Hostname: page-component-cb9f654ff-mwwwr Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2025-08-02T16:37:01.704Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Social Pressure and Voter Turnout: Evidence from a Large-Scale Field Experiment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  01 February 2008

ALAN S. GERBER*
Affiliation:
Yale University
DONALD P. GREEN*
Affiliation:
Yale University
CHRISTOPHER W. LARIMER*
Affiliation:
University of Northern Iowa
*
Alan S. Gerber is Professor, Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, CT 06520 (alan.gerber@yale.edu).
Donald P. Green is Professor, Department of Political Science, Yale University, New Haven, CT 06520.
Christopher W. Larimer is Assistant Professor, Department of Political Science, University of Northern Iowa, 1227 West 27th Street, Cedar Falls, IA 50614.
Get access
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Voter turnout theories based on rational self-interested behavior generally fail to predict significant turnout unless they account for the utility that citizens receive from performing their civic duty. We distinguish between two aspects of this type of utility, intrinsic satisfaction from behaving in accordance with a norm and extrinsic incentives to comply, and test the effects of priming intrinsic motives and applying varying degrees of extrinsic pressure. A large-scale field experiment involving several hundred thousand registered voters used a series of mailings to gauge these effects. Substantially higher turnout was observed among those who received mailings promising to publicize their turnout to their household or their neighbors. These findings demonstrate the profound importance of social pressure as an inducement to political participation.

Information

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © American Political Science Association 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Article purchase

Temporarily unavailable

Among the most striking features of democratic political systems is the participation of millions of voters in elections. Why do large numbers of people vote, despite the fact that, as Hegel once observed, “the casting of a single vote is of no significance where there is a multitude of electors”? One hypothesis is adherence to social norms. Voting is widely regarded as a citizen duty (Blais Reference Blais2000), and citizens worry that others will think less of them if they fail to participate in elections. Voters' sense of civic duty has long been a leading explanation of voter turnout among both behavioral (Campbell, Gurin, and Miller Reference Campbell, Gurin and Miller1954) and formal (Downs Reference Downs1957; Riker and Ordeshook Reference Riker and Ordershook1968) theories of voter turnout.

Even those scholars who are sympathetic to this line of argument nonetheless concede that the theoretical and empirical basis for this hypothesis remains thin (Feddersen Reference Feddersen2004). At a theoretical level, the notion that voters receive psychic utility from voting is murky, insofar as it fails to distinguish between the intrinsic rewards that voters obtain from performing this duty and the extrinsic rewards that voters receive when others observe them doing so. As Knack (Reference Knack1992) and Harbaugh (Reference Harbaugh1996) point out, intrinsic and extrinsic incentives have very different empirical implications. Although most scholarly attention has focused on the “expressive benefits” of voting, Harbaugh argues that widespread overreporting of voting in surveys signals the potential importance of extrinsic incentives. This suspicion accords with a large literature in social psychology, which emphasizes the extent to which other-regarding behavior varies depending on whether people perceive their actions to be public (Cialdini and Goldstein Reference Cialdini and Goldstein2004; Cialdini and Trost Reference Cialdini, Trost, Gilbert, Fiske and Lindzey1998; Lerner and Tetlock Reference Lerner and Tetlock1999).

The empirical literature on the effects of social norms on voting has not advanced much beyond the initial survey work on this topic during the 1950s. Researchers have frequently used cross-sectional survey data to show that people who report feeling a greater sense of civic duty are also more likely to report voting. However, such observational evidence is frequently a misleading guide to causality; it may be that espousing the virtue of voting is a symptom, not a cause, of being a voter. Similarly, it is sometimes pointed out that people whose friends and coworkers vote at high rates are themselves more likely to vote (Huckfeldt and Sprague Reference Huckfeldt and Sprague1995). Although this empirical regularity is consistent with the idea that voting is more likely when participatory norms prevail in one's social network, it is also consistent with other explanations, including affinity among people with similar political outlooks and group level differences in exposure to political campaigns. The ready availability of alternative explanations implies that, despite observed correlations, the key question remains unresolved: to what extent do social norms cause voter turnout?

This study departs from prior work on this subject by conducting an experiment designed to prime voters to think about civic duty while at the same time applying different amounts of social pressure in order to induce them to adhere to this norm. Unlike most previous experiments, which have taken place in laboratory settings, ours takes place in the context of an actual election. Prior to the August 2006 primary election in Michigan, approximately 80,000 households were sent one of four mailings encouraging them to vote. The content of these mailings was inspired by historical and cross-national examples of policies that publicized the names of voters and nonvoters (Lijphart Reference Lijphart1997). One experimental group received a mailing that merely reminded them that voting is a civic duty; in a second group, they were told that researchers would be studying their turnout based on public records; a third treatment group received mailings displaying the record of turnout among those in the household; a fourth mailing revealed both the household's voter turnout and their neighbors' turnout. The latter two treatments suggested that a follow-up mailing after the election would report to the household or the neighborhood the subject's turnout in the upcoming election.

Our study makes several important contributions. First, we provide strong statistical evidence that social pressure increases voter turnout. This finding is by no means obvious, for the literature in social psychology is divided between two sets of empirical findings, one emphasizing the tendency to comply with social norms (see Cialdini and Goldstein Reference Cialdini and Goldstein2004 for a review; see Gerber and Rugers Reference Gerber and Rogers2007 for an application to political behavior) and the other calling attention to “reactance” (Brehm and Brehm Reference Brehm and Brehm1981) or “boomerang effects” (Ringold Reference Ringold2002) in which receivers reject heavy-handed demands. According to Ringold and Steward and Martin (Reference Stewart and Martin1994), for example, public health messages concerning smoking, alcohol, drugs, and diet frequently lead to less compliance with the normative message.Footnote 1

Notwithstanding the potential for reactance, the influence of a single piece of direct mail turns out to be formidable when (and only when) social pressure is exerted. Exposing a person's voting record to his or her neighbors turns out to be an order of magnitude more effective than conventional pieces of partisan or nonpartisan direct mail (cf. Cardy Reference Cardy2005; Gerber, Green, and Green Reference Gerber, Green and Green2003; Ramirez Reference Gerber, Green and Green2005). In fact, the turnout effect associated with this mailing is as strong as the effect of direct contact by door-to-door canvassers (Green, Gerber, and Nickerson Reference Green, Gerber and Nickerson2003; Michelson Reference Michelson2005) and by far the most cost-effective voter mobilization tactic studied to date. Third, our experimental results also address the broad issue of how the content of a political communication affects political behavior. Previous experimental studies of voter mobilization have found that the way in which a turnout appeal is delivered has a critical effect on the effectiveness of the appeal. Personal, unhurried appeals are usually far superior to impersonal, mechanical and rushed communications (Gerber and Green Reference Gerber and Green2000). The content of the message, however, consistently had little effect on whether the communication produced higher turnout, a fact that may reflect the similarity of the tested messages or the inattentive manner in which voters hear or read them (Gerber and Green Reference Gerber and Green2000; Trivedi Reference Trivedi2005). Here we test four alternative mailers with widely varying messages (but devoid of eye-catching graphics, colors, or format) and find sizeable and statistically significant differences in their relative effectiveness. Finally, by showing the extent to which voting rates change as a function of social pressure, our results speak to the enduring paradox of participation in large electorates while at the same time shedding light on the large dropoff in turnout that accompanied the transition from public balloting to secret balloting at the end of the nineteenth century. In sum, the evidence presented here casts new light on theories of collective action and on the role of institutions that affect the degree to which voting behavior is subject to surveillance and social sanction.

SOCIAL NORMS, THE CALCULUS OF VOTING, AND PRIOR RESEARCH

Social norms are rules of conduct that are socially enforced. The causal influence of norms may be divided conceptually into three categories. First is the awareness or recognition of norms. Some rules of conduct, such as removing one's glove before shaking hands, are relatively unknown, whereas others, such as holding the door for an elderly person, are widely recognized. The expectation that citizens should vote on Election Day is nowadays widely acknowledged, although one can think of periods in history when this was not the case. The second aspect of norms is internalization, the acceptance of particular norms as proper and applicable, even when they impose costs. Honoring the dead, for example, is a norm that is widely accepted, whereas bowing one's head before superiors is not, at least not in the West. Internalization of voting norms varies across individuals, and scholars have long observed that “the more strongly a person feels a sense of obligation to discharge his civic duties, the more likely he is to be politically active” (Campbell, Gurin, and Miller Reference Campbell, Gurin and Miller1954, 199). Finally, enforcement of norms varies from disdain to ostracism to outright violence. Expectations of enforcement may induce compliance among those who recognize a norm but have not internalized it.

The extensive social psychological literature on the internalization and enforcement of norms attests to their powerful influence on behavior. People are attentive to the behavior modeled by others and internalize norms readily, especially when those around them provide clear signals about what types of conduct are considered appropriate (Scheff Reference Scheff2000). With regard to enforcement or anticipated enforcement, people are found to be highly sensitive to the perceptions of others, even strangers, and surveillance increases the likelihood of norm-compliant behavior (Rind and Benjamin Reference Rind and Benjamin1994; Posner and Rasmusen Reference Posner and Rasmusen1999). Compliance with norms of reciprocity, for example, is powerfully shaped by whether one's behavior is publicly visible (Whatley et al. Reference Whatley, Webster, Smith and Rhodes1999).

These general psychological propositions about norms have been verified not only in the lab but also in field settings. Schultz (Reference Schultz1999), for example, reports the results of a field experiment on the frequency and amount of recycling among families over a 17-week period. The manipulation in Schultz's experiment was the nature of social feedback that people receive concerning their behavior. When individuals received weekly updates on their own recycling behavior (individual feedback) or weekly updates about the average recycling behavior of those in their residential area (group feedback), participation in the recycling program and the amount of material recycled increased over time. By contrast, mere dissemination of information regarding the environmental benefits of recycling did not produce significant increases in recycling participation or the amount recycled. The results of this experiment and others (cf. Webster et al. Reference Webster, Duvall, Gaines and Smith2003) suggest that public disclosure of norm-related behavior significantly increases compliance with norms.

The policy implications of norm-enforcement have not been lost on lawmakers. Consider, for example, compulsory voting laws that, until recently, operated in Italy. Although there is some debate as to the level of enforcement, the penalty for not voting in Italy was a form of social sanction whereby nonvoters had their names posted outside a town hall and a “certificate of good conduct” stamped with “Did not vote” (Jackman Reference Jackman1987, 409; Lijphart Reference Lijphart1997, 9; Seton-Watson Reference Seton-Watson, Bogdanor and Butler1983, 111). These “innocuous sanctions” were designed to make it potentially more difficult to find adequate daycare or employment.Footnote 2 In other words, Italy had a “shaming” policy.

To what extent these shaming tactics in fact impel people to vote is an open question. As noted earlier, the literature in social psychology is replete with examples of norm-inducement campaigns that failed to increase compliance and sometimes decreased it. Telling people “don't litter” induced more littering than telling people nothing at all, and telling people “don't you dare litter” was worse still (Brehm and Brehm Reference Brehm and Brehm1981, 333). Thus, the compliance-inducing effects of shaming and the compliance-reducing effects of heavy-handedness are in tension, which makes the net effect of a shaming campaign an open empirical question.

The Calculus of Voting

The tendency to conform to social norms in public has important implications for models of political participation. Voting, though far from universal, is widely considered a civic obligation. The “calculus of voting” model suggests that a potential benefit of voting is the satisfaction of performing one's civic duty (Downs Reference Downs1957; Riker and Ordershook Reference Riker and Ordershook1968; see also Aldrich Reference Aldrich1993; Blais Reference Blais2000, 93). Indeed, in the absence of such psychic benefits, the standard rational choice model of voting generally fails to predict significant positive turnout (Ledyard Reference Ledyard1984; Palfrey and Rosenthal Reference Palfrey and Rosenthal1985). One hypothesis about why millions of citizens nonetheless vote is that they are willing to pay the slight costs in time and effort to avoid the feelings of shame associated with not voting or, conversely, to enjoy the satisfaction of voting.

When the formal model of voting is expanded to include these psychic benefits (Riker and Ordeshook Reference Riker and Ordershook1968), a citizen votes if

(1)

\begin{equation}
\textit{pB} + \textit{D} > C.
\end{equation}

Here p is the probability the vote is pivotal, B is the difference in utility from the candidates' attributes or policy stances, D is the direct benefit from voting and C is the cost of voting. Because the probability of casting the decisive vote in an election is typically infinitesimal, the calculus of voting boils down to the relative weight of C and D.

But what is D? The convention model in equation (1) can be extended by breaking the direct benefit term (D), into its components. Suppose that the utility from D were written as

(2)

\begin{equation}
D = U(D_{I}, D_{E}), 
\end{equation}

where U is the citizen's utility from voting given D I and D E, where D I is the intrinsic benefits associated with voting, a term that captures the positive feeling the voter experiences from fulfilling a civic duty, regardless of any other consequences associated with the act, and where D E is the extrinsic benefit from voting, a term which captures the social consequences of voting. Extrinsic consequences include feelings of shame or pride that accompany reflecting on the possibility that others might learn about your behavior. A linear approximation of the unknown function U(D I, D E) is

(3)

\begin{equation}
\label{eq1}
U(D_I ,D_E ) \approx \beta _1 D_I + \beta _2 D_E ,
\end{equation}

where β1 and β2 are positive constants. The extrinsic benefits we consider here are by definition a function of the likelihood that the act of voting is observed by others. Assuming that these extrinsic benefits are proportional to the probability that others learn of one's behavior, D E can be written as

(4)

\begin{equation}
\label{eq2}
D_E = \frac{\pi_r (\alpha + \beta _3 D_I )}{\beta _2 },
\end{equation}

where πr is the perceived probability others learn whether one voted, and α is a constant that indexes the importance of extrinsic consequences of voting to the citizen. The D I term is included in (4) to capture the possibility of an interaction between the intrinsic and extrinsic components of civic duty. Subjects who obtain significant intrinsic benefits from voting, for example, may be especially concerned with whether others learn if they voted. All else equal, higher values of α imply that the extrinsic component of civic duty is more important. We will examine the sign of β3 empirically later in the paper.

Combining (1)–(4), we can rewrite the traditional calculus of voting as vote if:

(5)

\begin{equation}
pB + \beta _1 D_I + \alpha \pi _r + \beta _3 \pi _r D_I > C.
\end{equation}

Our experimental treatments are intended to alter πr and D I. Under the stipulation that β3 ≥ 0, two conclusions follow immediately from equation (5). First, citizens become more likely to vote as the intrinsic return to voting (D I) increases. Second, a citizen becomes more likely to vote with increases in the perceived probability that his or her participation will become known to others (πr). On the other hand, if β3 < 0, publicizing one's voting behavior will undercut a citizen's intrinsic motivation, possibly to the point where the citizen becomes even less likely to vote than in the absence of such publicity. This possibility is strongly suggested by literature in education showing that students' intrinsic motivation declines when extrinsic incentives are provided (Deci Reference Deci1971; Lepper, Greene, and Nisbett Reference Lepper, Greene and Nisbett1973), and similar arguments have been advanced regarding pro-social behavior more generally (Bénabou and Tirole Reference Bénabou and Tirole2003). Thus, the direction and magnitude of effects associated with social disclosure are an open empirical question, motivating the experiment presented next.

Prior Experimental Research on Shaming and Voting

Prior experimental investigation of publicizing vote history to affect turnout is extremely limited. Our work builds on two pilot studies, which appear to be the only prior studies to examine the effect of providing subjects information on their own vote history and that of their neighbors (Gerber et al. Reference Gerber, Grebner, Green and Larimer2006). These two recent experiments, which together had treatment groups approximately 10% of the size of the current study, found borderline statistically significant evidence that social pressure increases turnout. These pilot studies had important limitations. Although they suggest that social exposure has a causal effect on turnout, they share unusual features which make interpretation difficult and employ treatments that cannot isolate the effect of social pressure from the effects of other elements of the experimental treatments.Footnote 3

EXPERIMENTAL DESIGN

Setting

Our field experiment was conducted in Michigan prior to the August 2006 primary election. The August 2006 primary was a statewide election with a wide range of offices and proposals on the ballot, most of which were limited to counties, cities, and local districts. In August 2006, the only statewide offices appearing on the ballot were Governor and U.S. Senate. There were no important contested statewide Democratic primary elections. The incumbent Democrats, Senator Stabenow and Governor Granholm, were unopposed on the ballot. The Republican candidate for Governor was also unopposed, but there was a moderately hard-fought primary contest for the Republican nomination for U.S. Senate. In addition, the election featured a scattering of primary contests in several of Michigan's 15 Congressional seats, but only one was likely to affect the ultimate winner of a seat: the Republican primary in the 7th Congressional District. Each voter was allowed to vote in either the Democratic primary or the Republican primary, but could not vote for a combination of parties in the primary. The voter's choice of party is secret under Michigan law, and there is no party registration. For those intending to vote as Democrats, there was little reason to vote in the 2006 primary apart from the occasional nonpartisan judicial race or contested local office. For Republicans, there was at least some interest throughout the state, since both U.S. Senate candidates spent significant funds and solicited votes wherever they could find them. Voter turnout in the August 2006 primary was 1,282,203, or 17.7% of registered voters.

Study Population

The sample for the experiment was 180,002 households in the state of Michigan. Households were defined to include everyone at the same address with the same last name. The 180,002 households represent a subset of all households that appear in the “Qualified Voter File” (QVF), the official state voter list. Prior to random assignment, we attempted to correct apparent errors in the official file (e.g., missing voter history, incorrect ZIP codes, typographical errors in names or addresses, or multiple listings on the QVF) using paper file records. Where we were unable to correct the file, voters were eliminated from the study. From the remaining file, we removed everyone for whom we could not assign a valid 9-digit ZIP because bulk rate requires a complete ZIP code. Next, we removed people who live on blocks where more than 10% of the addresses included apartment numbers.Footnote 4 We then removed people who live on streets with fewer than four addresses (or fewer than 10 voters).Footnote 5

Prior to random assignment we also removed households with the following characteristics: all members of the household had over a 60% probability of voting by absentee ballot if they votedFootnote 6 or all household members had a greater than a 60% probability of choosing the Democratic primary rather than the Republican primary.Footnote 7 Absentees were removed because it was thought that many would have decided to vote or not prior to receipt of the experimental mailings, which were sent to arrive just a few days before the election. Those considered overwhelmingly likely to favor the Democratic primary were excluded because it was thought that, given the lack of contested primaries, these citizens would tend to ignore preelection mailings. We removed everyone who lived in a route where fewer than 25 households remained, because the production process depended on using carrier-route-presort standard mail. To qualify for such treatment by the U.S. Postal Service requires that at least 10 pieces be mailed within each carrier route, which might not have been available after the control group was removed.Footnote 8 Finally, we removed all those who had abstained in the 2004 general election on the grounds that those not voting in this very high-turnout election were likely to be “deadwood”—those who had moved, died, or registered under more than one name.

Households assigned to treatment groups were sent one mailing 11 days prior to the primary election.Footnote 9 Households were randomly assigned to either the control group or one of four treatment groups described next. Each treatment group consisted of approximately 20,000 households, with 99,999 households in the control group. The 180,002 households were sorted exactly into the order required by the USPS for “ECR-LOT” eligibility (approximately: by ZIP, carrier route; then the order in which the carrier walks the route). The 180,002 households were then divided into 10,000 cells of 18 households each, with each cell consisting of households 1–18, 19–36, and so forth, of the sorted file. As a result, after sorting, each cell consisted entirely of either one or two carrier routes. A random number was generated and the entire 180,002 records were sorted by cell number and the random number. The effect was to leave all the cells together, but in a random order. Using this randomly sorted copy of the file, the records were assigned to treatments 1/1/2/2/3/3/4/4/c/c/c/c/c/c/c/c/c/c where “c” indicates “control group.” The records were then resorted into carrier route order.

Table 1 shows sample statistics for subject households. The table divides the sample into treatment and control groups and shows the relationship between treatment group assignment and the covariates in the 180,002 households that form the sample for the experiment. The covariates include a set of known predictors of voting in primaries: turnout history in previous primary and general elections, gender, number of registered voters in the household, and age.

TABLE 1. Relationship between Treatment Group Assignment and Covariates (Household-Level Data)

Note: Only registered voters who voted in November 2004 were selected for our sample. Although not included in the table, there were no significant differences between treatment group assignment and covariates measuring race and ethnicity.

Since the randomization took place at the household level, we looked for suspicious household-level differences. Table 1 reports sample means for the households in the study and confirms that there is no relationship between a household's experimental assignment and its average level of past electoral participation. This point may be made statistically, using multinomial logit to predict experimental assignment as a function of all eight variables listed in Table 1. As expected, a likelihood ratio test with 32 degrees of freedom (8 covariates times 4 treatments) is nonsignificant (LR = 18.6, p = .97), reaffirming that the experimental groups are very closely balanced in terms of observable characteristics. Randomized assignment coupled with large sample size ensures that the unobservable characteristics are likely to be closely balanced as well.

Treatments

Each household in the treatment group received one of four mailings. The Appendix shows examples of each type. Priming voters to think about their civic duty is common to all of the treatment mailings. All four treatments carry the message “DO YOUR CIVIC DUTY—VOTE!” The first type of mailing (“Civic Duty”) provides a baseline for comparison with the other treatments because it does little besides emphasize civic duty. Households receiving this type of mailing were told, “Remember your rights and responsibilities as a citizen. Remember to vote.”

The second mailing adds to this civic duty baseline a mild form of social pressure, in this case, observation by researchers. Households receiving the “Hawthorne effect” mailing were told “YOU ARE BEING STUDIED!” and informed that their voting behavior would be examined by means of public records. The degree of social pressure in this mailing was, by design, limited by the promise that the researchers would neither contact the subject nor disclose whether the subject voted. Consistent with the notion of Hawthorne effects, the purpose of this mailing was to test whether mere observation influences voter turnout.

The “Self” mailing exerts more social pressure by informing recipients that who votes is public information and listing the recent voting record of each registered voter in the household. The word “Voted” appears by names of registered voters in the household who actually voted in the 2004 primary election and the 2004 general election, and a blank space appears if they did not vote. The purpose of this mailing was to test whether people are more likely to vote if others within their own household are able to observe their voting behavior. The mailing informed voters that after the primary election “we intend to mail an updated chart,” filling in whether the recipient voted in the August 2006 primary. The “Self” condition thus combines the external monitoring of the Hawthorne condition with actual disclosure of voting records.

The fourth mailing, “Neighbors,” ratchets up the social pressure even further by listing not only the household's voting records but also the voting records of those living nearby. Like the “Self” mailing, the “Neighbors” mailing informed the recipient that “we intend to mail an updated chart” after the primary, showing whether members of the household voted in the primary and who among their neighbors had actually voted in the primary. The implication is that members of the household would know their neighbors' voting records, and their neighbors would know theirs. By threatening to “publicize who does and does not vote,” this treatment is designed to apply maximal social pressure.

RESULTS

Following the August 2006 election we obtained turnout data from public records. Table 2 reports basic turnout rates for each of the experimental groups. The control group in our study voted at a rate of 29.7%. By comparison, the “Civic Duty” treatment group voted at a rate of 31.5%, suggesting that appeals to civic duty alone raise turnout by 1.8 percentage points. Adding social pressure in the form of Hawthorne effects raises turnout to 32.2%, which implies a 2.5 percentage-point gain over the control group. The effect of showing households their own voting records is dramatic. Turnout climbs to 34.5%, a 4.9 percentage-point increase over the control group. Even more dramatic is the effect of showing households both their own voting records and the voting records of their neighbors. Turnout in this experimental group is 37.8%, which implies a remarkable 8.1 percentage-point treatment effect.

TABLE 2. Effects of Four Mail Treatments on Voter Turnout in the August 2006 Primary Election

It is important to underscore the magnitude of these effects. The 8.1 percentage-point effect is not only bigger than any mail effect gauged by a randomized experiment; it exceeds the effect of live phone calls (Arceneaux, Gerber, and Green Reference Arceneaux, Gerber and Green2006; Nickerson Reference Nickerson2006b) and rivals the effect of face-to-face contact with canvassers conducting get-out-the-vote campaigns (Arceneaux Reference Arceneaux2005; Gerber and Green Reference Gerber and Green2000; Gerber, Green, and Green Reference Gerber, Green and Green2003). Even allowing for the fact that our experiment focused on registered voters, rather than voting-eligible citizens, the effect of the Neighbors treatment is impressive. An 8.1 percentage-point increase in turnout among registered voters in a state where registered voters comprise 75% of voting-eligible citizens translates into a 6.1 percentage-point increase in the overall turnout rate. By comparison, policy interventions such as Election Day registration or vote-by-mail, which seek to raise turnout by lowering the costs of voting, are thought to have effects on the order of 3 percentage-points or less (Knack Reference Knack2001).

In terms of sheer cost efficiency, mailings that exert social pressure far outstrip door-to-door canvassing. The powder blue mailings used here were printed on one side and cost 30 cents apiece to print and mail. Treating each experimental group therefore cost approximately $6,000. The “Self” mailing generated 1,854 votes at a rate of $3.24 per vote. The “Neighbors” mailing generated 3,106 votes at $1.93 per vote. By comparison, a typical door-to-door canvassing campaign produces votes at a rate of roughly $20 per vote, while phone banks tend to come in at $35 or more per vote (Green and Gerber Reference Green and Gerber2004).

The analysis thus far has ignored the issue of sampling variability. The main complication associated with individual-level analysis of data that were randomized at the household-level is that proper estimation of the standard errors requires a correction for the possibility that individuals within each household share unobserved characteristics (Arceneaux Reference Arceneaux2005). For this reason, Table 3 reports robust cluster standard errors, which take intrahousehold correlation into account. We also consider a range of different model specifications in order to gauge the robustness of the results.

TABLE 3. OLS Regression Estimates of the Effects of Four Mail Treatments on Voter Turnout in the August 2006 Primary Election

Note: Blocks refer to clusters of neighboring voters within which random assignment occurred. Robust cluster standard errors account for the clustering of individuals within household, which was the unit of random assignment.

*p < .001.

**Covariates are dummy variables for voting in general elections in November 2002 and 2000, primary elections in August 2004, 2002, and 2000.

The first column of Table 3 reports the results of a linear regression in which voter turnout (Y i) for individual i is regressed on dummy variables {D 1i, D 2i, D 3i, D 4i} marking each of the four treatments (the reference category is the control group). This model may be written simply as

(6)

\begin{equation}
\label{eq4}
Y_i = \beta _0 + \beta _1 D_{1i} + \beta _2 D_{2i} + \beta _3 D_{3i} + \beta _4 D_{4i} + u_i ,
\end{equation}

where u i represents an unobserved disturbance term. The second column embellishes this model by including fixed effects {C 1i, C 2i,. . ., C 9999i} for all but one of the K = 10,000 geographic clusters within which randomization occurred:

(7)

\begin{eqnarray}
\label{eq5}
Y_i &=& \beta _0 + \beta _1 D_{1i} + \beta _2 D_{2i} + \beta _3 D_{3i} + \beta_4 D_{4i}\nonumber\\ 
&&+ \sum\limits_{k=1}^{K - 1} {\gamma_k C_{ki} } + u_i .
\end{eqnarray}

The parameters associated with these fixed effects are uninteresting for our purposes; we will focus on the treatment parameters β1, β2, β3, and β4. The advantage of including fixed effects is the potential to eliminate any observed imbalances within each geographic cluster, thereby improving the precision of the estimates. The final column of Table 3 controls further for voting in five recent elections:

(8)

\begin{eqnarray}
\label{eq6}
Y_i &=& \beta _0 + \beta _1 D_{1i} + \beta _2 D_{2i} + \beta _3 D_{3i} + \beta_4 D_{4i} + \sum\limits_{k = 1}^{K - 1} {\gamma_k C_{ki} }\nonumber\\
&& +\, \lambda _1 V_{1i} + \lambda_1 V_{1i} + \cdots + \lambda _5 V_{5i} + u_i .
\end{eqnarray}

Again, the point is to minimize disturbance variance and improve the precision of the treatment estimates.

The results are remarkably robust, with scarcely any movement even in the third decimal place. The average effect of the Civic Duty mailing is a 1.8 percentage-point increase in turnout, suggesting that priming civic duty has a measurable but not large effect on turnout. The Hawthorne mailing's effect is 2.5 percentage points. Mailings that list the household's own voting record increase turnout by 4.8 percentage points, and including the voting behavior of neighbors raises the effect to 8.1 percentage points. All effects are significant at p < .0001. Moreover, the Hawthorne mailing is significantly more effective than the Civic Duty mailing (p < .05, one-tailed); the Self mailing is significantly more effective than the Hawthorne mailing (p < .001); and the Neighbors mailing is significantly more effective than the Self mailing (p < .001).

Having established that turnout increases marginally when civic duty is primed and dramatically when social pressure is applied, the remaining question is whether the effects of social pressure interact with feelings of civic duty. Using an individual's voting propensity as a proxy for the extent to which he or she feels an obligation to vote, we divided the observations into six subsamples based on the number of votes cast in five prior elections; we further divided the subsamples according to the number of voters in each household, because household size and past voting are correlated. As noted earlier, one hypothesis is that social pressure is particularly effective because it reinforces existing motivation to participate. The contrary hypothesis is that extrinsic incentives extinguish intrinsic motivation, resulting in greater treatment effects among those with low voting propensities. To test these hypotheses while at the same time taking into account floor and ceiling effects, we conducted a series of logistic regressions and examined the treatment effects across subgroups.Footnote 10 This analysis revealed that the treatment effects on underlying voting propensities are more or less constant, regardless of whether the target group votes often or rarely.Footnote 11 We infer, therefore, that there are no appreciable interactions between social pressure and one's sense of civic duty. The enforcement of norms seems to have the same underlying effect on everyone, regardless of whether their past behavior bespeaks a high or low level of internalization of these norms. In terms of the model presented in equation (5), the interaction parameter β3 appears to be zero.

The lack of interaction between intrinsic motivation and external pressure has important implications. From a theoretical standpoint, the results suggest that, subject to the usual caveats about ceiling effects, the influence of social pressure is additive: the more pressure, the more voting, regardless of whether the recipient is predisposed to vote in the first place. This finding may suggest that while people vary in terms of their willingness or eagerness to conform to norms of civic participation, the norm is widely accepted as an appropriate behavioral standard (see Blais Reference Blais2000, ch. 5). The finding is also propitious from the standpoint of external validity. Voters with widely varying characteristics nonetheless respond similarly to this intervention, suggesting that the results obtained here may also apply to other demographic or electoral settings. Consistent with this argument, we find no evidence of interactions between the treatment and the voter's partisan orientations or levels of competitiveness within the voter's congressional district (p > .25).

DISCUSSION

The remarkable effectiveness of the social pressure appeals contrasts with the relatively modest effects observed in previous studies of the effectiveness of direct mail voter mobilization campaigns. Table 4 collects the results from previously published experimental studies of mailings involving at least 1,500 subjects. These studies cover a wide range of political contexts and a diverse set of experimental subjects. Consider the results for a single mailing. Treatment effects in the 1.8 percentage point range, similar to the effects we observe for the Civic Duty mailing, are rare but not unprecedented, though one mail piece more commonly produces a result less than 1 percentage point. Results in the 5% to 8% range have never before been observed, even for a nine-piece mail program. Given the large size of our experiment and those reported in Table 4, this startling result cannot be attributed to chance.

TABLE 4. Results from Previous Studies on the Effects of Pre-election Mailings on Voter Turnout

Note: . . . Not applicable.

aThe control group is the same both New Haven experiments in 1998.

bThe control group is the same both New Haven experiments in 1999.

cThe treatment group received two phone calls and five pieces of mail.

1Reproduced from Green and Gerber (Reference Green and Gerber2004: 121); Results for 1(a) are from experiment reported in Gerber and Green Reference Gerber and Green2000, 1 and 1(b) from experiments reported in Gerber, Green, and Green Reference Gerber, Green and Green2003; and Gerber Reference Gerber2004.

2Reproduced from Cardy Reference Cardy2005, 37.

3Reproduced from Wong Reference Wong2005, 108.

4Reproduced from Ramirez Reference Ramirez2005, 71, 76.

5Reproduced from Trivedi Reference Trivedi2005, 120. The control group is the same for all three experiments.

The difference between our intervention and mail used in previous experiments is that ours harnesses one of the most formidable forces in social psychology, pressure to conform to social norms. Prior experimental studies have often couched voter mobilization messages in terms of norms (e.g., “stand up for democracy”), but none have introduced social surveillance. Evidence from experiments in psychology and behavioral economics suggests that people are more likely to comply with social norms if they know their behavior will be made public (Cialdini and Goldstein Reference Cialdini and Goldstein2004; Kallgren, Reno, and Cialdini Reference Kallgren, Reno and Cialdini2000). Scholars in experimental economics, for example, consistently find that as social isolation is reduced, through either direct or indirect communication, individuals will tend to behave more generously in bargaining scenarios (Bohnet and Frey Reference Bohnet and Frey1999; Burnham Reference Burnham2003; Hoffman, McCabe, and Smith Reference Hoffman, McCabe and Smith1996). Although heavy-handed requests sometimes encounter reactance, on balance people tend to comply with social norms when others are believed to be watching in order to avoid shame and social ostracism.

Decades of survey research have suggested that people implicitly defer to the norm of voting, insofar as they tend to exaggerate their past rates of voter turnout. The present study is the first since Gosnell (Reference Gosnell1927) to examine whether these social pressures to vote can be used to encourage people to cast ballots. Whereas Gosnell sent recipients mail deriding nonvoters as “slackers” (27), our interventions brought to bear the power of surveillance. The particular treatments used in this experiment were admittedly unconventional. It is therefore an open question as to whether the effects of appeals patterned on those employed here will have the same, smaller, or larger effects with repeated use, a subject of ongoing experimental investigation. By the same token, we can only speculate about whether the results obtained here will be replicated in the context of a high-salience election such as a presidential contest in a battleground state. In presidential elections, the supply of nonvoters available to be mobilized is reduced; on the other hand, shaming and surveillance might have greater force in the context of a presidential election, where abstention is more counternormative. Certainly, the results obtained here are sufficiently large and robust to warrant efforts to replicate and extend this research paradigm in other electoral settings.

From a theoretical vantage point, the sheer magnitude of the surveillance effect suggests an important new line of attack for scholars seeking to explain long-term declines in voter turnout or, more generally, to understand the components of the calculus of voting. The activation and enforcement of social norms, as many scholars have observed, is potentially subject to “tipping points” or “cascades” (Schelling Reference Schelling1978). When norm-compliant behavior drops off or norm-enforcing behavior dissipates, the equilibrium level of compliance may quickly deteriorate. Enforcement of norms is potentially costly—many recipients of the Neighbors message called the phone number provided on the mailing and demanded to be removed from future mailing lists—and arguably more so when the level of compliance is low.

From an historical vantage point, one could argue that the sharp declines in turnout rates that occurred in the United States after the 1880s reflect social forces, such as rapid population growth and mobility, coupled with institutional changes, such as the introduction of secret balloting and rules requiring that party officials remain a long distance away from where ballots are cast, that diminished both the surveillance of voters and their sense that their voting behavior was being monitored. Concomitant changes, such as the decline of party machines, membership organizations, and party-aligned newspapers that openly excoriated nonvoters, also may have contributed to the erosion of social pressure.

The question is whether these processes are reversible. To answer this question requires a research program of experimental interventions that replicate and extend the work presented here. We have seen the power of a single mailer disclosing the voting behavior of oneself and one's neighbors. Does this effect persist over time, in the form of newly created voting habits (Gerber, Green, and Shachar Reference Gerber, Green and Shachar2003; Plutzer Reference Plutzer2002)? (Results from the November 2006 election suggest that it does, but 2008 presents a more stringent test.) Does the effect of the treatment spread to neighbors and others in the recipients' social networks (Huckfeldt and Sprague Reference Huckfeldt and Sprague1995; Nickerson forthcoming)? To what extent would the effect observed here be amplified if social pressure were conveyed in person, say, among members of the same social or political group (Schram and Van Winden Reference Schram and van Winden1991)? Does the effect grow when more than one person exerts social pressure?Footnote 12 Does it diminish, as in the famous Asch (Reference Asch, Macoby, Newcomb and Hartley1958) experiment, when other noncompliers openly challenge the pressure to conform?

In sum, the powerful effects of interventions like the ones described here present behavioral scientists with a new paradigm by which to study a wide array of different phenomena, ranging from habit-formation to interpersonal influence. Although we are not advocates of shaming tactics or policies, their cost-effectiveness makes them an inevitable development in political campaign craft, and social scientists have much to learn by studying the consequences of making public acts more public.

APPENDIX A: MAILINGS

Footnotes

1 In an effort to avoid what are thought to be formidable problems of reactance, social psychologists have turned to foot-in-the-door techniques whereby compliance is achieved through a series of small requests (Fiske Reference Fiske2004).

2 See International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance (http://www.idea.int/vt/compulsory_voting.cfm) for discussion of the administration of compulsory voting in Italy.

3 In both prior experiments, the identity of the sender of the mailing (a political consultant), an unfamiliar and unusual source of political information, was prominently displayed on the mailing. In addition, the mailings in the first pilot study announced to the subjects in large, bold type that they were part of an experiment, a feature that might be expected to induce a Hawthorne effect of its own. In the second pilot study, voters were told that the sender would be “looking for you at the polls,” a suggestion with unclear and perhaps unsettling implications. Moreover, all treatments in the two pilot studies presented past turnout for both the voter's own household and their neighbors'. Thus it is impossible to parse the extent to which any observed change in turnout was due to social pressure from neighbors, knowledge that the sender knows whether the recipient voted, or the priming of the voter's sense of civic responsibility.

4 The reasoning was that the study focused on typical neighborhoods of single-family homes. A study of apartment residents would need to consider the physical layout of apartment complexes in order to choose appropriate neighbors.

5 We also removed addresses in the western Upper Peninsula because of concern that our mail would not be delivered in time for the primary.

6 Those with a high probability of voting absentee voting were determined by: age (Michigan allows no-reason absentee voting for people over 60), previous use of absentee ballot, inclusion on a list of people to whom absentee applications are routinely sent, presence of another absentee voter in the household, and ease of using an absentee ballot in the voter's community.

7 Those with a high probability of choosing the Democratic primary were determined by: living in a Democratic precinct, being African-American, being Hispanic, being a single female, being born between 1930 and 1959, voting in primary elections where most of the turnout was Democratic, expressing support for a Democratic candidate to a phone bank, contributing money to Democratic campaigns, signing Democratic nomination petitions, signing liberal initiative petitions, and living in a household with a Democrat. They were removed because of the extremely spotty pattern of contested Democratic primaries in the August 2006 election. Some people with a greater than 60% chance of voting Democratic were included, however, because they lived with another member of the household who qualified for inclusion. Such Democrats comprise 2.7% of our experimental sample. With regard to issues of external validity, we do not find any interactions between our treatments and the probability of voting Democratic.

8 In order to achieve a universe of approximately 180,000 households, a small number of carrier routes were deleted which contained exactly 25 selected voters.

9 These mailings are included in the Appendix.

10 This analysis (not shown, but available on request) divided the subjects according to past voting history and household size. We tested the interaction hypothesis by means of a likelihood-ratio test, which failed to reject the null hypothesis of equal treatment effects across these subgroups.

11 The logistic function does imply, however, that the effects will generate the largest percentage-point movement among those whose baseline probability of voting is near 50%. As a practical matter, therefore, these treatments are most effective in terms of votes produced when directed at people with middling vote probabilities.

12 The Massachusetts Affordable Housing Alliance presents each student attending its training classes with his or her vote history as a way of encouraging political involvement. Among fundraisers, publicizing whether and how much people contribute is a common tactic.

References

REFERENCES

Aldrich, John H. 1993. “Rational Choice and Turnout.American Journal of Political Science 37 (February): 246–78.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arceneaux, Kevin. 2005. “Using Cluster Randomized Field Experiments to Study Voting Behavior.Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 601 (September): 169–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arceneaux, Kevin, Gerber, Alan S., and Green, Donald P.. 2006. “Comparing Experimental and Matching Methods using a Large-Scale Voter Mobilization Experiment.Political Analysis 14 (Winter): 3762.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Asch, Solomon E. 1958. “Effects of Group Pressure upon the Modification and Distortion of Judgments.” In Readings in Social Psychology 3rd edition. ed. Macoby, Eleanor E., Newcomb, Theodore M., and Hartley, Eugene L.. New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, 174–83.Google Scholar
Bénabou, Roland, and Tirole, Jean. 2003. “Intrinsic and Extrinsic Motivation.Review of Economic Studies 70 (July): 489520.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, Andre. 2000. To Vote or Not to Vote? Pittsburgh, PA: University of Pittsburgh Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bohnet, Iris, and Frey, Bruno S.. 1999. “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games: Comment.American Economic Review 89 (March): 335–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brehm, Sharon S., and Brehm, Jack W.. 1981. Psychological Reactance: A Theory of Freedom and Control. New York: Academic Press, 327–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burnham, Terence C. 2003. “Engineering altruism: a theoretical and experimental investigation of anonymity and gift giving.Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 50 (January): 133–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Angus, Gurin, George, and Miller, Warren E.. 1954. The Voter Decides. Evanston, IL: Row, Peterson.Google Scholar
Cardy, Emily Arthur. 2005. “An Experimental Field Study of the GOTV and Persuasion Effects of Partisan Direct Mail and Phone Calls.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 601 (September): 2840.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cialdini, Robert B., and Goldstein, Noah J.. 2004. “Social Influence: Compliance and Conformity.Annual Review of Psychology 55 (February): 591621.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Cialdini, Robert B., and Trost, Melanie R.. 1998. “Social Influence: Social Norms, Conformity, and Compliance.” In The Handbook of Social Psychology, 4th edition, ed. Gilbert, Daniel T., Fiske, Susan T., and Lindzey, Gardner. Boston: McGraw-Hill, 151–92.Google Scholar
Deci, Edward L. 1971. “Effects of externally mediated rewards on intrinsic motivation.Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 18 (April): 105–15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Feddersen, Timothy J. 2004. “Rational Choice Theory and the Paradox of Not Voting.Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (Winter): 99112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fiske, Susan T. 2004. Social Beings: A Core Motives Approach to Social Psychology. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Gerber, Alan S. 2004. “Does Campaign Spending Work? Field Experiments Provide Evidence and Suggest New Theory.” American Behavioural Scientific (January) 506–540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerber, Alan S., and Green, Donald P.. 2000. “The Effects of Canvassing, Telephone Calls, and Direct Mail on Voter Turnout: A Field Experiment.American Political Science Review 94 (September): 653–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerber, Alan S., Green, Donald P., and Green, Matthew N.. 2003. “The Effects of Partisan Direct Mail on Voter Turnout.Electoral Studies 22 (December): 563–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerber, Alan S., Green, Donald P., and Shachar, Ron. 2003. “Voting May Be Habit-Forming: Evidence from a Randomized Field Experiment.American Journal of Political Science 47 (July): 540–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerber, Alan S., Grebner, Mark, Green, Donald P., and Larimer, Christopher W.. 2006. “Does Public Knowledge of Neighborhood Voting Records Increase Voter Turnout? A Field Experiment.” Paper prepared for presentation at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association, Chicago, IL, April 20–23.Google Scholar
Gerber, Alan S., and Rogers, Todd. 2007. “The Effect of Descriptive Social Norms on Voter Turnout: The importance of accentuating the positive. Yale University manuscript.Google Scholar
Gosnell, Harold F. 1927. Getting-Out-the-Vote: An Experiment in the Stimulation of Voting. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Green, Donald P., and Gerber, Alan S.. 2004. Get Out the Vote: How to Increase Voter Turnout. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press.Google Scholar
Green, Donald P., Gerber, Alan S., and Nickerson, David W.. 2003. “Getting Out the Vote in Local Elections: Results from Six Door-to-Door Canvassing Experiments.Journal of Politics 65 (November): 1083–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harbaugh, W. T. 1996. “If People Vote because they Like to, then Why do so Many of them Lie?Public Choice 89 (October): 6376.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoffman, Elizabeth, McCabe, Kevin A., Smith, Vernon L.. 1996. “Social Distance and Other-Regarding Behavior in Dictator Games.American Economic Review 86 (June): 653–60.Google Scholar
Huckfeldt, Robert, and Sprague, John. 1995. Citizens, Politics, and Social Communication: Information and Influence in an Election Campaign. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance. 2005. “Compulsory Voting.” The Voter Turnout Project at International IDEA. Stockholm, Sweden. http://www.idea.int/vt/compulsory_voting.cfm. (February 1, 2006).Google Scholar
Jackman, Robert W. 1987. “Political Institutions and Voter Turnout in the Industrial Democracies.American Political Science Review 81 (June): 405–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kallgren, Carl A., Reno, Raymond R., and Cialdini, Robert B.. 2000. “A Focus Theory of Normative Conduct: When Norms Do and Do Not Affect Behavior.Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 26 (August): 1002–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, Stephen. 1992. “Civic Norms, Social Sanctions, and Voter Turnout.Rationality and Society 4 (May): 133–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Knack, Stephen. 2001. “Election-Day Registration: The Second Wave.American Politics Research 29 (January): 6578.Google Scholar
Knack, Stephen, and Kropf, Martha E.. 1998. “For Shame! The Effect of Community Cooperative Context on the Probability of Voting.Political Psychology 19 (September): 585–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ledyard, John O. 1984. “The pure theory of two-candidate elections.Public Choice 44 (January): 741.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, Jennifer S., and Tetlock, Philip E.. 1999. “Accounting for the effects of accountability.Psychological Bulletin 125 (March): 255–75.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Lepper, Mark R., Greene, David, and Nisbett, Richard E.. 1973. “Undermining Children's Intrinsic Interest with Extrinsic Rewards.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 28 (October): 129–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1997. “Unequal Participation: Democracy's Unresolved Dilemma.American Political Science Review 91 (March): 114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Michelson, Melissa R. 2005. “Meeting the Challenge of Latino Voter Mobilization.Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 601 (September): 85101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nickerson, David W. Forthcoming. “Is Voting Contagious? Evidence from Two Field Experiments.” American Political Science Review 102 (February)CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nickerson, David W. 2006b. “Volunteer Phone Calls Can Increase Turnout: Evidence from Eight Field Experiments.American Politics Research 34 (May): 271–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Palfrey, Thomas R., and Rosenthal, Howard. 1985. “Voter Participation and Strategic Uncertainty.American Political Science Review 79 (March): 6278.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plutzer, Eric. 2002. “Becoming a Habitual Voter: Inertia, Resources, and Growth in Young Adulthood.American Political Science Review 96 (March): 4156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Posner, Richard A., and Rasmusen, Eric B.. 1999. “Creating and Enforcing Norms, With Special Reference to Sanctions.International Review of Law and Economics 19 (September): 369–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramirez, Ricardo. 2005. “Giving Voice to Latino Voters: A Field Experiment on the Effectiveness of a National Nonpartisan Mobilization Effort.Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 601 (September): 6684.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ringold, Debra Jones. 2002. “Boomerang Effects in Response to Public Health Interventions: Some Unintended Consequences in the Alcoholic Beverage Market.Journal of Consumer Policy 25 (March): 2763.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Riker, William H., and Ordershook, Peter C.. 1968. “A Theory of the Calculus of Voting.American Political Science Review 62 (March): 2543.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rind, Bruce, and Benjamin, Daniel. 1994. “Effects of Public Image Concerns and Self-Image on Compliance.The Journal of Social Psychology 134 (February): 1925.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheff, Thomas J. 2000. “Shame and the Social Bond: A Sociological Theory.Sociological Theory 18 (March): 8499.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1978. Micromotives and Macrobehavior. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Schram, Arthur, and van Winden, Frans. 1991. “Why People Vote: Free Riding and the Production and Consumption of Social Pressure.Journal of Economic Psychology 12 (December): 575620.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, P. Wesley. 1999. “Changing Behavior With Normative Feedback Interventions: A Field Experiment on Curbside Recycling.Basic and Applied Social Psychology 21 (March): 2536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seton-Watson, Christopher. 1983. “Italy.” In Democracy and Elections: Electoral Systems and Their Political Consequences, eds. Bogdanor, Vernon and Butler, David. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stewart, David W., and Martin, Ingrid M.. 1994. “Intended and unintended consequences of warning messages: A review and synthesis of empirical research.Journal of Public Policy and Marketing 13 (Spring): 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trivedi, Neema. 2005. “The Effect of Identify-Based GOTV Direct Mail Appeals on the Turnout of Indian Americans.Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 601 (September): 115–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Webster, J. Matthew, Duvall, Jamieson, Gaines, Leslie M., and Smith, Richard H.. 2003. “The Role of Praise and Social Comparison in the Experience of Pride.The Journal of Social Psychology 143 (April): 209–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whatley, Mark A., Webster, J. Matthew, Smith, Richard H., and Rhodes, Adele. 1999. “The Effect of a Favor on Public and Private Compliance: How Internalized is the Norm of Reciprocity.Basic and Applied Social Psychology 21 (3): 251–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wong, Janelle S. 2005. “Mobilizing Asian American Voters: A Field Experiment.Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 601 (September): 102–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

TABLE 1. Relationship between Treatment Group Assignment and Covariates (Household-Level Data)

Figure 1

TABLE 2. Effects of Four Mail Treatments on Voter Turnout in the August 2006 Primary Election

Figure 2

TABLE 3. OLS Regression Estimates of the Effects of Four Mail Treatments on Voter Turnout in the August 2006 Primary Election

Figure 3

TABLE 4. Results from Previous Studies on the Effects of Pre-election Mailings on Voter Turnout

Submit a response

Comments

No Comments have been published for this article.