The 100-year life, if it becomes a reality, will bring daunting challenges as well as highly skewed gains. First, longer lives will be a blessing only if they come with gains in mental and physical health that last well into the last decade of those lives, and the extra years of life and health are likely to be distributed very unequally both across and within societies. Indeed, recent declines in life expectancy in the US point to the disturbing possibility that poorer and less-educated Americans might be looking at both shorter and less healthy lives for the foreseeable future.Footnote 1 Growing inequality thus casts a shadow over this chapter’s exploration of the implications of longer lifespans for the future of work and work law in the US – the world’s richest and, on some accounts, most unequal country.Footnote 2
Among the more profound challenges of the 100-year life will be to our already-frayed patchwork system of retirement security.Footnote 3 It is hard to imagine how either most individuals or the society as a whole will be able to fund more than three decades of reasonably comfortable retirement on the basis of four decades or so of workforce participation.Footnote 4 Without a very large (and arguably unjustifiedFootnote 5) shift of societal resources toward supporting nonworking seniors, most of those who can extend their working lives beyond what is now normal retirement age will have to do so. That might upset expectations, depending on how fast it happens, and it will put an especially heavy burden on those whose work is physically demanding. It might even generate political turmoil of the sort recently seen in France over proposals to increase the retirement age to sixty-four.Footnote 6
Longer working lives might in turn exacerbate competition for jobs that do not require scarce or advanced skills. For their part, older workers will be hindered in that labor market competition – more than they already are – by doubts about their capabilities. Longer working lives will require us to reassess the law of age discrimination in employment (discussed at greater length in Kenji Yoshino’s chapter) and to devise new ways to ensure intergenerational equity in employment. Longer working lives will also recast the debate over job security protections and will highlight the need to make work and work schedules less demanding, especially as workers age. This chapter will explore these challenges and how they will intersect with changing technology and its impact on the nature and number of jobs.
5.1 From Longer Lives to Longer Working Lives
All existing public and private pension systems, including personal retirement savings plans, depend ultimately on working adults generating the revenues that support nonworking retirees. Some of those revenues come from workers’ employers, but let us treat that as deferred compensation and part of what workers generate through their work. Let us also put aside the deus ex machina device of injecting massive additional funds from general tax revenues; that might prove necessary, but seeing why will require first working through the problems faced under existing models. On those models, workers support their own future nonworking selves through private retirement savings, and current workers collectively support the retirement incomes of current retirees through Social Security and other public and private pension plans. All of these elements of retirement security – public and private, voluntary and mandatory – depend on maintaining a sustainable ratio between the number of active workers and of retirees, and between years of active labor market participation and years of retirement.Footnote 7 The 100-year life will test the limits of what is sustainable.
To take a crucial example, consider Social Security, whose rather modest benefits – on average, just $1,614 a month, or $19,370 a year in 2022Footnote 8 – are the only source of retirement income for many US workers, including most workers of color.Footnote 9 (As of 2020, according to the US Census Bureau, over 40 percent of those aged fifty-six to sixty-four, and larger shares of younger cohorts, had no private retirement savings.Footnote 10) In 1940, shortly after Social Security began to provide basic pensions at age sixty-five, average life expectancy in the US was sixty-two years, and the ratio between covered workers and beneficiaries was 159 to 1.Footnote 11 By 2020, average life expectancy had risen to seventy-nine years, and by 2021, the worker-to-beneficiary ratio had fallen to about 2.8 to 1.Footnote 12 Thus far, reforms have been modest: a rise in the normal retirement age to sixty-seven (for those born after 1960),Footnote 13 and higher payroll taxes to support those longer retirement periods.Footnote 14 More of both kinds of reforms will surely be needed.
Employer-sponsored retirement plans, for those lucky enough to have them, face similar demographic pressures. Such plans grew in the mid twentieth century, encouraged by tax subsidies and impelled in some sectors by collective bargaining, but they were never made mandatoryFootnote 15 and were largely unregulated until the Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 (ERISA).Footnote 16 Back in the day, most employer-sponsored and collectively bargained pension plans were, like Social Security, “defined benefit” plans: They promised workers a specific monthly pension depending on age and years of service at the time of retirement; rising life expectancies thus necessitated higher employer contributions. That fact, and perhaps also ERISA’s tighter regulation of defined benefit plans, helped to spur employers’ sharp shift in recent decades to “defined contribution” plans, in which employers promise no particular benefit levels in the future but contribute some small percentage of each paycheck to individuals’ retirement savings.Footnote 17 Those plans banish the problem of unfunded employer liabilities, but they put the whole risk of financial mismanagement, underfunding, and underperformance on individuals, who are often ill-equipped both to manage assets and to weather economic downturns.Footnote 18 In the meantime, many public pension plans – which are unregulated by ERISA and mostly still of the defined benefit type – have begun to teeter or even topple under the weight of nearly $4 trillion in estimated unfunded liabilities.Footnote 19
How will this picture change with the advent of the 100-year life? The basic actuarial challenge of longer lifespans is quite simple: If the normal retirement age held steady, the burden of supporting longer retirement periods would require either higher contributions and savings during working lives (meaning lower disposable incomes for current workers), or lower benefit levels for retirees. A simple example from Gratton and Scott underscores the challenge: Suppose an individual born in 1998 (age twenty-five as of 2023), with a life expectancy of 100, hopes to retire at age sixty-five on an income that is half her average income during her working years (plus whatever Social Security provides). To reach that goal, she would have to accumulate savings (and employer contributions if she is lucky) amounting to 25 percent of her income during her entire remaining working life.Footnote 20 Some high earners – those whose income amply exceeds their living costs – will be able to save enough during their working lives to support a long and comfortable retirement. (Ironically, many of those high earners might choose to postpone retirement, given their high economic and psychic returns from work.) But it is hard to see how working people who are just making ends meet will be able to accumulate those private retirement savings.
The alternative to reducing incomes either during individuals’ working lives or in retirement is to extend working lives. (Indeed, all of the above might be necessary.) Most people will have to keep working longer, if they can, in order to save enough for their own retirements and, at the societal level, to maintain a sustainable ratio of active workers to retirees and of work years to retirement years. Every additional year of paid work does double duty in terms of retirement security, both increasing pension contributions and savings and shrinking the retirement period that those funds will have to cover.
Again, it would be possible to address this problem by injecting much greater public funds into Social Security (or, more ambitiously, into something like universal basic income (UBI) throughout individuals’ lifespans). That would stave off destitution for the least well-off retirees, though it would fall short of maintaining living standards for most people. And it would shift part of the burden of funding pensions off the platform of employment, which might make sense for a variety of reasons (which I explore elsewhere).Footnote 21 But the appeal of such solutions will depend partly on what the alternative of longer working lives would look like. So before considering large-scale redistributive public funding of pensions, let us assume here that, one way or another, workers and their employers will continue to fund pensions through a combination of savings, payroll taxes, and employer contributions. With the advent of the 100-year life, that will translate into longer working lives for many.
Some people will be unable to work longer due to age-related infirmities – including cognitive declineFootnote 22 – or simply the wear and tear from decades of physically demanding work. Their economic fates will mostly ride (in the US) on the future shape of Social Security’s retirement program. The rest of this chapter will focus instead on the implications of a growing cohort of older workers and would-be workers, especially in light of other likely changes in work and labor markets.
5.2 How Workplace Technology Will Interact with Longer Working Lives
As lifespans grow over the next few decades, other trends in the landscape of work will not stand still. In particular, some observers expect overall demand for labor to decline gradually but inexorably as innovations in robotics, artificial intelligence, and machine learning encroach on the comparative advantages of human workers.Footnote 23 That is hardly conventional wisdom among economists. By 2019, however, leading labor economists at MIT had concluded that, unlike in past waves of technological innovation, automation was already destroying more mid skill jobs than it was creating and was a major cause of labor market polarization.Footnote 24 They still projected growing demand for highly skilled labor, and for workers in health care and elder care across the skill spectrum, given the needs of an aging population.Footnote 25 But without huge advances in education and training, high demand for skilled labor might translate into job vacancies that are out of reach for the vast majority of workers. And the other side of an aging population explored above – that is, a probably growing supply of labor from older workers and job-seekers – does not factor into the MIT forecast. Those two caveats alone might point toward a sizable job gap in a decade or two.
We have not yet factored in other potential countervailing demographic trends that, according to the 2019 MIT report, “point towards rising labor scarcity in the decades ahead.”Footnote 26 In particular, lower birth rates in developed countries mean fewer new entrants to the labor force (putting aside immigration). But longer life expectancies throw a curveball into predictions of labor scarcity.Footnote 27 The MIT researchers note that growth in the older population will increase demand for workers in health care and elder care, but they don’t consider the prospect of longer working lives – that is, older workers seeking or holding onto jobs past “normal” retirement age. In some aging societies of Europe and Asia, a growing cohort of healthy older workers (as well as productivity improvements arising from automation) could help offset the shrinking flow of new entrants into the labor market.Footnote 28 The US population is younger and is aging more slowly than that of much of the developed world.Footnote 29 Still, longer working lives would make job deficits more likely than MIT experts predicted in 2019.
Two other developments since the MIT report – the splashy debut of “generative AI” such as Chat-GPT, and COVID-19 – might further swell job losses. The impact of generative AI is the quintessential “moving target” whose advances and failures feature daily in newsfeeds. Yet few doubt that it boosts the potential for automating the work of those who analyze data or produce words (or computer code) for a living, among others.Footnote 30
As for COVID-19, leading experts on automation, including the MIT folks, quickly tagged it as an accelerant of job destruction via several pathways.Footnote 31 First, economic downturns, whatever their cause, tend to spur adoption of labor-saving technologies.Footnote 32 Second, COVID highlighted the risks – and not only the health risks – associated with human labor. After all, “robots don’t need face masks, health care, or social distancing, and they don’t go on strike for better conditions.”Footnote 33 Third, COVID triggered a dramatic shift in the large retail sector both toward automation of brick-and-mortar retail and toward e-commerce, both of which reduce demand for human labor.Footnote 34 It “compress[ed] into a few short months what would otherwise have unfolded over multiple years.”Footnote 35 Fourth, the spike in remote work and meetings would usher in lasting “reductions in office occupancy, daily commuting trips, and business excursions” and “steep declines in demand for … workers who feed, transport, clothe, entertain, and shelter people when they are not in their own homes.”Footnote 36 By and large, these early predictions have been borne out.Footnote 37 Apart from its human death toll, the lasting legacy of COVID-19 might include sizable job losses,Footnote 38 notwithstanding the post-COVID rise of labor shortagesFootnote 39 (which, as noted earlier, carry their own tendency to spur automation).Footnote 40
All in all, a more automated future of less work – especially for those without advanced skills – appears likely enough that we should begin to ponder and plan for that future.Footnote 41 In particular, if automation depresses demand for ordinarily skilled human labor over the next few decades, then older workers who cannot afford to retire will be competing with younger workers for a shrinking number of decent jobs. That is, the convergence of demographic and technological trends could produce a double whammy: fewer work opportunities for a larger number of job-seekers.
Technology will affect the nature as well as the number of jobs. To begin with, more jobs will require working with technology, and the pace of technological change is more likely to speed up than slow down. That will tend to reduce the relative value of cumulative work experience versus newly minted skills. Back in the heyday of “lifetime employment,” labor economists sought to explain long job tenures and rising wages in core sectors of the economy.Footnote 42 They argued that the experience and tacit knowledge that workers accumulated on the job increased their productivity for many years (though not quite until retirement); long-term job security (until the then-standard and even mandatory retirement age) served to encourage workers to stay and share their tacit knowledge with younger workers. But those patterns were undercut in part by technological change: The value of accumulated experience declined as the skill demands of jobs began to change in ever-shorter cycles.Footnote 43 As that pattern continues, older workers will be burdened by both the reality of aging brains and skill sets and stereotypes about their facility with new technologies.Footnote 44
All of these technologically driven trends underscore the need for much better institutions of basic education and new and better pathways for adults to learn new skills on and off the job and to change occupations over the course of their careers. That is an article of faith among those who study technology’s evolving impact on work;Footnote 45 and it is one obvious implication of the 100-year life.Footnote 46 More and better training will ameliorate but not eliminate the challenges of changing workplace technologies for older workers, as well as the job gap that might open up with growing machine capabilities.Footnote 47
Technology will affect the nature as well as the number of jobs and can be deployed in ways that either help or hurt older workers. On the one hand, machines can take over physically demanding tasks in some jobs (as they have been doing for centuries). For example, robots can do the literal heavy-lifting of human bodies in elder care and of mattresses in hotel room cleaning.Footnote 48 Reducing cumulative physical wear and tear might enable some workers to extend their working lives. On the other hand, many employers use technology to intensify the pace of work by monitoring every working moment and movement and squeezing out seconds and minutes of downtime.Footnote 49 The resulting “burnout” could undercut older workers’ ability to keep at it. The use of such technologies at Amazon’s Bessemer warehouse was both a major impetus and a major impediment to union organizing, which takes place largely through conversations among coworkers.Footnote 50 These dimensions of workplace technology underscore both the importance and the difficulty of ensuring that workers have a meaningful voice at work, as explored by Kate Andrias in this volume and by Brishen Rogers elsewhere.Footnote 51
There are obvious upsides of technological change. Automation is likely to significantly boost productivity and yield enormous economic dividends. Those dividends could be redistributed to ordinary workers in the form of higher incomes, more leisure, or both and could further mitigate the daunting challenge of longer working lives. Or they might continue to flow overwhelmingly to the top of the income scale, as they have in recent decades. Let’s now shift to the policy plane.
5.3 Two Strategies for Extending Working Lives: Securing Jobs and Spreading Work
Let us assume that, a few decades hence, most people will be in the active labor market, either working or seeking work, into their seventies or beyond. Some will seek “self-employment” – nominally or actually independent work outside the relatively protective umbrella of employment, including work in the expanding “gig economy.” That might be a decent option for some older workers with specialized skills or capital to invest in a business, but it will be at best a fallback option for workers without those advantages, whatever their age. I’ll focus here on what longer working lives are likely to mean within the sphere of employment.
In order to continue working later in life, workers will have to hold onto jobs longer or find new jobs late in life. Both job-keeping and job-seeking are affected by age discrimination and stereotypes, and sometimes by real deterioration in skills or capabilities. Discrimination against older job applicants is especially likely, as stereotypes tend to carry more weight when employers have less information about, and no actual experience with, an individual.Footnote 52 And hiring discrimination is especially difficult to uncover, challenge, and deter through antidiscrimination law: Nonhiring decisions are relatively opaque to rejected applicants and are difficult and unlikely to be challenged.Footnote 53 Older job applicants already meet hiring resistance, partly due to age discrimination; their even older counterparts in the future are likely to encounter at least as much resistance. But the magnitude of that problem will depend partly on older workers’ ability to hold onto their jobs and avoid dismissals or layoffs, and that depends not only on the efficacy of discrimination laws but also on protections against arbitrary or unjustified dismissal.
Nearly all economically developed nations require employers to justify most dismissals based on legitimate reasons such as poor performance, misconduct, or economic necessity.Footnote 54 In the US, by contrast, the vast majority of workers can be fired at will – at any time and without justification.Footnote 55 Employment at will is the rule, and job security the exception, in both private and public sector employment, and exceptions are largely confined to the shrinking union sector and the civil service. In theory, individuals can bargain for job security, but that rarely happens for reasons explored by legions of US employment law scholars.Footnote 56 Employment at will no longer means – as it did a century ago – that employees can be fired for any reason at all. Many reasons for dismissal, including age discrimination, are now illegal, and that probably discourages many unjustified dismissals.Footnote 57 But prohibiting discrimination is a far cry from requiring just cause for dismissal, for the former puts the burden of proof of unlawful motive on the employee, and such proof can be very hard to come by. Moreover, some workers pose little risk of litigation, such as low-wage workers in high-turnover jobs (or the growing number of workers bound by mandatory arbitration agreements).Footnote 58
Overturning employment at will and mandating job security would bolster all of workers’ rights on the job and would better enable workers to demand overtime pay, complain of discrimination or harassment, or support unionization.Footnote 59 It would also promote both economic security and stability within workplace communities, with a range of individual and social benefits. And it would enable older workers to keep their jobs longer. The likely necessity of longer working lives is one more argument in favor of joining the rest of the developed world and protecting job security.
Importantly, employment protections might facilitate longer working lives not just by inhibiting dismissals but also by boosting workers’ productivity. How so? By encouraging employers to invest in incumbent workers’ skills rather than replacing them with newly credentialed new hires (or machines).Footnote 60 That might help to explain recent findings on the economic impact of employment protection laws (EPLs) – those regulating dismissals and layoffs and use of temporary workers.
The conventional economic wisdom, long touted by the World Bank, held that EPL discouraged hiring by taxing dismissals, to the detriment of economic dynamism and workers’ overall welfare.Footnote 61 But that conventional wisdom has met mounting contrary evidence. A major Cambridge University-based study of 117 countries over several decades found that EPL stringency has modest but mostly positive long-term effects on national economic performance, including slightly lower unemployment and a higher labor share of national income.Footnote 62 (Even the World Bank has now acknowledged that “employment regulations are unquestionably necessary” and “benefit both workers and firms.”Footnote 63) One explanation for these somewhat-surprising results is that investments in worker training – which make sense in a world of job security – appear to complement employment protections. That includes public spending on “active labor market policies,” including vocational training as well as employer investments in on-the-job training, all of which are much greater in most OECD countries than in the US.Footnote 64 Those investments should modestly slow the technological displacement of incumbent workers and better enable older workers to hang onto their jobs, extend their working lives, and build up their retirement assets.
One might worry, of course, that job security protects older incumbent workers to the detriment of younger entrants to the labor market. While some studies have linked more stringent EPL with higher youth unemployment,Footnote 65 the latest word, based on the aforementioned Cambridge studies, finds no long-term adverse impact on youth employment.Footnote 66 Concerns about youth employment should find their solution not in weaker employment protections but in dedicated investments in young people’s education and employment prospects and in strengthening the foundations for longer and more varied work lives.
Longer working lives will also be more feasible if the demands of work are less intensive. Technology could contribute on that score not only by taking over physically demanding work tasks, as noted above, but also by allowing for shorter working hours. A more automated economy might augur a future of too little or no work for many workers, but it could be steered in the direction of less work for nearly all – that is, fewer hours per week or fewer weeks per year or both, with guaranteed rights to take extra time off or work shorter schedules as needed. As Anne Alstott has recognized, older workers in particular would value the ability to scale back working hours as they age.Footnote 67 Elsewhere I propose a range of strategies for reducing overall hours of work for those with too much of it and for spreading work to those with too little.Footnote 68 Those include guaranteed paid vacations and family and sick leaves, guaranteed access to part-time schedules, wider eligibility for overtime pay and other deterrents to excessive and intrusive work demands, and eventually a shorter standard work week. Together, those strategies would help to meet the challenge of a future of less work, promote a better work–life balance for individuals, and facilitate longer working lives by reducing the cumulative toll of decades of work and by accommodating the distinctive toll aging can exact on physical and mental stamina.
5.4 Conclusion
When we ponder the many and daunting challenges that longer working lives will pose for both individuals and the society, we might ask: Wouldn’t it be more sensible – both more humane and more efficient – to maintain the current normal retirement age and find ways to publicly fund longer periods of retirement, at least for those who can’t afford to do so themselves, through taxes and transfers? In particular, why compound the challenge posed by automation and a future of less work by extending working lives and increasing the supply of older workers? These are more than fair questions (even if their empirical premises are still debated). But they suggest other questions.
First, if we can muster the political will for that much taxing and spending, how much of it should we direct to the support of retirees? There is no shortage of compelling demands on those societal resources – the needs of the poor and especially poor children, including severe housing insecurity; underfunded educational institutions at every level; unmet healthcare needs, which will rise in an aging society; climate change and its associated costs; and a societal debt from centuries of racial injustice. With all those needs in mind, could it possibly make sense to direct a large share of social resources to supporting seniors, many of whom might be capable of supporting themselves through remunerative work for many years to come?
Second, what are the implications of most people spending the last three to four decades of their lives outside of the nexus of paid work? If the question were simply about individual preferences – when would most people choose to retire if they expected to live to 100? – the answer would obviously vary widely. Many tenured academics, for example, are already choosing to delay retirement, so that “between 2000 and 2010 the proportion of all professors 65 and older nearly doubled, and the median age of the professorate now surpasses all other occupational groups.”Footnote 69 Most jobs are much less rewarding and more draining, physically and psychically, than ours. Even so, many people have mixed feelings about leaving the workforce when they still have energy and skills to contribute.Footnote 70
Consider also the social and political implications of longer retirements versus longer working lives. If most people continued to retire from work in their mid to late sixties even as life expectancies climb toward a century, retirees would soon make up a quarter or more of the population and a larger share of the electorate. The workplace is not only a source of economic sustenance, status, and identity; it is also our society’s single greatest cauldron of cooperation and integration, especially across lines of social division.Footnote 71 Most people’s social circles grow much smaller and less diverse once they retire. As that group swells, the political and social distance between seniors and others will become wider and more consequential, and the potential for intergenerational political conflict will grow.
Ours will be a more vibrant, fair, and cohesive polity and society if we instead find ways to make work less draining and more fulfilling, to spread work from those with too much of it to those with too little, and to enable people to work for more years but fewer hours per year and per week, especially as they grow older.