet catching up resumed, but after a promising start during the late 1940s, catching up proceeded at best very slowly. The contrast with western Europe during its Golden Age of the 1950s and 1960s in Figure i.1 is particularly striking because the Soviet Union was starting from a much lower level and therefore had much greater potential for catching up. As catching up levelled off in western Europe during the 1970s, the Soviet Union and its east European satellites began to fall further behind. The socialist bloc increasingly became associated with economic stagnation and loss of political freedom, leading to a growing loss of appeal and eventual implosion of the system. The collapse at the end of the 1980s was followed by a spectacular decline in per capita GDP, with the former USSR reaching a low point of just 14.5 per cent of the US level in 1998. By 2010, this had still only recovered to 25.4 per cent.
Since World War II, there have been a series of East Asian miracles and Figure i.2 helps to put these in context by charting the contrasting paths of GDP per capita in Japan and China compared with the United States. Chapter 4 sets out the performance of Japan, which was the first Asian economy to achieve modern economic growth following the Meiji Restoration of 1868. During the pre-World War I period Japan grew at about the same pace as the United States, which was in the process of overtaking the United Kingdom to become world productivity leader. It should be noted that the Japanese data constructed by Reference Fukao, Bassino, Makino, Paprzycki, Settsu, Takashima and TokuiFukao et al. (2015) substantially revise upwards the level of GDP per capita before World War II compared with earlier estimates, thus painting a picture of a more advanced Japan before World War I and during the interwar period than that suggested by Reference MaddisonMaddison (2001). The catastrophic collapse across World War II was followed by a dramatic return to GDP per capita growth of around 8 per cent per annum during the 1950s and 1960s, but this was followed by a return to 3 per cent growth during the 1970s and 1980s, and less than 1 per cent growth after 1990. Although Japan eliminated the productivity gap with western Europe, it stalled before catching up with the United States. A second wave of East Asian countries to develop after Japan, consisting of South Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore, known collectively as the newly industrializing countries (NICs), began to grow rapidly from the 1960s. By the early 1990s, there was talk of an economic miracle, based on ‘Asian values’ and activist industrial policies, which attracted some sceptical comment from economists (Reference KrugmanKrugman 1994; Reference YoungYoung 1995). Although all four NICs suffered serious setbacks during the East Asian financial crisis of 1997–98, they resumed catching up in the 2000s, and by 2010 South Korea and Taiwan were on a par with Japan, while the city states of Hong Kong and Singapore had caught up with the United States.

Figure i.2 Regional GDP per capita: East Asia
Chapter 5 offers an overview of developments in China, which followed a very different path from Japan, falling further behind the United States during the late nineteenth century and the first half of the twentieth. Chinese GDP per capita reached a nadir of around 5 per cent of the US level during the first thirty years of communist rule. From the late 1970s, however, following institutional reforms to liberalize the economy whilst maintaining the leading role of the Communist Party, China entered a dramatic catching-up phase. Although China did not manage to match the pace of catching up achieved by Japan between the 1950s and the 1970s, it had raised China’s comparative GDP per capita position to more than 25 per cent of the US level by 2010. Together with its huge population, this made China the world’s second largest economy measured by GDP at purchasing power parity, challenging the economic dominance of the West.
Turning to South Asia in Figure i.3, India has followed a similar trajectory to China, falling further behind the United States between 1870 and 1950 and remaining at around 5 per cent of the US level for the first three decades of independence from Britain. Liberalizing reforms during the 1980s then unleashed a dramatic period of catching up, again echoing the Chinese trajectory. By 2010, Indian GDP per capita had reached more than 10 per cent of the US level. Developments in India are discussed in Chapter 6.

Figure i.3 Regional GDP per capita: Latin America and South Asia
Figure i.3 also shows the performance of Latin America, which is discussed in Chapter 9. The eight Latin American economies covered here are: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, Uruguay, and Venezuela. The overall picture is a lack of catching up with the United States over the long run, although this hides important variation in individual country performance. Argentina and also Uruguay, to a lesser extent, were on a par with many west European countries in 1913, as major exporters of primary produce. However, they failed to fulfil their early promise and began a rapid relative decline from the 1930s. Venezuela, by contrast, was relatively poor until the mid-1920s, but then caught up rapidly on the back of oil resources. The whole region suffered a major setback with the debt crisis of the 1980s, leading to a ‘lost decade’.
The Middle East, which is plotted together with Africa in Figure i.4, is discussed in Chapter 8.Footnote 2 Reliable estimates of GDP per capita in the Middle East before 1950 are confined to Turkey for the interwar period and the Ottoman Empire before World War I, and suggest continued falling behind the United States until 1950. There then followed a period of catching up during the 1950s and 1960s, based on oil. The rate of catching up accelerated during the 1970s as the result of a massive swing in the terms of trade brought about by the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), led by Saudi Arabia. However, a reversal of the terms of trade during the 1990s brought about an equally dramatic period of falling behind, leaving Middle Eastern GDP per capita at less than 25 per cent of the US level by 2010.

Figure i.4 Regional GDP per capita: Middle East and Africa
African economic performance is discussed in Chapter 10. GDP per capita grew more slowly in Africa than in the United States between 1870 and 1950 so that Africa fell further behind during this period of colonization by European powers (Figure i.4). African performance during this period is more or less in line with the performance of colonial India, while independent Latin America held its own against the United States. Decolonization did not improve the relative performance of Africa, which continued to fall further behind after World War II, reaching a low point of just 5.3 per cent of the US level at the end of the 1990s. Africa then entered a period of catching-up growth, with GDP per capita recovering to 6.7 per cent of the US level by 2010.
The case of Australia, plotted in Figure i.5 and analysed in Chapter 11, reminds us that the world per capita income leader in the late nineteenth century was neither the United States nor the United Kingdom. The high per capita incomes in Australia were the result of a combination of a small settler population and natural resource abundance in an economy with good institutions. In the late nineteenth century, however, the resource boom faltered and Australian per capita income leadership disappeared. Across World War II, Australian per capita incomes declined further to around 80 per cent of the US level. South East Asia is discussed in Chapter 7, with the GDP per capita of Indonesia, the largest economy in the region, plotted on a comparative basis in Figure i.5. Indonesia fell further behind the United States between 1870 and the mid-1960s, before entering a catch-up phase after the coup to remove President Sukarno, who had presided over a period of slow growth and rapid inflation during the early 1960s. The setback following the East Asian financial crisis of 1998 is also clearly visible in Figure i.5.

Figure i.5 Regional GDP per capita: Australia and Indonesia
The data from Table i.1 can be used to calculate annual growth rates of per capita GDP in Table i.2. The first point to note is that compared with earlier epochs, the period since 1870 has seen a remarkable increase in per capita GDP growth rates. At the world level, GDP per capita grew at just 0.31 per cent between 1800 and 1870, so the increase to 1.3 per cent between 1870 and 1913 was a dramatic improvement. Even with the disruption of the two World Wars and the Great Depression, GDP per capita grew at 0.84 per cent per annum between 1913 and 1950, nearly three times as rapidly as during 1800–1870. Furthermore, the slowdown was dramatically reversed during the period 1950–73, when GDP per capita grew by 2.88 per cent per annum, before falling back to 1.76 per cent between 1973 and 2010. This general pattern of a setback between 1913 and 1950, followed by a Golden Age between 1950 and 1973, can be found in most regions, although it should be noted that Asia is the one region to achieve even higher growth during the period 1973–2010.
Table i.2 Growth rates of GDP per capita by region (% per annum)
1870–1913 | 1913–50 | 1950–73 | 1973–2010 | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Western Europe | 1.29 | 0.70 | 4.00 | 1.65 |
Eastern Europe | 1.38 | 0.51 | 3.81 | 1.48 |
British offshoots | 1.79 | 1.54 | 2.42 | 1.63 |
Latin America | 1.61 | 1.43 | 2.57 | 1.26 |
Asia | 0.51 | −0.02 | 3.71 | 3.79 |
Middle East | 0.87 | 1.21 | 4.37 | 1.08 |
Africa | 0.49 | 0.42 | 1.94 | 1.03 |
World | 1.30 | 0.84 | 2.88 | 1.76 |
Although GDP per capita is widely used as a measure of living standards, it is at best an incomplete measure, and needs to be supplemented by additional information. Two important variables widely monitored are life expectancy and education, which tend to show smaller differences between nations than GDP per capita. The Human Development Index (HDI), which combines GDP per capita with measures of life expectancy and education is sometimes used as a composite measure of the standard of living (UNDP 1990). Chapter 16 makes use of a modification of this, known as the Historical Index of Human Development (HIHD), introduced by Reference Prados de la EscosuraPrados de la Escosura (2015).Footnote 3 Mean values, however, do not tell us anything about the distribution of welfare across individuals. To take account of distributional issues, it is also necessary in Chapter 16 to examine measures of inequality, such as the Gini coefficient and top income shares.
Part II: Factors Governing Differential Outcomes in the Global Economy
Part II explores the factors governing differential outcomes in the various regions that are examined in Part I. An important distinction is made between the proximate and fundamental sources of growth, while a final section analyses the world economy as a system.
1. The Proximate Sources of Growth
Growth accounting helps us to assess whether economic growth came from the use of more factor inputs or from the more effective use of existing inputs (Reference SolowSolow 1957). In the simplest formulation, aggregate output is produced using factor inputs of capital and labour. The growth rate of output can then be related to the growth rates of the inputs of capital and labour and a residual factor representing any change in the efficiency with which the factors are used. Each factor is weighted by its relative importance in the production process, measured by its share in the costs of production. For labour this is the share of wages in the value of output, while for capital it is the share of profits. The residual factor, known as total factor productivity (TFP), is often associated with technological progress, but it can also reflect changes in organization.
Whereas the discussion of the labour input in Volume I focused on the increase in the number of workers as population increased, after 1870 the focus shifts to improvements in the quality of workers, as a growing number of economies completed the demographic transition from a poor economy with high rates of fertility and mortality to a rich economy with low rates of fertility and mortality. Chapter 12 thus focuses on human capital and the investments needed to make the labour force ‘healthy, literate, and smart’. Chapter 13 considers the roles of capital and technology. Countries that were catching up often did so with high rates of investment in physical as well as human capital, financed more through high rates of saving than through borrowing from abroad (Reference Feldstein and HoriokaFeldstein and Horioka 1980). These high rates of investment facilitated the transfer of advanced technology from abroad, which required both hi-tech machinery and the skills needed to operate it effectively.
2. The Ultimate Sources of Growth
Even if we had perfect information on the proximate sources of growth, however, this would only tell us how the transition to modern economic growth occurred, rather than why it occurred. If some economies grew faster than others because of more investment or faster technological progress, we would want to know why investment and technological progress were faster in those economies. Economists divide the more fundamental underlying sources of growth into two categories, geography and institutions.
The role of geography is analysed in Chapter 14 using the distinction between first and second nature geography. First nature geography covers natural endowments such as mineral deposits or climate, while second nature geography covers man-made factors such as access to markets and agglomeration economies. The effects of first nature geography can certainly be seen in the twentieth-century path of GDP per capita in countries with large endowments of oil. This is most obviously the case for the Middle East region, which benefited from rising per capita incomes as oil replaced coal as the chief source of energy. However, dependence on natural resources could also lead to volatility, again illustrated by the case of the Middle East, which formed a cartel to raise dramatically the price of oil during the 1970s, only to see it fall back when the cartel was undermined during the 1980s. The possibility of other negative consequences of resource discovery, such as the crowding out of local industry as a result of exchange rate appreciation in response to a balance of payments surplus, led some economists to coin the term ‘resource curse’ (Reference Sachs and WarnerSachs and Warner 2001).
Chapter 14 places more emphasis on the role of second nature geography (Reference Krugman and VenablesKrugman and Venables 1995). The basic idea here is that exogenously given first nature geography advantages or disadvantages become amplified rather than reduced by forces of economic integration. Favourable locations with high productivity are seen as attracting people and investment, which further raises productivity, while unfavourable locations with low productivity attract fewer people and investment, thus falling further behind. In such a world of increasing returns, reductions in the cost of trade may thus have asymmetric effects on different regions, with industry clustering in a few favourable locations rather than being dispersed evenly around the world. A useful summary measure to capture second nature geography of a country or region is market potential, measured by the sum of distance-weighted GDP of all regions in the neighbourhood. Building on the approach of Reference Crafts, Venables, Bordo, Taylor and WilliamsonCrafts and Venables (2003), Chapter 14 assesses to what extent the differential outcomes in the global economy over the period 1870–2010 can be explained using this new approach.
The role of institutions is explored in Chapter 15 using the ‘new institutional economics’ approach of Reference North, Wallis and WeingastNorth et al. (2009), who emphasize the need for a society to make the transition from a ‘natural state’ to an open-access social order so as to achieve sustained economic growth. In the natural state, a coalition of elites controls access to economic rents or profit opportunities, supported by concentration of political power. Economic growth can take place in such societies but is eventually choked off as elite power comes under threat. The transition to sustained economic growth requires the transformation of both political and economic institutions, widening access to economic rents, underpinned by a move towards representative political institutions.
3. The Global Economy
The world economy can clearly be broken down into its regional components, as in Part I of this volume. However, it is also helpful to think of the world economy as a global system, governing international transactions, such as international trade and migration and international finance. It is also important to stand back and assess the roles of warfare and empire. This can be useful in guarding against a tendency of earlier generations of economic historians to focus only on the effects of European developments on the rest of the world, without paying much attention to the impact of developments flowing in the opposite direction. Whilst the two-way nature of these reciprocal flows became too obvious to ignore in the second half of the twentieth century, they also need to be borne in mind when considering earlier eras.
The real flows of goods (via international trade) and labour (via migration) between 1700 and 1870 tell the story in Chapter 17 of the integration of product and factor markets in different parts of the world. The global economy became highly integrated between 1870 and 1913 as transport costs fell, trade liberalization led to a reduction in tariffs and other barriers, and there were few restrictions on international migration. Although there were already signs of a backlash against globalization before 1914, World War I led to a decisive reversal of market integration, ushering in a long period of deglobalization across and between the two world wars (Reference O’Rourke and WilliamsonO’Rourke and Williamson 1999). There then followed a period of reglobalization after World War II, which proceeded quite slowly at first before gathering pace during the 1980s. Although world exports now account for a higher share of GDP than on the eve of World War I, the peak ratio of migration flows to population occurred during the early 1900s, indicating that while goods market integration has continued to flourish, labour market integration has stalled at the global level.
International finance is considered in Chapter 18, which offers three perspectives. The first perspective follows on naturally from Chapter 17, showing that international mobility of capital has followed a U-shaped pattern, high before World War I and again since the late 1970s, but with an interlude of deglobalization during the interwar period and only a slow reglobalization during the Bretton Woods period after World War II. The second perspective connects the scale of capital flows with exchange rates and monetary policies using the idea of the ‘trilemma’, which states that economic policy can at best achieve two out of the three policy objectives of free mobility of capital, exchange rate stability, and monetary autonomy (Reference Obstfeld, Shambaugh and TaylorObstfeld et al. 2005). This trilemma is seen as helpful for understanding the choice of policy regimes adopted at different times in different places. The third perspective looks at the connections between international finance and economic and financial stability, asking whether pegged exchange rates and free mobility of capital are necessarily engines of instability, as has sometimes been argued.
Economic historians often focus on pre-war, post-war, and interwar periods, as if warfare was some kind of anomaly and minor disruption to normal events rather than a common occurrence that could sometimes lead to major turning points in history. And yet, by the late nineteenth century, a combination of military and economic advantages had enabled imperial powers to expand the territories and populations that they controlled to an unprecedented extent. Chapter 19 discusses the ways in which this expansion of imperialism facilitated the global movement of people, goods, and capital, but at the same time set up imperial rivalries that shaped the major conflicts of the twentieth century. World War I ushered in a period of deglobalization that lasted until after World War II, as the liberal world order gave way to increased controls over the international movement of commodities, labour, and capital. Although there were growing pressures for reform and greater autonomy for the colonized peoples, there was also a move towards greater integration within each empire to counter the growing trend towards protectionism and autarkic commercial policies. After World War II, by contrast, the return to globalization, combined with the weaker economic and financial position of even the victorious imperial powers, led to a period of decolonization, effectively ending the global hegemony of western Europe. However, the world then reoriented itself around two rival blocs led by the United States and the Soviet Union, based on an ideological divide between capitalism and communism. Although the end of the Cold War after the fall of the Berlin Wall in 1989 and the break-up of the Soviet Union initially reduced global tensions and led to reductions in defence spending, in the twenty-first century tensions have resurfaced between the United States and Russia, while China has emerged as a new superpower.
Concluding Comments
The economic history of the twentieth century is essentially an optimistic story of rising living standards everywhere. And yet the gains have not been equally distributed. Part I of this volume sets out the main trends in the different regions of the world. This is essentially a story of divergence between 1870 and 1950, as western countries pulled further ahead, while the period since 1950 has seen more convergence. Nevertheless there is a long way to go before the poorer countries catch up with the developed world. Part II seeks to shed light on the factors governing the differential outcomes outlined in Part I. It is clear that investment in proximate factors such as physical capital and human capital have played their part in the adoption of advanced technology, but that merely raises a further question of why some societies were better able to make those investments than others. More fundamental factors, such as geography and institutions, must also have played a role. The role of geography can be seen as operating through both first nature factors such as endowments of natural resources, and through second nature factors such as location near to buoyant markets. Institutions can be seen as playing an important role through setting incentives for socially productive activities such as investment and innovation. Finally, the pace of world economic growth was influenced by the institutions affecting the international flows of goods, labour, and capital, and there were striking contrasts between the extent of globalization in the pre-1914, interwar, and post-war worlds. The two world wars and the imperial struggles with which they were inextricably linked, also inevitably had their impact on economic performance.