Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-75dct Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-29T00:13:17.769Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Henry George on Two Continents: A Comparative Study in the Diffusion of Ideas

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 June 2009

Harold Schiffrin
Affiliation:
Hebrew University, Jerusalem
Pow-Key Sohn
Affiliation:
Seoul National University, Korea

Extract

The impact of Henry George's land value taxation theory was nothing less than global in scope, and his epochal Progress and Poverty – first published in 1879 – gained wider fame than any other political or socio-economic treatise emanating from an American pen. While George's doctrine was essentially a product of of his experience in California during the land-grabbing 60's and 70's, the most pervasive influence of the San Francisco sage was not manifested at home, but in Europe, Australasia and other distant places.

It is with some aspects of this remarkable diffusion of Georgeism during the latter part of the 19th century that this study is concerned. In particular, we would like to examine the circumstances under which this ideological stimulus was transmitted and received in such divergent settings as England, China and Japan. First we will trace the history of the Georgeist influence in each of these countries and then compare their respective patterns of development.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Society for the Comparative Study of Society and History 1959

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 From a letter to Hamlin Garland in 1904. Excerpts quoted from Barker, Charles A., Henry George (New York, 1955), pp. 375–76.Google Scholar

2 Barker, op. cit., p. 412.

3 “The idea of a natural right to the land and of a common interest in it is the instinctive possession of every nation. But in England the feeling seems more general than elsewhere, because, possibly, of the number of large proprietors and of the serious abuses to which the system has given rise.” Gide, Charles and Rist, Charles, A History of Economic Doctrines (London, 1932), p. 559.Google Scholar

4 Thomas Cook (editor) (New York, 1947), p. 13

5 Ibid., p. 137.

6 Beer, M., A History of British Socialism (New York, 1948), pp. 106107.Google Scholar

7 Geiger, George R., The Philosophy of Henry George (New York, 1933), p. 185.Google Scholar We have leaned heavily upon this scholarly exposition of George's philosophy. It is especially helpful in comparing George's ideas with those of earlier reformers and economists.

8 Ibid., p. 168.

9 Ibid., pp. 287–291.

10 Gide and Rist, op. cit., p. 553.

11 Dissertations and Discussions, V (New York, 1874), p. 225.Google Scholar

12 Ibid., p. 269.

13 George, Henry, Progress andPoverty (New York, 1916 ed.), pp. 401402.Google Scholar

14 Tiltman, H. Hessel, J. Ramsay MacDonald (New York, 1929), p. 18.Google Scholar

15 From Tom Mann's Memoirs, quoted by Geiger, op. cit., p. 236.

16 From Socialism in England, p. 21, quoted by Geiger, op. cit., p. 235.

17 Shaw, G. B. et al. , , Fabian Essays (New York, 1891), p. 233.Google Scholar

18 Ibid., p. 233.

19 English Political Thought in the 19th Century (London, 1933), p. 3.Google Scholar

20 A vast amount of unimproved land, free of taxation, was tied up in Britain. One-fifth of the land within the boundaries of London county lay vacant; in Birmingham almost 25% of the land was unimproved. Similar conditions prevailed in Edinburgh, Manchester, Bradford, etc. See Scheftel, Yetta, The Taxation of Land Values (New York, 1916), pp. 380381.Google Scholar

21 Barker, op. cit., pp. 516–517.

22 Hyndman, Henry Mayers, The Record of An Adventurous Life (New York, 1911), pp. 257-258.Google Scholar

23 Barker, op. cit., p. 564.

24 Geiger, op. cit., p. 202.

25 Lawrence, Elwood P., “Uneasy Alliance: The Reception of Henry George by British Socialists in the Eighties”, The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, II, No. 1 (10, 1951), p. 69Google Scholar. Unfortunately we have not had the opportunity to consult Professor Lawrence's recently published book, Henry George in the British Isles (East Lansing, 1957).Google Scholar

26 See Scheftel, op. cit., pp. 380 ff.

27 See Norman, E. H., Japan's Emergence as a Modern State (New York, 1940)Google Scholar, for a highly perceptive account of the socio-economic background to the Early Meiji period.

28 Ibid., pp. 136 ff.

29 See Scalapino, Robert A., Democracy and the Party Movement in Pre-war Japan (Berkeley and Los Angeles, 1953), p. 310.Google Scholar

30 Tetsuji, Kada, Ishin igo no shakai-keizai shiso gairon (Tokyo, 1933), p. 80.Google Scholar

31 Norman, op. cit., p. 144.

32 Ibid., p. 157.

33 Zendai, Hatano, “Shoki ni okeru Sun Wen no p'ing chun ti ch'00FC;an ni tsuite”, Shakaikeizai Shigaku, XXI, No. 5–6, (0306, 1955), p. 487.Google Scholar

34 Norman, op. cit., p. 168.

35 Scalapino, op. cit., pp. 105–106.

36 Ibid., p. 316 and note 34.

37 Motora, an American-trained psychologist, received a Ph.D. at Johns Hopkins and became acquainted with Georgeism during his stay in the United States.

38 Kyokuzan, Ishikawa and Shuzui, Kotoku (editors), “Shakai mondai Zatsusan”, Meiji Bunka Zenshu (Tokyo, 1929) p. 475.Google Scholar See also Hatano, op. cit., p. 488.

39 Kokumin no Tomo, II, No. 14 (Tokyo, 1888), pp. 106120.Google Scholar

40 Jo, a teacher by profession, was close to the Jiyuto intellectual leader Nakae Chomin. Nakae and Itagaki Taisuke, another Liberal leader wrote prefaces to this translation. See the Nihon shakai-shugi bunken (Tokyo, 1929), pp. 78.Google Scholar

41 Kada Tetsuji, op. cit., p. 192.

42 Meiji Bunka Zenshu, XXI, p. 308.Google Scholar

43 Ibid., p. 391–392.

44 See Garst, 's obituary in the Japan Weekly Mail (Yokohama, 12 31, 1898), p. 674.Google Scholar

45 This article appears under the title “Tanzei Taro” in Nihon shakai-shugi bunken, op. cit., p. 120.

46 Heimin Shimbun, No. 10 (1904). Reprinted in Heimin Shimbun, I, No. 10 (Tokyo, 1953), p. 219.Google Scholar

47 Ibid., III, No. 44, p. 273.

48 Ibid., I, No. 4, p. 85.

49 Ibid., I, No. 3, p. 59.

50 Nihon shakai-shugi bunken, op. cit., p. 61; and Yoshisaburo, Nakamura, “Jyuminken undo no hatten”, Shakaikagaku tokyu, I, No. 1 (Tokyo, 1956), pp. 197198.Google Scholar

51 Nishikawa was a socialist who collaborated with the famous radical leader Katayama Sen in publishing Rodo Sekai.

52 Miller, Joseph D., Single Tax Year Book (New York, 1917), p. 193.Google Scholar

53 Kata Tetsuji calls attention to the analogous role of Georgeism as a transitional development in Britain and Japan; op. cit., p. 194.

54 Scalapino points out that “the legacy of military ethics, the obstacles to legal reform, the lack of understanding of democratic theory, and the absence of conditions that would allow liberal theory to be translated immediately into practice – all combined to encourage the use of force”, op. cit., pp. 316–317.

55 The Single Tax Review, I, No. 3 (New York, 01 15, 1902), p. 47.Google Scholar

57 Scheftel, op. cit., pp. 184 ff.

58 For Macklin's version see the Single Tax Year Book, op. cit., p. 192, and the Single Tax Review, I, No. 3 (01 15, 1902), p. 47.Google Scholar Contrary views are held in Scheftel, op. cit., p. 184, and the Single Tax Review, I, No. 1 (07, 1901), p. 24.Google Scholar

59 See Schiffrin, Harold, “Sun Yat-sen's Early Land Policy”, The Journal of Asian Studies, XVI, No. 4 (08, 1957)Google Scholar, for a fuller discussion of the Georgeist influence upon Sun.

60 See Hatano, op. cit.

61 Schiffrin, op. cit., pp. 558, 560.

62 Ibid., p. 554.

64 In 1907 a T'ung Meng Hui faction opposing the “Equalization of land rights” slogan formed a new organization, the Kung-chin Hui, which cooperated with Sun in all other respects. Landowning supporters of the revolution in the Yangtze valley apparently led this faction. See Tzu-yu, Feng, Ko-ming i-shih, rev. ed., I (Shanghai, 1947), pp. 248252.Google Scholar

65 The Public, XV, No. 732 (Chicago, 04 12, 1912), p. 349.Google Scholar

66 Bulletin of the National Single Tax League, V, No. 5 (05, 1921), p. 6.Google Scholar

67 Ibid., p. 6.

68 In an interview in December, 1922, Sun would declare that Chinese conditions at that time would not allow for a strict adherence to single tax doctrine, and that other forms of revenue were necessary in addition to land value taxation. See Kuo-fu ch'uan-chi, IV (Taipei, 1957), p. 521.Google Scholar

69 Quoted by Geiger, op. cit., pp. 461–462, from the New York Times (09 11, 1927), p. 5Google Scholar of the Sunday feature section.

70 Free China Weekly (Chinese News Service, New York, 02 7, 1956).Google Scholar

71 For the Chinese Communist interpretation of Sun's use of Georgeist concepts, see “Sun Chung-shan ’p’ing-chün ti-ch'üan cheng-kang ti ch'an-sheng ho fa-chan”, Kuang-ming jih-pao (Peking, 10 27, 1955).Google Scholar