Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-wq484 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-27T04:07:49.659Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Introduction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 March 2017

Richard Blundell
Affiliation:
University College London
Estelle Cantillon
Affiliation:
Université Libre de Bruxelles, Brussels
Barbara Chizzolini
Affiliation:
Bocconi University, Milan, Italy
Marc Ivaldi
Affiliation:
Toulouse School of Economics, Toulouse, France
Wolfgang Leininger
Affiliation:
TU Dortmund University, Dortmund, Germany
Ramon Marimon
Affiliation:
European University Institute, Florence, Italy
Laszlo Matyas
Affiliation:
Central European University, Budapest, Hungary
Frode Steen
Affiliation:
Norwegian School of Economics, Bergen, Norway
Laszlo Matyas
Affiliation:
Central European University, Budapest
Richard Blundell
Affiliation:
University College London
Estelle Cantillon
Affiliation:
Université Libre de Bruxelles
Barbara Chizzolini
Affiliation:
Università Commerciale Luigi Bocconi, Milan
Marc Ivaldi
Affiliation:
Toulouse School of Economics, EHESS
Wolfgang Leininger
Affiliation:
Universität Dortmund
Ramon Marimon
Affiliation:
European University Institute, Florence
Frode Steen
Affiliation:
Norwegian School of Economics
HTML view is not available for this content. However, as you have access to this content, a full PDF is available via the 'Save PDF' action button.

Summary

The European Union is the world's largest economic entity, yet its ability to design and implement effective economic policies is not commensurate with its size. It is lagging, for example, in terms of effective policies promoting productivity, growth, scientific research or technological innovation. The Eurozone debt crisis has provided a sharp and painful reminder that the European Union must adopt a new approach to designing its economic policies and coordinating them with the policies of its Member States.

At the same time, while the field of economics in Europe has seen impressive growth in terms of global impact, and in the number of researchers and funding, Europe still lags behind the US in terms of research productivity, and European research remains fragmented across its Member States. According to recent research, the share of articles in the top economics journals published by European researchers represents 34 per cent of the total production of articles in the world, while the US amounts to 53.5 per cent.1 The contrast is even sharper when the citation impact of these publications is taken into account. In terms of share of citations, the US represents 70.8 per cent while the EU share is 28.4 per cent, which illustrates the considerably higher impact of US research in economics.

Developing a competitive and open European research area is essential for growth and to the progress of European integration, because research is a key factor of growth, and competition among researchers provide them with incentives for cooperating across borders. However, different languages, a diversity of academic traditions and a variety of informal barriers often inhibit the free flow of research funding, the mobility of academic talent and, as a result, the efficient allocation of research and development funding. In times of financial restraint the latter becomes particularly important. In this context, research grants, especially if they are allocated across national borders (e.g., by the European Research Council, ERC), can provide valuable tools to circumvent limits to integration and consequently to enhance the exchange of ideas. In fact, the relationship between openness and successful research funding is reciprocal and internationalization can benefit national and regional funding, by, for example, permitting the inflow of foreign resources.

Type
Chapter
Information
Economics without Borders
Economic Research for European Policy Challenges
, pp. 1 - 28
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2017
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×