Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-x24gv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-23T00:56:42.800Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

10 - Effective Solutions for Real-World Stackelberg Games: When Agents Must Deal with Human Uncertainties

from PART IV - FUTURE RESEARCH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 January 2012

Get access

Summary

Introduction

In Stackelberg games, one player, the leader, commits to a strategy publicly before the remaining players, the followers, make their decisions (Fudenberg and Tirole, 1991). There are many multi-agent security domains, such as attacker-defender scenarios and patrolling, for which these types of commitments by the security agent are necessary (Agmon et al., 2008; Brown et al., 2006; Kiekintveld et al., 2009; Paruchuri et al., 2006), and it has been shown that Stackelberg games appropriately model these commitments (Paruchuri et al., 2008; Pita et al., 2008). For example, security personnel patrolling an infrastructure decide on a patrolling strategy first, before their adversaries act taking this committed strategy into account. Indeed, Stackelberg games are at the heart of theARMOR system, deployed at LAX since 2007 to schedule security personnel (Paruchuri et al., 2008; Pita et al., 2008), and they have recently been applied to federal air marshals (Kiekintveld et al., 2009). Moreover, these games have potential applications for network routing and pricing in transportation systems, among many others possibilities (Cardinal et al., 2005; Korilis, Lazar, and Orda, 1997).

Existing algorithms for Bayesian Stackelberg games find optimal solutions considering an a priori probability distribution over possible follower types (Conitzer and Sandholm, 2006; Paruchuri et al., 2008). Unfortunately, to guarantee optimality, these algorithms make strict assumptions on the underlying games; namely, that players are perfectly rational and that followers perfectly observe the leader's strategy. However, these assumptions rarely hold in real-world domains, particularly those involving human actors.

Type
Chapter
Information
Security and Game Theory
Algorithms, Deployed Systems, Lessons Learned
, pp. 193 - 212
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2011

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

M., Aghassi and D., Bertsimas. Robust game theory. Math. Program., 107(1–2):231–273, 2006.Google Scholar
N., Agmon, V., Sadov, S., Kraus, and G., Kaminka. The impact of adversarial knowledge on adversarial planning in perimeter patrol. In International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (AAMAS), 2008.Google Scholar
G., Brown, M., Carlyle, J., Salmerón, and K., Wood. Defending Critical Infrastructure. Interfaces, 2006.
J., Cardinal, M., Labbé, S., Langerman, and B., Palop. Pricing of geometric transportation networks. In 17th Canadian Conference on Computational Geometry, 2005.Google Scholar
V., Conitzer and T., Sandholm. Computing the optimal strategy to commit to. In International Conference on Electronic Commerce (EC), 2006.Google Scholar
M., Friedman. The use of ranks to avoid the assumption of normality implicit in the analysis of variance. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 32 No. 100:675–701, 1937.Google Scholar
D., Fudenberg and J., Tirole. Game Theory. MIT Press, 1991.Google Scholar
J. C., Harsanyi and R., Selten. A generalized Nash solution for two-person bargaining games with incomplete information. Management Science, 18(5):80–106, 1972.Google Scholar
C., Kiekintveld, M., Jain, J., Tsai, J., Pita, M., Tambe, and F., Ordóñez. Computing Optimal Randomized Resource Allocations for Massive Security Games. In International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (AAMAS), 2009.Google Scholar
Y. A., Korilis, A. A., Lazar, and A., Orda. Achieving network optima using stackelberg routing strategies. In IEEE/ACM Transactions on Networking, 1997.Google Scholar
A., Nilim and L. E., Ghaoui. Robustness in markov decision problems with uncertain transition matrices. In Conference on Neural Information Processing Systems (NIPS), 2004.Google Scholar
F., Ordóñez and N. E., Stier-Moses. Robust wardrop equilibrium. In Workshop on Network Control and Optimization (NET-COOP), 2007.Google Scholar
P., Paruchuri, J., Marecki, J., Pearce, M., Tambe, F., Ordóñez, and S., Kraus. Playing games for security: An efficient exact algorithm for solving bayesian stackelberg games. In International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (AAMAS), 2008.Google Scholar
P., Paruchuri, M., Tambe, F., Ordonez, and S., Kraus. Security in multiagent systems by policy randomization. In International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (AAMAS), 2006.Google Scholar
J., Pita, M., Jain, J., Marecki, F., Ordóñez, C., Portway, M., Tambe, C., Western, P., Paruchuri, and S., Kraus. Deployed armor protection: The application of a game theoretic model for security at the los angeles international airport. In International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems (AAMAS), 2008.Google Scholar
A., Rubinstein. Modeling Bounded Rationality. MIT Press, 1998.Google Scholar
K. E., See, C. R., Fox, and Y. S., Rottenstreich. Between ignorance and truth: Partition dependence and learning in judgment under uncertainty. Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition, 32:1385–1402, 2006.Google Scholar
H., Simon. Rational choice and the structure of the environment. Psychological Review, 63:129–138, 1956.Google Scholar
A., Tversky and D. J., Koehler. Support thoery: A nonextensional representation of subjective probability. Psychological Review, 101:547–567, 1994.Google Scholar
B., von Stengel and S., Zamir. Leadership with commitment to mixed strategies. Technical Report London School of Economics-Centre for Discrete and Applicable Mathematics (LSE-CDAM)-2004-01, CDAM Research Report, 2004.
K. K., Yuen. The two-sample trimmed t for unequal population variances. Biometrika, 61:165–170, 1974.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure coreplatform@cambridge.org is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×