Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-m9kch Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T14:13:01.667Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 December 2015

Peter Spiegler
Affiliation:
University of Massachusetts, Amherst
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Behind the Model
A Constructive Critique of Economic Modeling
, pp. 202 - 215
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron 2005. “Understanding institutions,” presentation slides, Lionel Robbins Lectures, http://econ-www.mit.edu/faculty/acemoglu/selected, accessed September 19, 2008.
Acemoglu, Daron and Robinson, James A. 2006. Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Aiyagari, S. Rao 1994. “On the contribution of technology shocks to business cycles,” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 18(3): 22–34.Google Scholar
Akerlof, George A. 1982. “Labor contracts as partial gift exchange,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 97(4): 543–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, George A. 2011. “Rising to the challenge: equity, adjustment and balance in the world economy,” Panel discussion, Institute for New Economic Thinking Conference, Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, April 10.
Akerlof, George A. and Shiller, Robert J. 2009. Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Allied Social Sciences Association 2009. ‘Panel discussion: recent financial crisis’, ASSA Annual Meeting, January 3, www.aeaweb.org/webcasts/2009/Recent_Financial_Crisis_Jan_3_2009/Player.php.
Allied Social Sciences Association 2010. “Panel discussion: how should the financial crisis change how we teach economics?” ASSA Annual Meeting, January 3, Part 1, www.aeaweb.org/webcasts/2010/fin_crisis_1/. Part 2, www.aeaweb.org/webcasts/2010/fin_crisis_2/.
Almond, Gabriel A. and Verba, Sidney 1963. The Civic Culture: Political Attitudes and Democracy in Five Nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ashraf, Nava, Berry, James, and Shapiro, Jesse M. 2010. “Can higher prices stimulate product use? Evidence from a field experiment in Zambia,” American Economic Review 100(5): 2383–413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Audi, Robert J. (ed.) 1999. The Cambridge Dictionary of Philosophy. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bailer-Jones, Daniela M. 1999. “Tracing the development of models in the philosophy of science,” in Magnani, Lorenzo, Nersessian, Nancy, and Thagard, Paul (eds.) Model-Based Reasoning in Scientific Discovery. Dordrecht: Kluwer, pp. 23–40.Google Scholar
Bailer-Jones, Daniela M. 2002. “Models, metaphors and analogies,” in Machamer, Peter and Silberstein, Michael, eds., The Blackwell Guide to the Philosophy of Science. Oxford, UK; Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers, pp. 108–27.Google Scholar
Bailer-Jones, Daniela M. 2003. “When scientific models represent,” International Studies in the Philosophy of Science 17(1): 59–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bajaj, Vikas 2006. “Mortgages grow riskier, and investors are attracted,” New York Times, September 9, www.nytimes.com/2006/09/06/business/06place.html, accessed November 10, 2014.
Barro, Robert J. 1974. “Are government bonds net wealth?Journal of Political Economy 82(6): 1095–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, Robert J. 1997. Determinants of Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Study. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert J. 2009. “Voodoo multipliers,” Economists' Voice 6(2), article 5.Google Scholar
Barthes, Roland 1982. “Introduction to the structural analysis of narratives,” in Sontag, S. (ed.) A Roland Barthes Reader. London: Vintage, pp. 251–95.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. 1986. “Productivity growth, convergence, and welfare: what the long-run data show,” American Economic Review 76(5): 1072–85.Google Scholar
Beales, Richard and Tett, Gillian 2005. “How rating agencies navigate the lucrative waters of structured finance,” Financial Times, London edn, July 28, p. 23.Google Scholar
Bernanke, Ben S. 2004. “The great moderation,” remarks by Governor Ben S. Bernanke at the meetings of the Eastern Economic Association, Washington, DC, February 24, www.federalreserve.gov/Boarddocs/Speeches/2004/20040220/, accessed July 1, 2012.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2010. “Implications of the financial crisis for economics,” remarks at the conference co-sponsored by the Center for Economic Policy Studies and the Bendheim Center for Finance, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ, September 24, 2010, www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100924a.htm, accessed July 1, 2012.
Besley, Tim and Hennessy, Peter 2009. “The global financial crisis – why didn't anybody notice?British Academy Review 14: 8–10.Google Scholar
Besley, Tim and Hennessy, Peter 2010. “Financial and economic horizon-scanning,” British Academy Review 15: 12–14.Google Scholar
Bewley, Truman F. 1999. Why Wages Don't Fall During a Recession. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Black, Max 1962. Models and Metaphors. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Black, Max 1993. “More about metaphor,” in Ortony, Andrew (ed.) Metaphor and Thought, nd edn. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 19–41.Google Scholar
Black, R.D. Collison, Coats, A.W., and Goodwin, Craufurd D.W. (eds.) 1973. The Marginal Revolution in Economics: Interpretation and Evaluation. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Blanchard, Olivier J. 2008. “The state of macro,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 14259.CrossRef
Blinder, Alan S., Canetti, Elie R.D., Lebow, David E., and Rudd, Jeremy D. 1998. Asking about Prices: A New Approach to Understanding Price Stickiness. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.Google Scholar
Blomberg, Brock and Harrington, Joseph E. Jr. 2000. “A theory of rigid extremists and flexible moderates with an application to the US Congress,” American Economic Review 90(3): 605–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Botticini, Maristella and Siow, Aloysius 2003. “Why dowries?American Economic Review 93(4): 1385–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boumans, Marcel 1999. “Built-in justification,” in Morgan, Mary S. and Morrison, Margaret (eds.) Models as Mediators: Perspectives on Natural and Social Science. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 66–96.Google Scholar
Boumans, Marcel 2005. How Economists Model the World into Numbers. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burtless, Gary 1995. “The case for randomized field trials in economic and policy research,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9(2): 63–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burton, Peter, Phipps, Shelley, and Curtis, Lori 2002. “All in the family: a simultaneous model of parenting style and child conduct,” American Economic Review 92(2): 368–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Buiter, Willem 2009. “The unfortunate uselessness of most ‘state of the art' academic monetary economics,” http://voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3210, accessed February 28, 2014.
Caballero, Ricardo J. 2010. “Macroeconomics after the crisis: time to deal with the pretense-of-knowledge syndrome,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 24(4): 85–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cappelli, Peter and Chauvin, Keith 1991. “An interplant test of the efficiency wage hypothesis,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(3): 769–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Case, Karl E. and Shiller, Robert J. 2003. “Is there a bubble in the housing market?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2): 299–342.Google Scholar
Cassidy, John 2010a. “Interview with Eugene Fama,” The New Yorker, January 13, www.newyorker.com/online/blogs/johncassidy/2010/01/interview-with-eugene-fama.html, accessed September 6, 2011.
Cassidy, John 2010b. “Interview with John Cochrane,” The New Yorker, January 13, www.newyorker.com/online/blogs/johncassidy/2010/01/interview-with-john-cochrane.html, accessed September 6, 2011.
Cavendish, Henry 1798. “Experiments to determine the density of the Earth,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society of London 88: 469–526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chang, Ha-Joon 2006. “Understanding the relationship between institutions and economic development: Some key theoretical issues,” UNU-WIDER Research Paper, World Institute for Development Economics Research.
Chari, V.V. 2010. Testimony before the Committee on Science and Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight, US House of Representatives, Building a Science of Economics for the Real World: Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Investigation and Oversight, Committee on Science and Technology, US House of Representatives, 111th Congress, Second Session, July 20, Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, pp. 32–7.Google Scholar
Chari, V.V. and Kehoe, Patrick J. 2006. “Modern macroeconomics in practice: how theory is shaping policy,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(4): 3–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cochrane, John H. 2009. “Fiscal stimulus, fiscal inflation, or fiscal fallacies?” http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.cochrane/research/papers/fiscal2.ht, accessed June 24, 2012.
Cochrane, John H. 2011. “Why did Paul Krugman get it so wrong?Economic Affairs 31(2): 36–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coddington, Alan 1975. “The rationale of general equilibrium theory,” Economic Inquiry 13(4): 539–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cogan, John F., Cwik, Tobias, Taylor, John B., and Wieland, Volker 2009. “New Keynesian versus Old Keynesian government spending multipliers,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 14782.
Cogan, John F. and Taylor, John B. 2011. “Stimulus has been a Washington job killer,” Wall Street Journal, October 4, p. A21.
Cogan, John F. and Taylor, John B. 2012. “What the government purchases multiplier actually multiplied in the 2009 stimulus package,” in Ohanion, Lee. E., Taylor, John B., and Wright, Ian J. (eds.) Government Policies and the Delayed Economic Recovery. Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Jessica and Dupas, Pascaline 2010. “Free distribution or cost-sharing? Evidence from a randomized malaria prevention experiment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 125(1): 1–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David 2005a. “The future of economics: the appropriately educated person in pursuit of the knowable,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 29(6): 927–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David 2005b. “The making of an economist redux,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(1): 175–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David 2009. Testimony before the Committee on Science and Technology, US House of Representatives, The Risks of Financial Modeling: VaR and the Economic Meltdown, September 10. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, pp. 127–41.Google Scholar
Colander, David 2010. Testimony before the Committee on Science and Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight, US House of Representatives, Building a Science of Economics for the Real World: Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Investigation and Oversight, Committee on Science and Technology, US House of Representatives, 111th Congress, Second Session, July 20, Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, pp. 39–45.Google Scholar
Colander, David, Goldberg, Michael, Haas, Armin, Juselius, Katarina, Kirman, Alan, Lux, Thomas, and Sloth, Birgitte 2009. “The financial crisis and the systemic failure of the economics profession,” Critical Review 21(2–3): 249–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David, Holt, Richard, and Rosser, Barkley 2004. “The changing face of mainstream economics,” Review of Political Economy 16(4): 485–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colander, David, Howitt, Peter, Kirman, Alan, Leijonhufvud, Axel, and Mehrling, Perry 2008. “Beyond DSGE models: toward an empirically based macroeconomics,” American Economic Review 98(2): 236–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, John R. 1924. Legal Foundations of Capitalism. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. 1934. Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Contessa, Gabriele 2007. “Scientific representation, interpretation, and surrogative reasoning,” Philosophy of Science 74: 48–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Courcelle-Seneuil, J.-G. 1858. Traité theoretique et pratique d'économie politique, 2 vols. Paris: Guillaumin.Google Scholar
Darnell, Adrian C. (ed.) 1994. The History of Econometrics, 2 vols. Aldershot, Hants, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Davidson, Paul 2009. The Keynes Solution: The Path to Global Economic Prosperity. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Davis, Douglas D. and Holt, Charles A. 1993. Experimental Economics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, John B. 2007. “The turn in economics and the turn in economic methodology,” Journal of Economic Methodology 14(3): 275–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dell'Ariccia, Giovanni and Marquez, Robert 2006. “Lending booms and lending standards,” The Journal of Finance 61(5): 2511–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeLong, J. Bradford 1987. “Have productivity levels converged? Productivity growth, convergence, and welfare in the very long run,” National Bureau of Economics Working Paper #2419. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Dennis, Ken 1982a. “Economic theory and the problem of translation: part one,” Journal of Economic Issues 16(3): 691–712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dennis, Ken 1982b. “Economic theory and the problem of translation: part two,” Journal of Economic Issues 16(4): 1039–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dequech, David 2002. “The demarcation between the ‘old’ and the ‘new’ institutional economics: recent complications,” Journal of Economic Issues 36(2): 565–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DeWalt, Kathleen M. and DeWalt, Billie R. 1998. “Participant observation,” with Wayland, C.B., in Bernard, H. R. (eds.) Handbook of Methods in Cultural Anthropology. Walnut Creek, CA: AltaMira.Google Scholar
Diamond, Douglas W. and Rajan, Raghuram G. 2005. “Liquidity shortages and banking crises,” The Journal of Finance 60(2): 615–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, Avinash, Grossman, Gene M., and Gul, Faruk 2000. “The dynamics of political compromise,” Journal of Political Economy 108(3): 531–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Domar, E. D. 1946. “Capital expansion, rate of growth, and employment,” Econometrica 14(2): 137–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Duflo, Esther and Banerjee, Abhijit 2011. Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty. New York: PublicAffairs.Google Scholar
Duhem, Pierre 1954. The Aim and Structure of Physical Theory, nd edn. trans. Wiener, Philip P.. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Dupas, Pascaline 2014. “Short-run subsidies and long-run adoption of new health products: evidence from a field experiment,” Econometrica 82(1): 197–228.Google ScholarPubMed
Eatwell, John and Milgate, Murray 2011. The Rise and Fall of Keynesian Economics. New York: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ericsson, Jan and Renault, Olivier 2006. “Liquidity and credit risk,” Journal of Finance 61(5): 2219–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Faccio, Mara, Masulis, Ronald W., and McConnell, John J. 2006. “Political connections and corporate bailouts,” Journal of Finance 61(6): 2597–635.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fang, Hanming 2001. “Social culture and economic performance,” American Economic Review 91(4): 924–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farmer, J. Doyne and Foley, Duncan 2009. “The economy needs agent-based modeling,” Nature 460(6): 685–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finkelstein, L. 1975. “Fundamental concepts of measurement: definition and scales,” Measurement and Control 8: 105–10.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving 1911. The Purchasing Power of Money: Its Determination and Relation to Credit, Interest and Crises. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton 1991. “Old wine in new bottles,” Economic Journal 101(January): 33–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gadamer, Hans-Georg 1987. “The problem of historical consciousness,” in Rabinow, Paul and Sullivan, William M. (eds.) Interpretive Social Science: A Second Look, Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Gadamer, Hans-Georg 1989. Truth and Method. New York: Continuum.Google Scholar
Gallegati, Mauro and Richiardi, Matteo G. 2011. “Agent based models in economics and complexity,” in Myers, Robert A. (ed.), Complex Systems in Finance and Econometrics. Berlin: Springer, pp. 30–53.Google Scholar
Geertz, Clifford 1973. The Interpretation of Cultures: Selected Essays, New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Gibbard, Allan and Varian, Hal R. 1978. “Economic models,” Journal of Philosophy 75: 664–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giere, Ronald N. 1979. Understanding Scientific Reasoning. New York: Holt, Reinhart & Winston.Google Scholar
Giere, Ronald N. 1988. Explaining Science: A Cognitive Approach. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giere, Ronald N. 1999. Science Without Laws. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Giere, Ronald N. 2004. “How models are used to represent reality,” Philosophy of Science 71(December): 742–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gintis, Herbert 2006. “The evolution of private property,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 64(1): 1–16.Google Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L., Gyourko, Joseph, and Saks, Raven E. 2005. “Why have housing prices gone up?American Economic Review 95(2): 329–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glaeser, Edward L. and Shleifer, Andrei 2003. “The rise of the regulatory state,” Journal of Economic Literature 41(2): 401–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Godfrey-Smith, Peter 2006. “The strategy of model-based science,” Biology and Philosophy 21: 725–40.Google Scholar
Goodman, Allen C. and Thibodeau, Thomas G. 2008. “Where are the speculative bubbles in US housing markets?Journal of Housing Economics 17: 117–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gorton, Gary and Huang, Lixin 2004. “Liquidity, efficiency, and bank bailouts,” American Economic Review 94(3): 455–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Groenewegen, John, Kerstholt, Frans and Nagalkerke, Ad 1995. “On integrating new and old institutionalism: Douglass North building bridges,” Journal of Economic Issues 29(2): 467–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grossman, Gene M. 1986. “Strategic export promotion: a critique,” in Krugman, Paul R. (ed.), Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, pp. 47–68.Google Scholar
Guala, Francesco 2005. The Methodology of Experimental Economics. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guiso, Luigi, Sapienza, Paola, and Zingales, Luigi 2006. “Does culture affect economic outcomes?Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2): 23–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haavelmo, Trygve 1944. “The probability approach in econometrics,” Econometrica 12(supplement): iii–vi, 1–115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacking, Ian 1983. Representing and Intervening: Introductory Topics in the Philosophy of Natural Science. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, F.H. 1970. “Some adjustment problems,” Econometrica 38(1): 1–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hands, D. Wade 2001. Reflection Without Rules: Economic Methodology and Contemporary Science Theory. New York and Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanssen, F. Andrew 2004. “Is there a politically optimal level of judicial independence?American Economic Review 94(3): 712–29.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harrod, R.F. 1939. “An essay in dynamic theory,” Economic Journal 49(193): 14–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, Daniel 1984. “Why look under the hood?” in Hausman, Daniel (ed.), The Philosophy of Economics: An Anthology. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel 1992. The Inexact and Separate Science of Economics. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausman, Daniel (ed.), 1984. The Philosophy of Economics: An Anthology. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Heckman, James J. and Smith, Jeffrey A. 1995. “Assessing the case for social experiments,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 9(2): 85–110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heidelberger, Michael 1993. “Fechner's impact for measurement theory,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 16: 146–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Henderson, H.D. 1938. “The significance of the rate of interest,” Oxford Economic Papers 1: 1–13.Google Scholar
Herfel, William E., Krajewski, Wladyslaw, Niiniluoto, Ilkka, and Wójcicki, Ryszard (eds.) 1995. Theories and Models in Scientific Processes, Poznan Studies in the Philosophy of the Sciences and Humanities 44. Amsterdam: Rodopi.Google Scholar
Hess, Gregory D. and Orphanides, Athanasios 2001. “War and democracy,” Journal of Political Economy 109(4): 776–810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hesse, Mary B. 1963. Models and Analogies in Science. London: Sheed & Ward.Google Scholar
Hesse, Mary B. 1966. Models and Analogies in Science. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Himmelberg, Charles, Mayer, Christopher, and Sinai, Todd 2005. “Assessing high house prices: bubbles, fundamentals and misperceptions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 19(4): 67–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1970. Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Response to Decline in Firms, Organizations, and States. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey 1988. Economics and Institutions. London: Polity Press.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey 1999. “Structures and institutions: reflection on institutionalism, structuration theory, and critical realism,” presented at European Association for Evolutionary Political Economy conference, Prague.
Hodgson, Geoffrey 2007. “Evolutionary and institutional economics as the new mainstream?Evolutionary Institutional Economics Review 4(1): 7–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey 2008. “After 1929 economics changed: will economists wake up in 2009?Real-World Economics Review 48: 273–8.Google Scholar
Hodgson, Geoffrey 2009. “The great crash of 2008 and the reform of economics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 33: 1205–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holmes, Douglas R. 2013. Economy of Words: Communicative Imperatives in Central Banks. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoover, Kevin D. 2001. Causality in Macroeconomics. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoover, Kevin D. 2005. “The methodology of econometrics,” available at http://public.econ.duke.edu/~kdh9/Source Materials/Research/econometric_methodology_plus_abstract.pdf, accessed August 1, 2014.
Hughes, R.I.G. 1997. “Models and representation,” Philosophy of Science 64 (Supplement. Proceedings of the 1996 Biennial Meetings of the Philosophy of Science Association, Part II): S325–S336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hutchison, T.W. 1938. The Significance and Basic Postulates of Economic Theory. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Iacoviello, Matteo 2005. “House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle,” American Economic Review 95(3): 739–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ireland, Peter N. 2004. “A method for taking models to the data,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 28: 1205–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1958. The Principles of Science: A Treatise on Logic and Scientific Method, nd edn. Intr. by Nagel, Ernest. New York: Dover Publications.Google Scholar
Jevons, W. S. 1965. The Theory of Political Economy, th edn. reprint of the 1957 edition. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Johnson, Simon and Kwak, James 2010. 13 Bankers: The Wall Street Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown. New York: Pantheon.Google Scholar
Juselius, Katarina and Franchi, Massimo 2007. “Taking a DSGE model to the data meaningfully,” Economics 1, 2007(4), available at http://dx.doi.org/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2007-4, accessed August 1, 2014.Google Scholar
Kehoe, Timothy J. and Levine, David K. 2001. “Liquidity constrained markets versus debt constrained markets,” Econometrica 69(3): 575–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kiyotaki, Nobuhiro and Moore, John 1997. “Credit cycles,” Journal of Political Economy 105(2): 211–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krishnan, C.N.V., Ritchken, P.H., and Thomson, J.B. 2005. “Monitoring and controlling bank risk: does risky debt help?Journal of Finance 40(1): 343–78.Google Scholar
Krugman, Paul 2009. “How did economists get it so wrong?” New York Times Magazine, September 2, www.nytimes.com/2009/09/06/magazine/06Economic-t.html, accessed August 31, 2014.
Krusell, Per and Smith, Anthony A. Jr. 1998. “Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy,” Journal of Political Economy 106(5): 867–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, Per and Smith, Anthony A. Jr. 2006. “Quantitative macroeconomic models with heterogeneous agents,” in Blundell, R., Newey, W., and Persson, T. (eds.) Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications. Econometric Society Monographs 41. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 298–340.Google Scholar
Kuhn, Thomas S. 1996. The Structure of Scientific Revolutions, rd edn. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kydland, Finn E. and Prescott, Edward C. 1982. “Time to build and aggregate fluctuations,” Econometrica 50(6): 1345–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lakatos, Imre 1978. The Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Langlois, Richard N. 2003. “The vanishing hand: the changing dynamics of industrial capitalism,” Industrial and Corporate Change 12(2): 351–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, Tony 1997. Economics and Reality. London; New York: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lawson, Tony 2003. Reorienting Economics. London; New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Lawson, Tony 2009. “The current economic crisis: its nature and the course of academic economics,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 33: 759–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layard, Richard and Nickell, Stephen 1986. “Unemployment in Britain,” Economica 53(210 Supplemental Issue on Unemployment): S121-S169.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
LeBaron, Blake and Tesfatsion, Leigh 2008. “Modeling macroeconomies as open-ended dynamic systems of interacting agents,” American Economic Review 98(2): 246–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leijonhufvud, Axel 2009. “Out of the corridor: Keynes and the crisis,” Cambridge Journal of Economics 33: 741–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leontief, Wassily 1971. “Theoretical assumptions and nonobserved facts,” American Economic Review 61(1): 1–7.Google Scholar
Lépinay, Vincent A. 2011. Codes of Finance: Engineering Derivatives in a Global Bank. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
LeRoy, Stephen F. 2004. “Rational exuberance,” Journal of Economic Literature 42(3): 783–804.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levy, Robert I. and Hollan, Douglas W. 1998. “Person-centered interviewing and observation,” in Bernard, H. Russell (ed.) Handbook of Methods in Cultural Anthropology. Walnut Creek, CA: AltaMira.Google Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. 1972. “Expectations and the neutrality of money,” Journal of Economic Theory 4(2): 103–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. 2003. “Macroeconomic priorities,” American Economic Review 93(1): 1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lycan, William G. 1999. “Philosophy of language,” in Audi, Robert J. (ed.) The Cambridge Dictionary of Philosophy. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 673–6.Google Scholar
Machamer, Peter and Silberstein, Michael (eds.) 2002. The Blackwell Guide to the Philosophy of Science. Oxford, UK; Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishers.Google Scholar
MacIntyre, Alasdair 1978. “Is a science of comparative politics possible?” in Against the Self-Images of the Age: Essays on Ideology and Philosophy. Notre Dame, IN: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
Mäki, Uskali 1992. “On the method of isolation in economics,” Idealization IV: Intelligibility in Science: Poznan Studies in the Philosophy of the Sciences and the Humanities 26: 37–51.Google Scholar
Mäki, Uskali 1994. “Reorienting the assumptions issue,” in Backhouse, Roger E. (ed.) Economists and the Economy: The Evolution of Economic Ideas, nd edn. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers, pp. 236–56.Google Scholar
Mäki, Uskali 2005. “Models are experiments, experiments are models,” Journal of Economic Methodology 12(2): 303–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mäki, Uskali 2009a. “MISSing the World: models as isolations and credible surrogate systems,” Erkenntnis 70: 29–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mäki, Uskali 2009b. “Models and truth,” in EPSA Epistemology and Methodology of Science, Suárez, Mauricio, Dorato, Mauro and Rédei, Miklós, eds. Dordrecht: Springer, pp. 177–87.Google Scholar
Marglin, Stephen A. 1974. “What do bosses do? The origins and functions of hierarchy in capitalist production,” Review of Radical Political Economics 6(2): 60–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marglin, Stephen A. 1975. “What do bosses do? Part II,” Review of Radical Political Economics 7(1): 20–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marglin, Stephen A. and Spiegler, Peter 2014. “Did the states pocket the Obama stimulus money? Lessons from cross-section regression and interviews with state officials,” Political Economy Research Institute Working Paper #371.
Maskin, Eric and Tirole, Jean 2004. “The politician and the judge: accountability in government,” American Economic Review 94(4): 1034–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCleary, Rachel M. and Barro, Robert J. 2006. “Religion and economy,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(2): 49–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre N. 1990. If You're So Smart: The Narrative of Economic Expertise. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Donald N. 1983. “The rhetoric of economics,” Journal of Economic Literature 21(2): 481–517.Google Scholar
Mead, Margaret 1953. Coming of Age in Samoa: A Psychological Study of Primitive Youth for Western Cultures. New York: Modern Library.Google Scholar
Meade, J.E. and Andrews, P.W.S. 1938. “Summary of replies to questions on effects of interest rates,” Oxford Economic Papers 1: 14–31.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart 1972. The Collected Works of John Stuart Mill, Volume XVII, The Later Letters of John Stuart Mill 1849–1873, Part IV. Mineka, Francis E. and Lindley, Dwight N. (eds.) Toronto: University of Toronto Press; London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. http://oll.libertyfund.org/titles/254#lf0223-17_footnote_nt_1141_ref, accessed April 2, 2015.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mill, John Stuart 1974. A System of Logic Ratiocinative and Inductive: Being a Connected View of the Principles of Evidence and the Methods of Scientific Investigation. Robson, J.M. (ed.). Introduction MacRae, R.F.. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip 2013. Never Let a Good Crisis Go to Waste: How Neoliberalism Survived the Financial Meltdown. New York: Verso.Google Scholar
Moore, Jr., Barrington 1966. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Boston, MA: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. 1990. The History of Econometric Ideas. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. 1997. “The technology of analogical models: Irving Fisher's monetary worlds,” Philosophy of Science 64 (Supplement. Proceedings of the 1996 Biennial Meetings of the Philosophy of Science Association. Part II: Symposia papers): S304–S314.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. 2001. “Models, stories and the economic world,” Journal of Economic Methodology 8(3): 361–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. 2008. “Models,” in Durlauf, Steven N. and Blume, Lawrence E. (eds.) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, nd edn. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. and Morrison, Margaret (eds.) 1999. Models as Mediators: Perspectives on Natural and Social Science. Cambridge UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Morgenson, Gretchen 2007. “Crisis looms in mortgages,” New York Times, March 11, p. A1.
Morley, James 2010. “James Morley on the failure of ‘modern’ macroeconomics,” Brad DeLong's Grasping Reality, June 27, http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2010/06/james-morley-on-the-failure-of-modern-macroeconomics.html, accessed September 6, 2011.
Morrison, Alan D. and White, Lucy 2005. “Crises and capital requirements in banking,” American Economic Review 95(5): 1548–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mulligan, Casey B. 2009. “Is macroeconomics off track?The Economists’ Voice 6: Article 6.Google Scholar
Murphy, Kevin M. and Shleifer, Andrei 2004. “Persuasion in politics,” American Economic Review 94(2): 435–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1991. “Institutions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1): 97–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ortalo-Magné, François and Rady, Sven 2006. “Housing market dynamics: on the contribution of income shocks and credit constraints,” Review of Economic Studies 73(2): 459–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Page, Scott E. 2010. Testimony before the Committee on Science and Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight, US House of Representatives, Building a Science of Economics for the Real World: Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Investigation and Oversight, Committee on Science and Technology, US House of Representatives, 111th Congress, Second Session, July 20, Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, pp. 29–32.Google Scholar
Peart, Sandra J. 1995. “‘Disturbing causes,’ ‘noxious errors,’ and the theory-practice distinction in the economics of J.S. Mill and W.S. Jevons,” Canadian Journal of Economics 28(4b): 1194–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peek, Joe and Wilcox, James A. 2006. “Housing, credit constraints and macro stability: the secondary mortgage market and reduced cyclicality of residential investment,” American Economic Review 96(2): 135–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piore, Michael 1979. “Qualitative research techniques in economics,” Administrative Science Quarterly 24(4): 560–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1968. The Logic of Scientific Discovery. London: Hutchinson.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1969. Conjectures and Refutations. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Popper, Karl R. 1994. The Myth of the Framework: In Defence of Science and Rationality. Notturno, M. A. (ed.) London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Quigley, John M. and Raphael, Steven 2005. “Regulation and the high cost of housing in California,” American Economic Review 95(2): 323–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Quine, W.v.O. 1963. From a Logical Point of View, nd edn. New York: Harper & Row.Google Scholar
Reddy, Sanjay G. 2013. “Randomise this! On poor economics,” Journal of Agrarian Studies 2(2), www.ras.org.in/randomise_this_on_poor_economics.Google Scholar
Riles, Annelise 2011. Collateral Knowledge: Legal Reasoning in the Global Financial Markets. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani 1999. “Democracies pay higher wages,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(3): 707–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, Dani, Subramanian, Arvind, and Trebbi, Francesco 2004. “Institutions rule: the primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development,” Journal of Economic Growth 9(2): 131–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sargent, Thomas 2010. “Interview with Thomas Sargent,” The Region, September, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, www.minneapolisfed.org/publications_papers/pub_display.cfm?id=4526.Google Scholar
Scheinkman, José A. and Xiong, Wei 2003. “Overconfidence and speculative bubbles,” The Journal of Political Economy 111(6): 1183–219.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, Martin and Tornell, Aaron 2004. “Balance sheet effects, bailout guarantees and financial crises,” Review of Economic Studies 3: 883–913.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya 1999. Development as Freedom. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Sethi, Rajiv 1996. “Evolutionary stability and social norms,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 29(1): 113–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapiro, Carl and Stiglitz, Joseph E. 1984. “Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device,” American Economic Review 74(3): 433–44.Google Scholar
Shiller, Robert J. 2007. “Understanding recent trends in house prices and home ownership,” Proceedings: Housing, Housing Finance and Monetary Policy Symposium, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, www.kansascityfed.org/publicat/sympos/2007/PDF/Shiller_0415.pdf.
Sims, Christopher A. 1980. “Macroeconomics and reality,” Econometrica 48(1): 1–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sims, Christopher A. 2007. “On the fit of New Keynesian Models: comment,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 25(2): 152–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skidelsky, Robert 2009. Keynes: The Return of the Master. New York: Public Affairs.Google Scholar
Smets, Frank and Wouters, Rafael 2007. “Shocks and frictions in US business cycles: a Bayesian DSGE approach,” American Economic Review 97(3): 586–606.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, Margaret Hwang and Smith, Gary 2006. “Bubble, bubble, where's the housing bubble?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (1): 1–50.Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon L. 1976. “Experimental economics: induced value theory,” American Economic Review 66(2): 274–9.Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon L. 1982. “Microeconomic systems as an experimental science,” American Economic Review 72(5): 923–55.Google Scholar
Smith, Yves 2011. Econned: How Unenlightened Self Interest Undermined Democracy and Corrupted Capitalism. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Snowdon, Brian and Vane, Howard R. 1999. Conversations with Leading Economists: Interpreting Modern Macroeconomics. Cheltenham, UK; Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishers.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 1956. “A contribution to the theory of economic growth,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(1): 65–94.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 1957. “Technical change and the aggregate production function,” Review of Economics and Statistics 39(3): 312–20.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 1979. “Another possible source of wage stickiness,” Journal of Macroeconomics 1(1): 79–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 2010. “Testimony before the Committee on Science and Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight, US House of Representatives,” Building a Science of Economics for the Real World: Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Investigation and Oversight, Committee on Science and Technology, US House of Representatives, 111th Congress, Second Session, July 20, Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, pp. 12–15.Google Scholar
Spiegler, Peter 2012. “The unbearable lightness of the economics-made-fun genre,” Journal of Economic Methodology 19(3): 283–301.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spiegler, Peter and Milberg, William 2009. “The taming of institutions in economics: The rise and methodology of the new, new institutionalism,” Journal of Institutional Economics 5(3): 289–313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spiegler, Peter 2013. “Methodenstreit 2013? Historical perspective on the contemporary debate over how to reform economics,” Forum for Social Economics 42(4): 311–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stevens, S.S. 1959. “Measurement, psychophysics, and utility,” in C. Churchman, West and Ratoosh, Philburn (eds.) Measurements: Definitions and Theories. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Stockhammer, Engelbert and Onaran, Ozlem 2012. “Wage-led growth: theory evidence and policy,” Political Economy Research Institute Working Paper No. 300, www.peri.umass.edu/fileadmin/pdf/working_papers/working_papers_251-300/WP300.pdf.
Suárez, Mauricio 2004. “An inferential conception of scientific representation,” Philosophy of Science 71: 767–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Summers, Lawrence 2011. “A conversation on new economic thinking with Larry Summers and Martin Wolf,” video recording, Institute for New Economic Thinking Conference, Bretton Woods, NH, April 8, http://ineteconomics.org/video/bretton-woods/larry-summers-and-martin-wolf-new-economic-thinking.
Suppe, Frederick 1989. The Semantic Conception of Theories and Scientific Realism. Urbana and Chicago, IL: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Suppes, Patrick 1960. “A comparison of the meaning and uses of models in mathematics and the empirical sciences,” in Studies in the Methodology and Foundations of Science: Selected papers from 1951 to 1969. Dordrecht: D. Reidel.Google Scholar
Suppes, Patrick 1962. “Models of data,” in Nagel, Ernest, Suppes, Patrick, and Tarski, Alfred (eds.) Logic, Methodology and Philosophy of Science: Proceedings of the 1960 International Congress. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 252–61.Google Scholar
Suppes, Patrick 1967. “What is a scientific theory?” in Morgenbesser, Sidney (ed.) Philosophy of Science Today. New York: Basic Books, pp. 55–67.Google Scholar
Swoyer, C. 1981. “Structural representation and surrogative reasoning,” Synthese 87: 449–508.Google Scholar
Taylor, Charles 1985. “Interpretation and the sciences of man,” in Philosophy and the Human Sciences: Philosophical Papers 2. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, John B. 2011a. “An empirical analysis of the revival of fiscal activism in the 2000s,” Journal of Economic Literature 49(3): 686–702.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, John B. 2011b. “The 2009 stimulus package: two years later,” testimony before the Committee on Oversight and Government Reform, Subcommittee on Regulatory Affairs, Stimulus Oversight and Government Spending, US House of Representatives, February 16, http://media.hoover.org/sites/default/files/documents/2009-Stimulus-two-years-later.pdf, accessed June 24, 2012.
Taylor, Lance 2010. Maynard's Revenge: The Collapse of Free Market Macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Terkel, Studs 1985. Working: People Talk About What They Do All Day and How They Feel About What They Do. New York: Viking Penguin.Google Scholar
Tett, Gillian 2005a. “Innovative ways to repackage debt and spread risk have brought higher returns but have yet to be tested through a full credit cycle: not everyone believes buyers are fully aware of the potential downside,” Financial Times, London edn, April 19, p. 17.Google Scholar
Tett, Gillian 2005b. “Why more opacity is dangerous for financial markets,” Financial Times, London edn, October 21, p. 19.Google Scholar
Tinbergen, J. 1935. “Suggestions on quantitative business cycle theory,” Econometrica 3(3): 241–308.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tuck, Richard 1979. Natural Rights Theories: Their Origin and Development. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Uhlig, Harald 2010. “Some fiscal calculus,” American Economic Review 100(2, Papers and Proceedings of the One Hundred Twenty Second Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association): 30–4.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
US House Committee on Science and Technology 2010. Building a Science of Economics for the Real World, July 20, www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/CHRG-111hhrg57604/pdf/CHRG-111hhrg57604.pdf, accessed August 1, 2014.
US Senate Committee on Homeland Security and Governmental Affairs 2011. Wall Street and the Financial Crisis: Anatomy of a Financial Collapse, www.hsgac.senate.gov//imo/media/doc/Financial_Crisis/FinancialCrisisReport.pdf, accessed August 1, 2014.
Van Fraassen, Bas 2000. The Scientific Image. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Van Order, Robert 2006. “A model of financial structure and financial fragility,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 38(3): 565–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1912. The Theory of the Leisure Class: An Economic Study in the Evolution of Institutions. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1915. The Theory of Business Enterprise. New York: Charles Scribner's Sons.Google Scholar
Veblen, Thorstein 1919. “Why is economics not an evolutionary science?” in Veblen, Thorstein, The Place of Science in Modern Civilization. New York: Cosimo.Google Scholar
Wadhwani, Sushil B. and Wall, Martin 1989. “The effects of unions on corporate investment: Evidence from accounts data,” Centre for Labour Economics, London School of Economics, Discussion Paper No. 355.
Wadhwani, Sushil B. and Wall, Martin 1991. “A direct test of the efficiency wage model using UK micro-data,” Oxford Economic Papers, New Series 43(4): 529–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisberg, M. 2007a. “Who is a modeler?British Journal of the Philosophy of Science 58: 207–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisberg, M. 2007b. “Three kinds of idealization,” Journal of Philosophy 104(12): 639–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1975. Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Williamson, Oliver E. 2000. “The new institutional economics: taking stock, looking ahead,” Journal of Economic Literature 38(3): 595–613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Winter, Sidney G. 2010. “Testimony before the Committee on Science and Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and Oversight, US House of Representatives,” Building a Science of Economics for the Real World: Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Investigation and Oversight, Committee on Science and Technology, US House of Representatives 111th Congress, Second Session, July 20, Washington, DC: Government Printing Office, pp. 15–27.Google Scholar
Woodward, Jim 1989. “Data and phenomena,” Synthese 79(3): 393–472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Worsley, Peter 1968. The Trumpet Shall Sound: A Study of “Cargo” Cults in Melanesia, rd edn. New York: Schocken.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Peter Spiegler, University of Massachusetts, Amherst
  • Book: Behind the Model
  • Online publication: 05 December 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107706941.010
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Peter Spiegler, University of Massachusetts, Amherst
  • Book: Behind the Model
  • Online publication: 05 December 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107706941.010
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Peter Spiegler, University of Massachusetts, Amherst
  • Book: Behind the Model
  • Online publication: 05 December 2015
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9781107706941.010
Available formats
×