Hostname: page-component-848d4c4894-2pzkn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-05-05T12:17:04.230Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Factor markets in England before the Black Death

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  20 April 2009

BRUCE M. S. CAMPBELL
Affiliation:
School of Geography, Archaeology and Palaeoecology, The Queen's University of Belfast.

Abstract

Modern English factor markets originated during the two centuries of active commercialization that preceded the Black Death. An active labour market was established by the late twelfth century. Evolution of a land market followed the legal reforms of the 1170s and 1180s, which created legally secure and defensible property rights in land. These rights stimulated growth of a capital market, since land became a security against which credit could be obtained. Nevertheless, none of these nascent factor markets functioned unconstrained and each became embedded in legal, tenurial, and institutional complexities and rigidities which it took later generations centuries to reform.

Les marchés de facteurs de production en angleterre avant la peste noire

Les marchés de facteurs de production anglais des temps modernes ont leur origine au cours des deux siècles de vie commerciale active qui précédèrent la Peste Noire. Un actif marché du travail existait à la fin du 12e siècle. L'évolution du marché foncier a correspondu aux réformes législatives des années 1170 et 1180 qui mirent en place des droits de propriété terrienne reconnus par la loi et juridiquement défendables. Ces droits stimulèrent la croissance d'un marché des capitaux, le foncier étant devenu une valeur pouvant servir de caution à un crédit. Cependant aucun de ces marchés émergents ne fonctionnait en toute liberté, chacun se trouvant noyé dans un réseau de rigidités complexes d'ordre légal, seigneurial ou institutionnel qu'il fallut des siècles aux générations futures pour réformer.

Faktormärkte in england vor dem schwarzen tod

In England entstanden moderne Faktormärkte in den zwei Jahrhunderten aktiver Kommerzialisierung, die dem Schwarzen Tod vorausgingen. Im späten 12. Jahrhunderts hatte sich ein aktiver Arbeitsmarkt etabliert. Durch die Rechtsreformen der 1170er und 80er Jahre, die sichere und einklagbare Eigentumsrechte am Grund und Boden schufen, entwickelte sich ein Bodenmarkt. Diese Rechte wiederum stimulierten die Entwicklung eines Kapitalmarktes, da Grund und Boden als Sicherheit bei der Kreditvergabe fungierte. Gleichwohl funktionierte keiner dieser heranwachsenden Faktormärkte ungehemmt. Sie waren vielmehr komplexen rechtlichen, grundherrschaftlichen und institutionellen Einschränkungen unterworfen, deren Reform spätere Generationen noch Jahrunderte kosten solte.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

ENDNOTES

1 Useful accounts are provided by R. H. Britnell, The commercialisation of English society 1000–1500 (Cambridge, 1993); E. Miller and J. Hatcher, Medieval England: towns, commerce and crafts 1086–1348 (London, 1995); Langdon, J. and Masschaele, J., ‘Commercial activity and population growth in medieval England’, Past and Present 190 (2006), 3581.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

2 J. L. Abu-Lughod, Before European hegemony: the world system A.D. 1250–1350 (Oxford, 1989). Abu-Lughod's thirteenth-century world system comprised eight inter-linked circuits; see her page 34.

3 C. Delano-Smith and R. J. P. Kain, English maps: a history (London, 1999), 36–42.

4 B. M. S. Campbell, ‘The sources of tradable surpluses: English agricultural exports 1250–1349’, in L. Berggren, N. Hybel and A. Landen eds., Cogs, cargoes and commerce: maritime bulk trade in northern Europe, 1150–1400 (Toronto, 2002), 1–30, and ‘Benchmarking medieval economic development: England, Wales, Scotland, and Ireland circa 1290’, Economic History Review 61 (2008), 896–948.

5 Campbell, ‘Benchmarking’; D. A. Hinton, ‘The large towns 600–1300’, and J. Kermode, ‘The greater towns 1300–1540’, in D. M. Palliser ed., The Cambridge urban history of Britain, vol. 1: 600–1540 (Cambridge, 2000), 217–43 and 441–65. For a higher estimate of the percentage urban see C. C. Dyer, ‘How urbanized was medieval England?’, in J.-M. Duvosquel and E. Thoen eds., Peasants and townsmen in medieval Europe: studia in honorem Adriaan Verhulst (Ghent, 1995), 169–83.

6 P. Nightingale, ‘The growth of London in the medieval English economy’, in R. H. Britnell and J. Hatcher eds., Progress and problems in medieval England: essays in honour of Edward Miller (Cambridge, 1996), 89–106; Campbell, ‘Benchmarking’, 908, 912.

7 B. M. S. Campbell, English seigniorial agriculture 1250–1450 (Cambridge, 2000), 399–406.

8 L. M. Salzman, Building in England down to 1540: a documentary history (Oxford, 1952); R. K. Morris, Cathedrals and abbeys of England and Wales: the building Church, 600–1540 (London, 1979).

9 E. M. Carus-Wilson and O. Coleman, England's export trade 1275–1547 (Oxford, 1963); T. H. Lloyd, Alien merchants in England in the High Middle Ages (Brighton, 1982); Miller and Hatcher, Medieval England, 182–213.

10 Campbell, English seigniorial agriculture, 406–10.

11 S. R. Epstein, Freedom and growth: the rise of states and markets in Europe, 1300–1750 (London and New York, 2000), 10; Federico, Giovanni and Malanima, Paolo, ‘Progress, decline, growth: product and productivity in Italian agriculture, 1000–2000’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 57 (2004), 456–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

12 Britnella, Commercialisation; R. H. Britnell and B. M. S. Campbell eds., A commercialising economy: England 1086–c.1300 (Manchester, 1995); J. Masschaele, Peasants, merchants, and markets: inland trade in medieval England, 1150–1350 (New York, 1997); C. C. Dyer, Making a living in the Middle Ages: the people of Britain, 850–1520 (New Haven and London, 2002).

13 D. L. Farmer, ‘Prices and wages’, in H. E. Hallam ed., Agrarian history of England and Wales, vol. 2: 1042–1350 (Cambridge, 1988), 716–817; D. L. Farmer, ‘Prices and wages, 1350–1500’, in E. Miller ed., The agrarian history of England and Wales, vol. 3: 1348–1500 (Cambridge, 1991), 431–525; Clark, Gregory, ‘The price history of English agriculture, 1209–1914’, Research in Economic History 22 (2004), 41120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

14 Mayhew, N. J., ‘Population, money supply, and the velocity of circulation in England, 1300–1700’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 48 (1995), 238–57Google Scholar; Allen, M., ‘The volume of the English currency, 1158–1470’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 54 (2001), 595611CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Allen, M., ‘The quantity of money in England 1180–1247: new data’, British Numismatic Journal 75 (2005), 44–9.Google Scholar

15 S. Letters with M. Fernandes, D. Keene, and O. Myhill, Gazetteer of markets and fairs in England and Wales to 1516 (parts 1–2), List & Index Society, Special Series, 32–3 (Kew, 2003); B. M. S. Campbell and K. Bartley, England on the eve of the Black Death: an atlas of lay wealth, land, and property, 1300–49 (Manchester, 2006), 299–312.

16 E.g. D. J. Keene, Survey of medieval Winchester, 2 vols., Winchester Studies, 2 (Oxford, 1985); Palliser ed., Cambridge urban history; C. Dyer, ‘Trade, urban hinterlands and market integration, 1300–1600’, in J. A. Galloway ed., Trade, urban hinterlands and market integration, c.1300–1600: a collection of working papers given at a conference organised by the Centre for Metropolitan History and supported by the Economic and Social Research Council, 7 July 1999, Centre for Metropolitan History, Working Papers, 3 (London, 2000). 103–9.

17 B. M. S. Campbell, J. A. Galloway, D. J. Keene, and M. Murphy, A medieval capital and its grain supply: agrarian production and its distribution in the London region c.1300, Historical Geography Research Series, 30 (n. p., 1993); Galloway, J. A., Keene, D. J., and Murphy, M., ‘Fuelling the city: production and distribution of firewood and fuel in London's region, 1290–1400’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 49 (1996), 447–72CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Lee, J. S., ‘Feeding the colleges: Cambridge's food and fuel supplies, 1450–1560’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 56 (2003), 243–64CrossRefGoogle Scholar; J. S. Lee, Cambridge and its economic region 1450–1560 (Hatfield, 2005).

18 E. Power, The wool trade in English medieval history (Oxford, 1941); T. H. Lloyd, The English wool trade in the Middle Ages (Cambridge, 1977); J. Hatcher, English tin production and trade before 1550 (Oxford, 1973); Campbell, ‘Sources of tradable surpluses’.

19 Campbell, English seigniorial agriculture; Campbell and Bartley, England on the eve of the Black Death.

20 Biddick, K., ‘Missing links: taxable wealth, markets and stratification among English medieval peasants’, Journal of Interdisciplinary History 18 (1987), 277–98CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Masschaele, Peasants, merchants, and markets; D. J. Keene, ‘Changes in London's economic hinterland as indicated by debt cases in the Court of Common Pleas’, in Galloway ed., Trade, urban hinterlands and market integration, 59–81.

21 C. Dyer, Everyday life in medieval England (London, 1994), 285.

22 M. Bailey, ‘Peasant welfare in England, 1290–1348’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 51 (1998), 223–51.

23 B. M. S. Campbell ed., Before the Black Death: studies in the ‘crisis’ of the early fourteenth century (Manchester, 1991); J. H. Munro, ‘The “industrial crisis” of the English textile towns, c.1290–c.1330’, in M. Prestwich, R. H. Britnell, and R. Frame eds., Thirteenth century England VII: proceedings of the Durham conference 1997 (Woodbridge, 1999), 103–42; B. M. S. Campbell, ‘Ecology versus economics in late thirteenth- and early fourteenth-century English agriculture’, in D. Sweeney ed., Agriculture in the Middle Ages: technology, practice, and representation (Philadelphia, 1995), 76–108.

24 G. Snooks, in ‘The dynamic role of the market in the Anglo-Norman economy and beyond, 1086–1300’, in Britnell and Campbell eds., Commercialising economy, 27–54, here pp. 41–3, was the first to draw explicit attention to the economic importance of medieval factor markets.

25 Snooks, ‘Dynamic role of the market’, 43.

26 M. Bloch, Feudal society, trans. L. A. Manyon (London, 1961), 116.

27 David A. E. Pelteret, Slavery in early medieval England: from the reign of Alfred until the twelfth century (Woodbridge, 1995), 251–9.

28 J. Hatcher, ‘English serfdom and villeinage: towards a reassessment’, Past and Present 90 (1981), 26–33.

29 Campbell, B. M. S., ‘The agrarian problem in the early fourteenth century’, Past and Present 188 (2005), 2644CrossRefGoogle Scholar; R. H. Hilton, The decline of serfdom in medieval England (2nd edn; London and Basingstoke, 1983).

30 P. R. Hyams, King, lords and peasants in medieval England: the common law of villeinage in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries (Oxford, 1980).

31 Campbell, ‘Agrarian problem’, 26–36.

32 For a case study see J. Whittle, The development of agrarian capitalism: land and labour in Norfolk, 1440–1580 (Oxford, 2000).

34 For examples see E. M. Carus-Wilson ed., The overseas trade of Bristol in the later Middle Ages (Bristol, 1937).

35 Clark, Gregory, ‘The cost of capital and medieval agricultural technique’, Explorations in Economic History 35 (1998), 265–94Google Scholar; see also Peter Boomgaard, ‘Labour, land, and capital in pre-modern and early-modern Southeast Asia’, paper presented at the workshop of the Global Economic History Network, ‘The rise, organization, and institutional framework of factor markets’, University of Utrecht, The Netherlands, 23–25 June 2005.

36 E.g. Elaine Clark, ‘Debt litigation in a late medieval English vill’, in J. A. Raftis ed., Pathways to medieval peasants (Toronto, 1981), 247–79.

37 But see Gregory Clark, ‘Interpreting English economic history 1200–1800: Malthusian stasis or early dynamism?’, paper presented to Session 122, ‘Progress, stasis, and crisis: demographic and economic developments in England and beyond A.D. c.1000–c.1800’, 14th International Economic History Congress, Helsinki, August 2006, available at http://www.helsinki.fi/iehc2006/papers3/Clark/pdf.

38 Clark, ‘Cost of capital’; Epstein, Freedom and growth, 61–2.

39 Britnell, R. H., ‘Commerce and capitalism in late medieval England: problems of description and theory’, Journal of Historical Sociology 6 (1993), 364.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

40 Morris, Cathedrals and abbeys; David Knowles and R. N. Hadcock, Medieval religious houses: England and Wales (2nd edn; London, 1971).

41 E. H. Phelps Brown and S. V. Hopkins, A perspective of prices and wages (London, 1981), 1–31; Gregory Clark, ‘Work, wages and living conditions: building workers in England from the Magna Carta to Tony Blair’, in S. Cavaciocchi ed., L'edilizia prima della rivoluzione industriale secc. XIII–XVIII, Atti della “Trentaseiesima Settimana di Studi” (Prato, 2005), 889–932.

42 Gray, H. L., ‘The commutation of villein services in England before the Black Death’, English Historical Review 29, 116 (1914), 625–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar; E. A. Kosminsky, Studies in the agrarian history of England in the thirteenth century, trans. R. Kisch, ed. R. H. Hilton (Oxford, 1956), 152–96; Campbell and Bartley, England on the eve of the Black Death, 251–68. Why great landlords, in England alone, from the early thirteenth century chose to manage their estates directly has so far defied convincing historical explanation; see Harvey, P. D. A., ‘The Pipe Rolls and the adoption of demesne farming in medieval England’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 27 (1974), 345–59CrossRefGoogle Scholar; N. J. T. Poynder, ‘The growth and decline of direct demesne management in medieval England’, unpublished PhD thesis, The Queen's University of Belfast, 2002.

43 Campbell, English seigniorial agriculture, 3.

44 Farmer, ‘Prices and wages’.

45 Clark, Gregory, ‘The long march of history: farm wages, population, and economic growth, England 1209–1869’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 60 (2007), 97135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

46 Stone, D., ‘The productivity of hired and customary labour: evidence from Wisbech Barton in the fourteenth century’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 50 (1997), 640–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

47 Hatcher, ‘English serfdom and villeinage’, 12. A more positive verdict on the efficiency with which labour services were performed is offered by Eona Karakacili, in ‘English agrarian labor productivity rates before the Black Death: a case study’, Journal of Economic History 64 (2004), 24–60. ‘Weekworks’ were so named because the work was owed each week throughout the year.

48 On the Winchester estate see, B. M. S. Campbell, ‘A unique estate and a unique source: the Winchester pipe rolls in perspective’, in R. H. Britnell ed., The Winchester pipe rolls and medieval English society (Woodbridge, 2003), 21–43. On famuli see M. M. Postan, The famulus: the estate labourer in the XIIth and XIIIth centuries, Economic History Review Supplement 2 (Cambridge, 1954); D. L. Farmer, ‘The famuli in the later Middle Ages’, in Britnell and Hatcher eds., Progress and problems, 207–36.

49 See e.g. Derek V. Stern, A Hertfordshire demesne of Westminster Abbey: profits, productivity and weather, ed. C. Thornton (Hatfield, 2000), 129.

50 M. Page, ‘The peasant land market on the estate of the bishopric of Winchester before the Black Death’, in Britnell ed., Winchester pipe rolls, 66–7.

51 Campbell, ‘Benchmarking’; B. M. S. Campbell, ‘Land markets and the morcellation of holdings in pre-plague England and pre-famine Ireland’, in G. Beaur and P. R. Schofield eds., ‘Property rights, the market in land and economic growth in Europe (13th–19th centuries)’ (Turnhout, 2009, forthcoming).

52 Campbell, ‘Agrarian problem’, 50–1.

53 Clark, ‘Long march’.

54 R. Horrox ed., The Black Death (Manchester, 1994), 289.

55 Langdon and Masschaele, ‘Commercial activity and population growth’, 69–73.

56 J. A. Raftis, Tenure and mobility: studies in the social history of the mediaeval English village (Toronto, 1964); J. A. Raftis, Peasant economic development within the English manorial system (Stroud, 1997).

57 Zvi Razi, Life, marriage and death in a medieval parish: economy, society and demography in Halesowen, 1270–1400 (Cambridge, 1980).

58 H. S. A. Fox, ‘Exploitation of the landless by lords and tenants in early medieval England’, in Zvi Razi and R. M. Smith eds., Medieval society and the manor court (Oxford, 1996), 518–68, here p. 520.

59 Campbell, ‘Agrarian problem’.

60 Munro, J. H., ‘Nominal wage stickiness and the real-wage problem: J. M. Keynes, Adam Smith, and the evidence’, Research in Economic History 21 (2003), 186297Google Scholar; Clark, ‘Long march’.

61 Farmer, ‘Prices and wages’; P. Latimer, ‘Early thirteenth-century prices’, in S. D. Church ed., King John: new interpretations (Woodbridge, 1999), 41–73.

62 Campbell, English seigniorial agriculture, 4–6.

63 Munro, ‘Nominal wage stickiness’.

64 Langdon and Masschaele, ‘Commercial activity and population growth’, 71–3.

65 On the agrarian crisis see Kershaw, I., ‘The Great Famine and agrarian crisis in England 1315–22’, Past and Present’, 59 (1973), 350CrossRefGoogle Scholar (reprinted as pp. 85–132 in R. H. Hilton ed., Peasants, knights and heretics (Cambridge, 1976)); B. A. Hanawalt, Crime and conflict in English communities 1300–1348 (Cambridge, Mass., 1979); W. C. Jordan, The Great Famine: northern Europe in the early fourteenth century (Princeton, 1996); Bailey, ‘Peasant welfare’; Clark, ‘Long march’.

66 Clark, ‘Work, wages and living conditions’, 894–6.

67 R. B. Dobson ed., The Peasants' Revolt of 1381 (2nd edn; London, 1983), 63–72. For a discussion of the range of wage and price controls adopted across Europe in the wake of the Black Death see Cohn, Samuel, ‘After the Black Death: labour legislation and attitudes towards labour in late-medieval western Europe’, Economic History Review 60, 3 (2007), 457–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

68 Clark, ‘Long march’; Munro, ‘Nominal wage stickiness’. Clark does concede that nominal wages failed to respond to the price deflation of the 1330s and 1340s but also effectively demonstrates that, notwithstanding the Statute of Labourers, wage rates were remarkably responsive to successive reductions of the labour force by plague.

69 Palmer, R. C., ‘The origins of property in England’, Law and History Review 3 (1985), 7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

70 P. D. A. Harvey ed., The peasant land market in medieval England (Oxford, 1984), ‘Introduction’, 19. Note that a ‘quitclaim’ was a formal renunciation of all existing and residual legal property rights in a piece of land.

71 Harvey ed., The peasant land market, 19–28; M. T. Clanchy, From memory to written record: England 1066–1307 (London, 1979).

72 Zvi Razi and R. M. Smith, ‘Origins of the English manorial court rolls as a written record: a puzzle’, in Razi and Smith eds., Medieval society, 36–68, here pp. 57–68.

73 Poynder, ‘Direct demesne management’, 154.

74 Campbell, ‘Agrarian problem’, 36.

75 Barg, M. A., ‘The social structure of manorial freeholders: an analysis of the Hundred Rolls of 1279’, Agricultural History Review 39 (1991), 108–15.Google Scholar

76 Poynder, ‘Direct demesne management’, 160–1, 169.

77 Campbell, ‘Agrarian problem’.

78 Kanzaka, J., ‘Villein rents in thirteenth-century England: an analysis of the Hundred Rolls of 1279–80’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 55 (2002), 609–12.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

79 R. Evans, ‘Merton College's control of its tenants at Thorncroft, 1270–1349’, in Razi and Smith eds., Medieval society, 236–7.

70 Hyams, P. R., ‘The origins of a peasant land market in England’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 23 (1970), 1831CrossRefGoogle Scholar; P. D. A. Harvey, ‘The peasant land market in medieval England – and beyond’, in Razi and Smith eds., Medieval society, 392–407.

81 For examples see F. W. Maitland ed., Select pleas in manorial and other seigniorial courts: reigns of Henry III and Edward I, Selden Society, 2 (London, 1889).

82 Page, ‘Peasant land market’.

83 K. Stocks, ‘Payments to manorial courts in the early Winchester Accounts’, in Britnell ed., Winchester pipe rolls, 45–59; Razi and Smith, ‘The origins of the English manorial court rolls’, 38–42.

84 Razi and Smith, ‘Origins of the English manorial court rolls’, 50–6.

85 E.g. B. M. S. Campbell, ‘Population pressure, inheritance and the land market in a fourteenth-century peasant community’, in R. M. Smith ed., Land, kinship and life-cycle (Cambridge, 1984), 87–134.

86 L. Bonfield and L. R. Poos, ‘The development of deathbed transfers in medieval English manor courts’, in Razi and Smith eds., Medieval society, 117–42.

87 Archives of King's College Cambridge, E32.

88 Archives of King's College Cambridge, E32.

89 Further examples demonstrating the sophistication of both inter vivos and testamentary transfers undertaken and enforced in manorial courts are presented and discussed in L. R. Poos and L. Bonfield, eds., Select cases in manorial courts 1250–1550: property and family law, Selden Society, 114 (London, 1998).

90 P. R. Schofield, ‘Access to credit in the medieval English countryside’, and Chris Briggs, ‘Creditors and debtors at Oakington, Cottenham and Dry Drayton (Cambridgeshire), 1291–1350’, both in P. R. Schofield and N. J. Mayhew eds., Credit and debt in medieval England, c.1180–1350 (Oxford, 2002), 106–26 and 127–48 respectively.

91 Schofield, P. R., ‘Dearth, debt and the local land market in a late thirteenth-century village community’, Agricultural History Review 45 (1997), 117.Google Scholar

92 Hudson, W., ‘The prior of Norwich's manor of Hindolveston: its early organisation and the right of the customary tenants to alienate their strips of land’, Norfolk Archaeology 20 (1919–1920), 179–84Google Scholar; Campbell, ‘Population pressure’; Schofield, ‘Dearth’.

93 Davies, Mike and Kissock, Jonathan, ‘The Feet of Fines, the land market and the English agricultural crisis of 1315 to 1322’, Journal of Historical Geography 30 (2004), 215–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

94 Bekar, C. T. and Reed, C. G., ‘Open fields, risk, and land divisibility’, Explorations in Economic History 40 (2003), 308–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

95 Campbell, B. M. S., ‘The extent and layout of commonfields in eastern Norfolk’, Norfolk Archaeology 38 (1981), 532Google Scholar; Campbell, ‘Population pressure’; Whittle, Development of agrarian capitalism.

96 Palmer, ‘Origins of property’, 249; Palmer, R. C., ‘The economic and cultural impact of the origins of property: 1180–1220’, Law and History Review 3 (1985), 375–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

97 Farmer, ‘Prices and wages’; Latimer, ‘Early thirteenth-century prices’.

98 Allen, ‘Volume of the English currency’.

99 Campbell, English seigniorial agriculture.

100 N. Brady, ‘The gothic barn of England: icon of prestige and authority’, in E. Smith and M. Wolfe eds., Technology and resource use in medieval Europe: cathedrals, mills and mines (Aldershot, 1997), 76–105; R. Holt, The mills of medieval England (Oxford, 1988); J. L. Langdon, Mills in the medieval economy: England 1300–1540 (Oxford, 2004) and Horses, oxen and technological innovation: the use of draught animals in English farming from 1066 to 1500 (Cambridge, 1986); D. Harrison, The bridges of medieval England: transport and society 400–1800 (Oxford, 2004); I. Friel, The good ship: ships, shipbuilding and technology in England 1200–1520 (London, 1995).

101 Epstein, Freedom and growth, 62.

102 Epstein, Freedom and growth, 20–3.

103 M. Prestwich, The three Edwards: war and the state in England 1272–1377 (London, 1980), 33, 85, 106, 217, 223.

104 R. C. Stacey, ‘Jewish lending and the medieval English economy’, in Britnell and Campbell eds., Commercialising economy, 78–101, here p. 89. See also R. R. Mundill, ‘Christian and Jewish lending patterns and financial dealings during the twelfth and thirteenth centuries’, in Schofield and Mayhew eds., Credit and debt, 42–67.

105 Stacey, ‘Jewish lending’, 93.

106 Stacey, ‘Jewish lending’, 94.

107 Jews ‘were not usually interested in acquiring possession of landed property itself. Christians were’ (Stacey, ‘Jewish lending’, 101). For the situation in the Lordship of Ireland, see M. D. O'Sullivan, Italian merchant bankers in Ireland in the thirteenth century: a study in the social and economic history of medieval Ireland (Dublin, 1962), 26–86.

108 Stacey, ‘Jewish lending’, 101.

109 P. Nightingale, ‘The lay subsidies and the distribution of wealth in medieval England, 1275–1334’, Economic History Review, 2nd series 57 (2004), 15.

110 Nightingale, ‘Lay subsidies’, 15.

111 Jenks, S., ‘The lay subsidies and the state of the English economy, 1275–1334’, Vierteljahrschrift für Sozial- und Wirtschaftsgeschichte 85 (1998), 139Google Scholar; Nightingale, ‘Lay subsidies’, 12, 15.

112 Schofield and Mayhew eds., Credit and debt.

113 Lloyd, English wool trade, 289–95.

114 For examples see Lloyd, English wool trade, 289–90.

115 Schofield, ‘Dearth’.

116 On debt cases recorded in manorial courts see E. Clark, ‘Debt litigation’; Chris Briggs, ‘Credit and the peasant household economy in England before the Black Death: evidence from a Cambridgeshire manor’, in Cordelia Beattie, Anna Maslakovic, and Sarah Rees Jones eds., The medieval household in Christian Europe, c.850–c.1550: managing power, wealth, and the body (Turnhout, 2003), 231–48; Briggs, Chris, ‘Empowered or marginalized? Rural women and credit in later thirteenth- and fourteenth-century England’, Continuity and Change 19 (2004), 1343.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

117 Centre for Metropolitan History, ‘Metropolitan market networks c.1300–1600’, Annual Report 1999–2000 (London, 2000), 5–9.

118 Keene, ‘Changes in London's economic hinterland’.

119 Clark, ‘Cost of capital’; Epstein, Freedom and growth, 62.

120 Epstein, Freedom and growth, 61.

121 Britnell, Commercialisation; Miller and Hatcher, Medieval England; Britnell and Campbell eds., Commercialising economy; Campbell et al., Medieval capital; P. R. Schofield, Peasant and community in medieval England, 1200–1500 (Basingstoke, 2003), 131–56. On commercialization within Europe, see R. S. Lopez, The commercial revolution of the Middle Ages, 950–1350 (Cambridge, 1976); K. G. Persson, Pre-industrial economic growth: social organization and technological progress in Europe (Oxford, 1988); Peter Spufford, Power and profit: the merchant in medieval Europe (London, 2003).

122 Epstein, Freedom and growth, 20–3.

123 Stacey, ‘Jewish lending’, 98–100.

124 Munro, ‘Nominal wage stickiness’.

125 Whittle, Development of agrarian capitalism, 275–301; Clark, ‘Long march’.

126 A. Harding, ‘The revolt against the justices’, in R. H. Hilton and T. H. Aston eds., The English rising of 1381 (Cambridge, 1984), 165–93, here pp. 184–7; Dobson, ed. Peasants' revolt.

127 Campbell, ‘Agrarian problem’.