Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-76dd75c94c-nbtfq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-30T08:01:07.367Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

15 - Bottom-up modeling of energy and greenhouse gas emissions: approaches, results, and challenges to inclusion of end-use technologies

from Part III - Mitigation of greenhouse gases

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 December 2010

Jayant A. Sathaye
Affiliation:
Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory Berkeley, CA, USA
Michael E. Schlesinger
Affiliation:
University of Illinois, Urbana-Champaign
Haroon S. Kheshgi
Affiliation:
ExxonMobil Research and Engineering
Joel Smith
Affiliation:
Stratus Consulting Ltd, Boulder
Francisco C. de la Chesnaye
Affiliation:
US Environmental Protection Agency
John M. Reilly
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Tom Wilson
Affiliation:
Electric Power Research Institute, Palo Alto
Charles Kolstad
Affiliation:
University of California, Santa Barbara
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Two general approaches have been used for the integrated assessment of energy demand and supply – the so-called “bottom-up” and “top-down” approaches. The bottom-up approach focuses on individual technologies for delivering energy services, such as household durable goods and industrial process technologies. For such technologies, the approach attempts to estimate the costs and benefits associated with investments in alternative fuels and technologies, and increased energy efficiency, often in the context of reductions in greenhouse gas (GHG) emission or other environmental impacts. The top-down method assumes a general equilibrium or macroeconomic perspective, wherein costs are defined in terms of changes in economic output, income, or GDP, typically from the imposition of energy or emissions taxes.

A fundamental difference between the two approaches is in the perspective each typically takes on consumer and firm behavior, and the performance of markets for energy efficiency. The bottom-up approach typically assumes that various market factors (“barriers”) prevent consumers from taking actions that would be in their private self-interest, that is, would result in the provision of energy services at lower cost. These market barriers include lack of information about energy efficiency opportunities, lack of access to capital to finance energy efficiency investment, and misplaced incentives which separate responsibilities for making capital investments and paying operating costs. In contrast, the top-down approach typically assumes that consumers and firms correctly perceive, and act in, their private self-interest (are utility and profit maximizers), and that unregulated markets serve to deliver optimal investments in energy efficiency as a function of prevailing prices.

Type
Chapter
Information
Human-Induced Climate Change
An Interdisciplinary Assessment
, pp. 171 - 180
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Boero, G., Clarke, R. and Winters, L. (1991). The Macro-economic Consequences of Controlling Greenhouse Gases: A Survey. UK Department of the Environment.
Brown, R. (1993). Estimates of the Achievable Potential for Electricity Efficiency Improvements in US Residences. Unpublished ERG Masters thesis, University of California Berkeley.
Brown, R. and Koomey, J. (2002). Electricity use in California: past trends and present usage patterns. Energy Policy 31(9), 849–864.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
de Feber, M. A. P. C., Schaeffer, G. J., Seebregts, A. J. and Smekens, K. E. L. (2003). Enhancements of Endogenous Technology Learning in the Western European MARKAL Model: Contributions to the EU SAPIENT project. ECN-C-03–032, April 2003.
Eto, J., Prahl, R. and Schlegel, J. (1997). A Scoping Study on Energy-efficiency Market Transformation by California Utility DSM Programs. Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory.
Fischer-Vanden, K., Jefferson, G., Liu, H. and Tao, Q. (2004). What is driving China's decline in energy intensity?Resource and Energy Economics 26 (1), 77–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gielen, D., Unander, F., Mattsson, N. and Sellers, R. (2004). Technology learning in the ETP model. Paper presented at the 6th IAEE European Conference, Zurich, Switzerland.
Goldstein, D. and Rosenfeld, A. (1976). Projecting an Energy-efficient California. LBL-3274/EEB 76–1. Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory.
Golove, W. H. and Eto, J. H. (1996). Market Barriers to Energy Efficiency: A Critical Reappraisal of the Rationale for Public Policies to Promote Energy Efficiency. Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanson, D. and Laitner, J. A. S. (2004). An integrated analysis of policies that increase investments in advanced energy-efficiency/low-carbon technologies. Energy Economics 26(4), 739–755.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hourcade, J. and Shukla, P. (2001). Global, regional, and national costs and ancillary benefits of mitigation. In Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, ed. Metz, B., Davidson, O., Swart, R. and Pan, J.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Interlaboratory Working Group (2000). Scenarios for a Clean Energy Future. Oak Ridge, TN: Oak Ridge National Laboratory; and Berkeley, CA: Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory), ORNL/CON-476 and LBNL-44029, November.
IPCC (2001). Climate Change 2001: Synthesis Report. Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, ed. , R. T. Watson. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Jaccard, M., Nyboer, J., Bataille, C. and Sadownik, B. (2003). Modeling the cost of climate policy: distinguishing between alternative cost definitions and long-run cost dynamics. The Energy Journal 24(1), 49–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jaffe, A. and Stavins, R. (1994). The energy efficiency gap: what does it mean?Energy Policy 22(10), 804–810.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kanudia, A. and Loulou, R. (1998). Robust response to climate change via stochastic MARKAL: the case of Quebec. European Journal of Operations Research 106, 15–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koomey, J., Richey, C., Laitner, S., Markel, R. and Marnay, C. (1998). Technology and GHG Emission: An Integrated Analysis Using the LBNL-NEMS Model. Berkeley, CA: LBNL Report 42054.Google Scholar
Krause, F., Haites, E., Howarth, R. and Koomey, J. (1993). Cutting Carbon Emissions: Burden or Benefit? The Economics of Energy-tax and Non-price Policies. El Cerrito, CA: International Project for Sustainable Energy.Google Scholar
Krause, F., Koomey, J. and Olivier, D. (1999). Cutting Carbon Emissions while Saving Money: Low Risk Strategies for the European Union. Executive Summary in Energy Policy in the Greenhouse. Vol. II, Part 2IPSEP, International Project for Sustainable Energy Paths, El Cerrito CA. November 33 p.
Krause, F., De Canio, S., Hoerner, J. A. and Baer, P. (2003). Cutting carbon emissions at a profit (Part II): Impacts on US competitiveness and jobs. Contemporary Economic Policy, 21 (No. 1), 90–105.CrossRef
Laitner, J. A. S. and Sanstad, A. H. (2004). Learning-by-doing on both the demand and the supply sides: implications for electric utility investments in a heuristic model. International Journal of Energy Technology and Policy 2(1–2), 142–152.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Loulou, L., Kanudia, A., Labriet, M., Margolick, M. and Vaillancourt, K. (2000). Integration of GHG Abatement Options for Canada with the MARKAL Model. Report prepared for the National Process on Climate Change and the Analysis and Modeling Group, Canadian Government.
Michaelowa, A., Stronzik, M., Eckermann, F. and Hunt, A. (2003). Transaction costs of the Kyoto mechanisms. Climate Policy 3(3), 261–226.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nakicenovic, N., Grubler, A. and McDonald, A. (eds.) (1998). Global Energy Perspectives.Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
National Audit Office (2004). The UK Emissions Trading Scheme: A New Way to Combat Climate Change. Ordered by the House of Commons.
Reddy, A. K. N. (1991). Barriers to improvements in energy efficiency. Energy Policy 19, 953–961.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rosenfeld, A. (1999). The art of energy efficiency: protecting the environment with better technology. Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 24, 33–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sathaye, J. and Ketoff, A. (1991). CO2 emissions from major developing countries: better understanding the role of energy in the long term. The Energy Journal 12(1), 161–171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sathaye, J. and Murtishaw, S. (2004). Market Failures, Consumer Preferences, and Transaction Costs in Energy Efficiency Purchase Decisions. CEC-500–2005–020/LBNL-57318. Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory for the California Energy Commission, PIER Energy-Related Environmental Research.
Sathaye, J. and Phadke, A. (2004). Cost and carbon emissions of coal and combined cycle power plants in India: implications for costs of climate mitigation projects in a nascent market. Energy Policy 34, 1619–1629.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sathaye, J., Schipper L. and Levine, M. (1986). Growth in LDC Oil Demand: Implications and Opportunities for the US. Presentations to William F. Martin, Deputy Secretary, US Department of Energy, Washington DC.
Sathaye, J., Ghirardi, A. and Schipper, L. (1987). Energy demand in developing countries: a sectoral analysis of recent trends. Annual Review of Energy 12, 253–281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sathaye, J., Bouille D., Biswas, D. et al. (2001a). Barriers, opportunities, and market potential of technologies and practices. In Climate Change 2001: Mitigation. Contribution of Working Group III to the Third Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, ed. Metz, B., Davidson, O., Swart, R. and Pan, J.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sathaye, J., Maundi, W., Andrasko, K.et al. (2001b). Carbon mitigation potential and costs of forestry options in Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Mexico, the Philippines, and Tanzania. Mitigation and Adaptation Strategies for Global Change 6 (3–4), 185–211.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schipper, L., Meyers, S., Howarth, R. and Steiner, R. (1992). Energy Efficiency and Human Activity: Past Trends, Future Prospects. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Schumacher, K. and Sathaye, J. (1999). Carbon emissions trends for developing countries and countries with economies in transition. Quarterly Journal of Economic Research 4, Special Issue: Energy Structures Past 2000.Google Scholar
Stoft, S. (1995). The economics of conserved-energy supply curves. The Energy Journal 16 (4), 109–137.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Worrell, E., Laitner, J. A., Ruth, M. and Finman, H. (2003). Productivity benefits of industrial energy efficiency measures. Energy 28 (11), 1081–1098.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×