Published online by Cambridge University Press: 05 January 2018
Introduction
Predatory pricing is one of the most interesting and most controversial issues in antitrust. The term refers to a practice whereby an incumbent firm (the predator) sets prices very aggressively with the aim of excluding a rival from the market (that is, forcing the rival to leave the market or discouraging it from entering) or marginalising the rival and relegating it to a niche role. Predation – if successful – will therefore be associated with the existence of two periods: one, the predatory period, in which consumers will enjoy low prices and the incumbent will sacrifice profits; the other, the recoupment period, in which the incumbent will be able to increase its prices, and obtain higher profits, because the prey is no longer in the market (or has been marginalised). From the incumbent's point of view, this strategy is profitable if the earlier profit sacrifice is outweighed by the subsequent higher gains. From the point of view of consumers, and of social welfare, exactly the opposite happens. If the predatory strategy is successful, higher surplus during the predatory period will be outweighed by lower surplus in the recoupment phase.
Given that predatory episodes are associated with low prices, it should not come as a surprise that it is extremely difficult to distinguish low prices that are an expression of tough but fair competition from low prices that are an expression of an exclusionary strategy by the dominant firm. Suppose we observe that after the entry of a competitor, an incumbent firm reacts by starting to cut prices aggressively. Is this the sort of genuine competitive response that we should expect (after all, any theory in which firms do not collude would foresee that entry would lower equilibrium prices), or is it instead predation? In other words, are low prices good news for consumer welfare, or are they instead just a temporary consumer gain which anticipates the permanent consumer loss which will take place when the prey exits the market? This is the first reason why predation is a controversial issue. A second reason is that, until the 1980s, economists had been unable to propose a convincing rationale for predation.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure no-reply@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.